Download By How Much Does GDP Rise If the Government Buys More Output?

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Economic democracy wikipedia , lookup

Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup

Okishio's theorem wikipedia , lookup

Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup

Business cycle wikipedia , lookup

Consumerism wikipedia , lookup

Rostow's stages of growth wikipedia , lookup

Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Fiscal multiplier wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 183
ROBERT E. HALL
Stanford University
By How Much Does GDP Rise
If the Government Buys More Output?
ABSTRACT During World War II and the Korean War, real GDP grew by
about half the increase in government purchases. With allowance for other
factors holding back GDP growth during those wars, the multiplier linking
government purchases to GDP may be in the range of 0.7 to 1.0, a range generally supported by research based on vector autoregressions that control for
other determinants, but higher values are not ruled out. New Keynesian macroeconomic models yield multipliers in that range as well. Neoclassical models
produce much lower multipliers, because they predict that consumption falls
when government purchases rise. Models that deliver higher multipliers feature
a decline in the markup ratio of price over cost when output rises, and an elastic
response of employment to increased demand. These characteristics are complementary to another Keynesian feature, the linkage of consumption to current income. The GDP multiplier is higher—perhaps around 1.7—when the
nominal interest rate is at its lower bound of zero.
M
ajor contractions in economic activity bring policies of temporary
expansion in government purchases of goods and services. The severe
contraction that hit the U.S. and world economies in 2008 was no exception.
The need for fiscal expansion was particularly acute because monetary policy had driven nominal short-term safe interest rates down to zero without
heading off the contraction. Fiscal policy, including increases in federal
purchases and in state and local purchases financed by federal grants, was
an important part of the government’s response to a severe recession.
A major issue for fiscal policy is how much total output increases when
the government temporarily buys more goods and services. The ratio of the
output increase to the purchases increase is the government purchases
multiplier. I emphasize that my concern in this paper is with government
purchases, not all of government spending, which includes transfers and
interest payments as well as purchases. I assume in all cases that the products
183
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
184
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 184
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
the government purchases enter preferences in a separable fashion: they do
not affect households’ marginal rate of substitution between consumption
and work or between consumption this year and in any future year. Military
spending is the obvious example. If instead the government provided consumers with goods and services they would have purchased anyway, the
resulting multiplier would be lower. In the extreme case, where the government purchases consumption goods and provides them to consumers, the
multiplier would be zero in the standard life-cycle model.
I exclude effects that operate through externalities. One such effect
arises from the fact that the government, as the nation’s agent for collective
action, may have uses for output that exceed the private value of the output.
For example, law enforcement is underprovided by private action and may
be underprovided by current government action. If the increase in government purchases includes more spending on law enforcement, its value may
exceed its direct contribution to GDP. I leave out that increased value,
which could be attributed either to the purchases or to the increase in GDP
that occurs because more enforcement makes other production more efficient. Another example is road building, where the benefits accrue mainly in
the future, because roads are part of the public capital stock. I omit benefits
related to externalities not because I think they are unimportant, but because
I want to focus on a limited, strictly macroeconomic question. Thus, as a
general matter, I do not offer a welfare analysis of government purchases,
but rather one important piece of a welfare analysis, having to do with the
aggregate effects, mainly in the labor market, of the government’s increase
in product demand.
I assume that no special distortionary taxes apply during the brief period
of the countercyclical purchases; the government balances its budget in the
long run with whatever taxes it normally uses. I also do not comment on
the other major branch of fiscal stimulus, tax reductions. An analysis of
fiscal stimulus in the form of higher transfers or lower taxes would make
use of the conclusion about the effects of higher purchases on overall economic activity, because it is a fair presumption that the effects of higher
consumer purchases are similar to the effects of higher government purchases. But I do consider the effects of the subsequent financing of increased
government purchases, both explicitly in the models I study and implicitly
in my empirical work, which assumes that the public knows that the government must eventually service the debt it has issued to pay for its higher
