Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
The Gerontologist, 2015, Vol. 55, No. 4 694 Making Retirement Viable Again Charles D. Ellis, Alicia H. Munnell, & Andrew D. Eschtruth (2014). Falling Short: The Coming Retirement Crisis. Oxford University Press, New York, NY, 159 pp., no price listed (cloth). Nancy J. Altman & Eric R. Kingson. (2014). Social Security Works! The New Press, New York, NY, 288 pp., $16.95 (paper). After the 2014 off-year elections catapulted the Republican Party into majority status in both Houses of the 114th Congress, House Republicans unexpectedly adopted a rule which would bar the House from shifting payroll taxes from the Old Age and Survivors’ Insurance (OASI; Social Security retirement) program to the (Social Security) Disability Insurance (DI) program, which is in danger of running out of funds to pay disability benefits by 2016. Altman and Kingson (A&K) anticipated this action by House Republicans in their new book, Social Security Works! As the authors speculate, the new rule was undoubtedly intended to facilitate the consideration of so-called entitlement reform by those determined to cut entitlement programs, including DI and Medicare. It is instructive that this very same type of reallocation action had been taken on 11 previous occasions by Congress, with no apparent ill effects (all benefits were paid, no funds were taken from other programs, taxes were not increased, and the nation survived). Equally important to note is the fact that the shifting of funds via tax rates has not gone exclusively from OASI to DI trust funds; it sometimes went from DI to OASI as well. One of these reallocations from DI to OASI occurred in 1983 and was substantial. It was only partially rectified in a 1994 shift from OASI to DI. If that 1983 reallocation had not occurred, DI would not be in need of bolstering today (Ruffing, 2015). A&K elaborate on how the term entitlement has become a lightning rod for so-called reformers, who are actually interested in cutting entitlement spending. An irony of this development is that entitlement authority, as defined in the 1974 Congressional Budget Reform and Impoundment Control Act, was nothing more than a term intended to classify a certain kind of spending authority. However, opponents of Social Security and Medicare have, over time, by deliberately and consistently conflating entitlements with anti-poverty or welfare programs (which are intended to be seen as wasteful gifts), intentionally given the term entitlement an entirely different and somewhat odious meaning, a process that A&K discuss at some length in their book. To be fair, the conflation of Social Security with poverty policy may also be due in part to the widely cited conclusion that Social Security is the most effective program in the U.S. policy arsenal at reducing poverty. The lineage and history of Social Security is of wage insurance, not poverty alleviation. Its legislative progeny, Medicare, is of a similar origin. Nevertheless, as A&K emphasize repeatedly throughout their book, the combined size of these two programs (which now account for roughly 40% of federal outlays, and perhaps more importantly, their automatic funding) has made them the primary objects of the rhetoric of entitlement reform, which is transparent code for cutting entitlement spending. As A&K note, it is regrettable that the relentless equating of entitlements with benefits to the poor has occurred over time not only as a result of assaults by well-known entitlement foes [such as mega-millionaire entitlement opponent and crusader Peter Peterson and his allies, such as David Walker (the former Comptroller General) and former Senator Alan Simpson (R-WY)], but also as the perhaps unintended side effect of actions by more liberal friends, such as President Bill Clinton (whose creation of a so-called entitlements commission gave an opportunity to entitlement opponents to propose cuts to these programs) and President Barack Obama (whose eagerness to achieve a so-called grand bargain on the budget, including changes to Social Security and Medicare, lent legitimacy to the arguments of the opponents of Social Security and Medicare, equating them with need-based programs). As noted by Gist in Hudson (2009, p. 174), “In budgetary terms, entitlements are programs that generally carry permanent authorizations and are not subject to annual appropriations, thereby insulating them from congressional appropriations scrutiny.” Rhetorically, however, the term entitlements has become a code word to conjure up images of wasteful and extravagant uncontrollable spending on older citizens, rather than earned benefits based on contributions such as Social Security, Medicare, unemployment insurance, and federal worker pensions. As much as anything, it is the independence of spending for entitlements from annual congressional control which seems to invigorate opponents, and has even led some more thoughtful analysts The Gerontologist, 2015, Vol. 55, No. 4 to blame our budgetary woes on the historical decisions of “dead men ruling” (Steuerle, 2014), suggesting that our so-called fiscal freedom is jeopardized by letting decisions made as long ago as the 1930s govern today’s budget allocations. I would suggest we should be grateful for the wisdom of past Congresses for enacting legislation that not only provided adequate funding for a multi-generational program, but also made it possible to structure benefits in a way that allows beneficiaries to know in advance what they can count on receiving in retirement. Imagine 41 million old-age retirees waiting for today’s Congress (which has demonstrated a willingness to consider not paying federal workers) to appropriate sufficient funds to pay retirement benefits, and to allocate those funds in a rational way across individuals. The prospect is disquieting, to say the least. However, thanks to the foresight of those dead men, we need not be concerned about a dysfunctional Congress doing the right thing, and the Congress does not need to decide on the proper amount of funds to appropriate. Nevertheless, we still have a Congress (or at least one party) determined to undermine programs that have functioned successfully (although not necessarily to their liking) for decades. Regrettably and ironically, entitlement reformers have no doubt been inadvertently aided in their effort to cut entitlements by the outstanding work of the Congressional