purchases. Here my focus on temporary increases in purchases is critical:
permanent increases have a different effect because households will respond
by cutting consumption in anticipation of permanent increases in taxes, a
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
ROBERT E. HALL
11:35 AM
Page 185
185
wealth effect. I demonstrate the irrelevance of any wealth effect for temporary programs of higher government purchases.
The paper describes a closed economy. In effect, it is about the world
economy, although I use U.S. data to find parameter values. In the context of the events of 2008 and 2009, a global focus is appropriate, because
every major economy has suffered substantial declines in employment and
output, and many have responded with increases in government purchases.
I start with a discussion of the direct evidence from simple regressions
about both the output multiplier and the analogous consumption multiplier
for government purchases. Given the reasonable assumption that movements in military purchases are exogenous and the fact that they account
for much of the variation in government purchases, the natural approach is
to study the econometric relationship between output and consumption, on
the one hand, and military spending, on the other. The resulting multipliers
are about 0.5 for output and slightly negative for consumption. Although
the standard errors of these estimates are agreeably small, the estimates are
under suspicion for understating the multipliers, because the bulk of the
evidence comes from the command economy of World War II and may not
be relevant to today’s market economy. Omitting World War II from the
sample yields similar multipliers with rather larger standard errors, based
largely on the Korean War buildup, but these too are questionable because
that buildup was accompanied by large increases in tax rates. Changes in
military purchases from the Vietnam War period, the Reagan years, or the
two wars in Iraq are not large enough to deliver usable estimates of the
multipliers. I conclude that the evidence from U.S. historical experience on
the magnitude of the multipliers only makes the case that the multiplier is
above 0.5.
I next report evidence from vector autoregressions (VARs), which find
fairly consistently that the output multiplier is in the range from 0.5 to
1.0 and that the consumption multiplier is somewhat positive. To varying
extents, these estimates include adjustments for factors such as taxes that
may correct downward biases in the simple regressions.
The paper then turns to models, specifically those derived from the
blending of neoclassical and Keynesian theory that has flourished in the
past decade under the name New Keynesian economics. Following many
earlier authors, I demonstrate that the purely neoclassical general-equilibrium
model without unemployment yields the pretty much unshakable conclusion that increases in government purchases come largely out of investment
and consumption and do not raise output substantially. The output multiplier is well under 1, and the consumption multiplier is quite negative. The
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
186
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 186
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
reason is that increased output in this type of model can come only from
increased employment. Without a reservoir of unemployed workers to draw
down, any increase in labor input must drive the wage down, resulting in
less labor supply. The neoclassical model thus predicts small increases in
output and fairly large declines in consumption.
A key idea of modern macroeconomics that results in more reasonable
multipliers is that the margin of price over cost falls during expansions; that
is, the markup ratio declines as output rises. Often this property is expressed
as stickiness of the price level: prices stay constant during a boom that
raises input costs. Other rationalizations based on oligopoly theory or other
principles deliver the result directly. The declining markup permits the
wage to rise, or at least not fall as much as it would with constant markup
during an expansion. Hence, it permits the household to supply much more
labor when the government increases its claim on output.
A second key idea of modern macroeconomics needed to rationalize a
reasonably positive output multiplier is elastic labor supply. Research based
on household data is adamant that the elasticity of labor supply is below 1
even after adjustment for the income effect. Such an elasticity precludes a
substantially positive output multiplier with any reasonable response of the
markup to changes in output. It takes both a declining markup and elastic
labor supply to generate a substantial output multiplier.
My approach to rationalizing a high wage elasticity of labor supply starts
from the observation that most of the cyclical movement in work effort
takes the form of variations in unemployment. I raise the elasticity of labor
supply to incorporate the response of unemployment to changes in labor
demand, following a search-and-matching approach to the labor market. A
standard dynamic general-equilibrium model with a sufficiently responsive
markup and realistically elastic effective labor supply (including the response
of unemployment) yields an output multiplier as high as just below 1, in
accord with the direct evidence.
One might think that the traditional Keynesian hypothesis of rigid
wages would be a close cousin of elastic labor supply, but this thought
turns out to be quite wrong. An unresponsive wage constrains the immediate effect of an increase in government purchases to zero, because
employment and thus output are determined entirely by the equality of
the marginal product of labor and the wage. This predetermination of
output remains in an economy where the markup ratio declines with higher
output.
The standard model with responsive markup and elastic labor supply
still generates a negative consumption multiplier. I show that adding com-
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
ROBERT E. HALL
11:35 AM
Page 187
187
plementarity between hours worked and consumption—a topic of extensive recent research—can tame the negative multiplier. The logic is that
employed people consume significantly more market goods and services
than do the unemployed, who have more time to create nonmarket equivalents. My preferred specification for matching the observed positive multiplier for output and the slightly negative multiplier for consumption has a
substantial negative response of the markup of price over cost to changes in
output, a fairly elastic response of employment to changes in labor demand,
and a degree of complementarity of consumption and work estimated from
micro data.
Modern models generally embody the life-cycle model of consumption,
where households use credit markets to smooth consumption. It is widely
believed that replacing this feature of models with a traditional consumption function linking consumer spending to current income will boost the
output and consumption multipliers. The issue then becomes by how much
an increase in government purchases crowds out investment. Traditional
Keynesian models assume rigid real wages, in which case output is determined on the demand side of the labor market by firms equating the marginal
product of labor to the fixed real wage. With output unresponsive, crowding
out is complete and the output multiplier is zero. Adding partial borrowing
constraints to an otherwise standard New Keynesian model does boost the
consumption multiplier.
Multipliers are not structural constants. They describe the responses
of endogenous variables to changes in the driving force of government
purchases. Multipliers depend on monetary policy. In normal times, monetary policy leans against the expansionary effect of increased government
spending, reducing the multipliers. But when monetary policy lowers nominal interest rates to their minimum value of zero, the offsetting effect disappears, and so an economy at the lower bound has higher multipliers. In
an economy with an output multiplier for government purchases of just
under 1 in normal times, the multiplier rises to 1.7 when monetary policy
becomes passive with a zero nominal interest rate.
I conclude that the efficacy of stimulus from higher government purchases depends on two features of the economy: a markup of price over
cost that declines as output expands, and a substantially wage-elastic labor
supply or the equivalent. Both features are related to traditional Keynesian
views about price and wage stickiness: the negative response of the markup
can be viewed as price stickiness, and elastic labor supply as wage stickiness. Both features appear to describe the U.S. economy, although research
on this topic is still far from definitive.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
188
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 188
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
I review the evidence on the movement of the markup ratio as output
expands. The hypothesis of a negative response implies that the share of
profit in total income should fall during expansions. In fact, that share
rises. The most promising rationalization involves a substantial amount of
wage smoothing. Then the observed increase in profit during booms is the
combination of two phenomena: an increase associated with wage contracts
that give management the bulk of the benefit of higher revenue, partly
offset by a decline in profit per unit of output. But this is pure guesswork—
I lack any handle on measuring wage smoothing. There is no meaningful
factual support for the key hypothesis that the markup ratio declines with
output.
I show that the expansion of government purchases so far enacted to
deal with the severe current recession is too small to add meaningfully to
our knowledge on this subject—or to offset much of the loss in output. A
debate about whether the government purchases multiplier is 1.0 or 1.5 is
completely off the point in this respect.
I. Regression Estimates of Output
and Consumption Multipliers
I begin by estimating the government purchases multipliers for output and
consumption in simple (ordinary least squares) regressions and in VARs.
I.A. Estimates from Simple Regressions on Military Purchases
The most direct way to measure the government purchases multipliers
is to exploit large and arguably exogenous fluctuations in military spending. I start with a review of that evidence for the United States over the past
80 years, using the following specification:
(1)
z t − z t −1
g − gt − 1
= mz t
+ εt .
yt −1
yt −1
Here z is either y for the output multiplier my or c for the consumption
multiplier mc. The equation also contains a constant (not shown). Note that
using the same denominator on the left and the right preserves the normal