Budget Office in analyzing and presenting budget options, and by its use of ostensibly neutral budget terminology such as entitlements and transfers, which has lent legitimacy to efforts to equate Social Security and Medicare with need-based welfare programs such as Temporary Assistance to Needy Families (TANF), Supplemental Nutritional Assistance Program (SNAP), Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC), Medicaid, and other programs dedicated to the amelioration of the condition of the poor. A&K’s investigation underscores the centrality of Social Security to a financially successful retirement. In this respect, at least, their treatment is similar to that of Ellis, Munnell, and Eschtruth (EME), who place Social Security at the heart of any retirement plan. A&K emphasize several aspects of Social Security: (1)It is wage insurance, to which workers contribute, and it is therefore earned, not a gift, the way many think of poverty programs; (2)Because workers make contributions to purchase the insurance, Social Security cannot go bankrupt, as some critics claim, as long as there are workers paying into the fund; 695 (3)Worker and employer contributions provide the basic funding for the program; (4)Program spending is based not on need, but rather is directly related to workers’ contributions; (5)Program funding does not depend on general income tax revenue. A&K’s most notable contribution is the plan they call the Social Security Works for All Generations Plan, which is a “comprehensive package of benefit and revenue changes that expands Social Security’s protections in important ways.” This plan consists of several changes to both benefits and revenues. On the benefit side: (1)Increasing benefits to everyone who receives Social Security now, or will in the future, by 10% across the board up to $150/month; (2)Adoption of a cost of living adjustment based on spending by the elderly—the so-called CPI-E—which they deem to be more accurate (although it is not based on a full sample of older consumers) than either the CPI-U (the one used today), or the so-called chained CPI, which is thought by many to be more accurate than either of the other inflation adjustment measures; (3)Update the special minimum benefit to 125% of the poverty line for those who work at least 30 years and retire at their full retirement age; (4)Payment of full benefits for wealthy people whose contributions increase; (5)Improvement in SSI benefits; (6)Restoring student benefits for children of deceased or disabled workers; (7)Enhancing protections for disabled adult children. If these seem like costly revisions, they are. A&K propose financing these enhancements through a variety of means, as follows: (1)A two-decade-long increase of 1% each (on workers and employers) in the rate of contributions to Social Security (payroll tax), which means contributions would rise in 20 years from 6.2% on each to 7.2%, or an overall rate of contribution of 14.4 compared to today’s 12.4%; (2)Uncapping the payroll tax, which is currently capped at just below $120,000. The cap now causes some 6% of earners and 7.5% of earnings at the very top of the earnings distribution to escape payroll taxation. The increase in taxes would be coupled with an increase in benefits for contributions above the cap; 696 (3)A new, higher marginal personal income tax rate of 49.6% (10% age points above today’s maximum) on incomes in excess of $1 million, with the new revenue dedicated to Social Security; (4)Diversification of the assets of the Social Security trust funds to include investment in equities rather than just federal bonds. This is unlike the proposal of the George W. Bush Administration in early 2005 to have each individual worker carry a portfolio of assets, including equities, in their private Social Security account. The A&K proposal would not give each worker the responsibility for managing his or her own asset portfolio. Rather, it would provide for the investment of the total asset portfolio of the Social Security trust funds, in much the same way that defined benefit plan portfolios are managed by the employer, unlike defined contribution plans in which the investment burden lies with the worker. EM&E’s book Falling Short also emphasizes the primacy of Social Security to retirement security, but in so doing expresses a rather different view of Social Security’s evolution. Rather than the stable, unchanging program described by A&K, EME describe how changes to Social Security in the last 20 years have taken us from the so-called golden age of retirement (1980–2000) to a situation where retirement is precarious, and many are falling short because they simply do not have adequate retirement income, which EME define as a replacement rate equal to at least 75% of their pre-retirement income. In the golden age of retirement, Social Security alone provided about 60% of the pre-retirement income for the average couple (including spousal benefits), fairly close to the 75% replacement rate required by their assumption. Consequently, less additional saving was needed in that era. In the golden age, the defined benefit pension was more likely to be available than it is today. Not that pension coverage was so much more widespread in those days—it wasn’t; only about half of workers received DB pensions, but those that did were guaranteed a lifetime income stream that required little or no decision making on the part of the retiree, as distinct from today’s predominant defined contribution plan. The DB pension investment decisions were the responsibility of the employer. Also, those that received a DB pension from their employer were also likely to receive retiree health insurance coverage. However, as distinct from A&K’s argument, EME argue that changes to Social Security over time have altered the nature of the program. EME describe how the program was expanded between 1949 and 1979. The year 1950 Amendments expanded coverage to include farm and domestic workers and the self-employed. As Social Security The Gerontologist, 2015, Vol. 55, No. 4 was expanded, it also began to allow more flexibility in the age at which people could claim benefits. Social Security was transformed by these changes: “from an insurance plan for individual workers into a family-based economic security program and significantly weakened the link between lifetime contributions and benefits. Moreover, the legislation accelerated the payment of benefits so individuals who had worked only a few years under the system were entitled to full benefits. The decision shifted the financing model from a funded system to pay-as-you-go, with big implications for the cost of Social Security benefits today. If earlier cohorts had received only the benefits that could have been financed by their contributions plus interest, trust fund assets and interest earnings would be much larger today and the required tax on our current earnings much lower.” As EME explain, the situation for the worker is far riskier today than it was two decades or more ago. First, people are living longer, so the length of the retirement period is longer. Social Security’s funding is more precarious, and although 401(k)s are perhaps capable of providing adequate funding, along with Social Security, for retirement, there are many more opportunities for workers to make mistakes with 401(k)s than with DB plans (they may not contribute enough; their investment choices may not be as good, such as investing too much in company stock; they may withdraw money too early; and they may fail to manage their income flow in retirement, e.g., not annuitizing assets). Although both books strongly advocate improvements to Social Security as the bedrock of retirement security, some of their suggestions for fixes to Social Security are similar and somewhat surprising. For example, both recommend diversifying Social Security’s assets into equities, although both oppose the creation of individual investment accounts in the Social Security program, as the Bush Administration proposed in 2005. However, more generally, it seems to me a fair characterization to say that the A&K solution to the retirement problem is to change programs, whereas the EME solution is to change behavior (although not without public policy assistance). The EME answer to what people can do individually to cope with the retirement problem, distilled to its basic elements, is that individuals should: (1)Work longer; (2)Save more; (3)Invest more wisely; (4)Think about the home as a source of retirement saving. The Gerontologist, 2015, Vol. 55, No. 4 Although this seems more like a so-called yoyo (i.e., you’re on your own) prescription than that of A&K, EME also propose several actions (some of which are controversial) that we can take as a nation that would facilitate the individual behavioral changes: (1)Improve incentives to work longer. Current law signals that age 62 is the earliest age of eligibility for Social Security, but that age is too early for most people to reach the desired 75% replacement rate. The key to the EME recommendation is that “monthly benefits increase by about 7 to 8 percent for each year we delay claiming” (because benefits are actuarially reduced for those who retire before the full retirement age and they are actuarially increased for those who retire later than the full retirement age). The meaning of actuarial in this context is that benefits are held constant, on average, by those adjustments to individual benefits. However, for those who live longer, higher benefits will be an important benefit. EME conclude that the Boston College Center for Retirement Research’s National Retirement Risk Index, which indicates that about 53% of retirees will fail to reach the 75% threshold of retirement saving adequacy under current law, would increase to 85% if people work to age 70. They find that the so-called net Social Security replacement rate at age 70 for those who retire then will be 43% in 2030, but only 24% if they retire at age 62. (2)Maintain Social Security. Among the options suggested here are to raise the combined payroll tax rate by 2.88% of earnings, not to increase the full retirement age (which is tantamount to reducing benefits), fixing the system permanently rather than for the 75-year projection window, consider investing part of the trust funds in equities, and possibly subjecting part of Social Security financing to the income tax. (3)Fixing the 401(k) system. Here they suggest improving participation and contribution levels by making the adoption of automatic participation provisions (with an optout) universal, making it harder to take money out of the plan, increase use of target-date funds (which combine an age-appropriate mix of risky and safer investments), make the use of index funds (which mimic the overall stock market) more widespread (as opposed to actively managed funds), and make the drawdown of funds more rational by making annuities cheaper and safer; 697 (4)Expanding savings plan coverage through plans such as the Obama MyRA plan; (5)Restructuring tax incentives for saving by converting tax deductions to credits; (6)Making the use of home equity savings more widespread by educating the public about the merits and mechanics of using home equity for retirement income purposes. These two books together provide an important antidote to those Paul Krugman calls the fiscal scolds who tell us that catastrophe awaits if we don’t fix our entitlement problem. They remind us why Social Security is such a popular and successful program, and that it is not in the dire straits that are often described by its critics. They are instructive in setting forth an agenda of action that will make retirement more feasible for today’s older workers. John R. Gist, PhD Institute of Public Policy Research Professor George Washington University Washington, DC 20052 E-mail: [email protected] doi:10.1093/geront/gnv084 John R. Gist: Before rejoining the academy at George Washington University, John Gist worked for two decades in AARP’s Public Policy Institute as Associate Director for economic policy research, and later as Senior Advisor for fiscal and economic policy. He recently completed a study for the Pew Charitable Trusts and the Mott Foundation on retirement security across generations, from which he published (with Megan E. Hatch) “Retirement Replacement Rates and Retirement Wealth Inequality Among Baby Boomer and Other Birth Cohorts,” Journal of Retirement, July 2014 References Hudson, R. (Ed.). (2009). Boomer bust: Economic and political issues of the graying society. Westport, CT: Praeger. Ruffing, K. (2015). “Getting it wrong on disability insurance,” Off the Charts Blog, Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, February 13, 2015. Steuerle, C. E. (2014). Dead men ruling: How to restore fiscal freedom and rescue our future. Century Foundation.