definition of the multiplier as the dollar change in output or consumption
per dollar of increased government purchases.
In this approach I am treating the change in nonmilitary government
purchases as one of the sources of the noise εt. Because these purchases
grow smoothly, their difference has little variability. The alternative of using
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
ROBERT E. HALL
11:35 AM
Page 189
189
military spending as an instrument for total purchases gives essentially
identical results.
I assume that the change in military spending g is uncorrelated with
the non-g component of the right-hand-side variable εt. This identifying
assumption has two aspects. First, military spending does not respond to
forces determining GDP or consumption, such as monetary or financial
forces, but only to geopolitical events. I have long believed that this
aspect of the identifying assumption is among the more plausible in
macroeconomics. Second, no other determinants of output or consumption growth change when government purchases change. The basis for
this aspect of the identifying assumption is much weaker. In particular,
when military spending rises substantially, two other policy responses
may occur: command-type interventions in the economy, including
rationing, and increases in taxes. Both of these presumably decrease consumption demand and thus reduce output growth. The result is a failure
of the identifying assumption in the direction of a negative correlation
between the disturbance εt and military spending, and thus a downward
bias in the estimate of the multiplier mz. I conclude that the value of the
multiplier is probably better interpreted as a lower bound than as an
unbiased estimate.
Because the movements in GDP and consumption induced by changes
in government purchases have essentially the same dynamics as the
changes in purchases, it is not necessary (in fact, it is inefficient) to find
the innovation in g and then track the response to the innovation, as would
occur in a VAR. The advantage of a VAR is that it can account for other
influences, notably taxes, and isolate the causal effect of government
purchases. The simple regression considered here confounds the effects
of wartime increases in purchases with the effects of accompanying tax
increases. Temporary increases in purchases for stimulus purposes are not
accompanied by comparable tax increases. I discuss evidence from VARs
in the next subsection.
To form the differences in the data, I use the various versions of National
Income and Product Accounts table 1.1.6, Real Gross Domestic Product,
Chained Dollars. Each version of the table uses a different base year for
the deflator. For the overlap years, I take the average of the two measures
of the two changes; these are usually identical to two digits. I use this
approach because the deflator for military spending drifts relative to the
GDP deflator, and I wish to retain the usual interpretation of the multiplier
as the effect of one current dollar of purchases on GDP or consumption,
also measured in current dollars.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
190
Page 190
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
Table 1. Ordinary Least Squares Estimates of Government Purchases Multipliers
for Military Spendinga
Period
1930–2008
1948–2008
1960–2008
1939–48
1949–55
1939–44
1945–49
GDP multiplier
Consumption multiplier
0.55
(0.08)
0.47
(0.28)
0.13
(0.65)
0.53
(0.07)
0.48
(0.56)
0.36
(0.10)
0.39
(0.08)
−0.05
(0.03)
−0.12
(0.10)
−0.09
(0.29)
−0.05
(0.02)
−0.18
(0.05)
−0.11
(0.03)
−0.04
(0.05)
Source: Author’s calculations.
a. Numbers in parentheses are standard errors.
Table 1 shows the results of the regressions for output and consumption.
The top row shows that, over the entire sample 1930 through 2008, the
output multiplier is just over half, with a standard error of 0.08, and the
consumption multiplier is close to zero, although slightly negative, with a
standard error of 0.03. The higher precision of the consumption multiplier
estimate arises because the change in consumption has a much lower volatility than does the change in real GDP.
As I noted earlier, estimates of the multiplier that include the huge
changes in military spending during World War II are biased downward
because important parts of the economy were run on command principles
during the war. Direct controls on consumption through rationing arguably
held back consumption growth that would have occurred under free-market
conditions. Other factors, including the draft and the wartime surge in
patriotism, result in an upward bias. Although I am inclined to believe that
the net bias is downward, there is no solid evidence one way or the other.
The other rows in table 1 show the evidence from various subperiods. The
second row starts the sample in 1948, after the rise and fall of wartime military purchases. The multiplier estimates are similar to those for the whole
period but with much larger standard errors. The confidence interval for the
output multiplier runs from about zero to about 1. The confidence interval
for the consumption multiplier remains fairly tightly concentrated near zero.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
ROBERT E. HALL
11:35 AM
Page 191
191
The third row of the table starts the sample in 1960, several years after
the Korean War. It shows that military spending did not move enough
during the Vietnam War, the Reagan buildup, or the two wars in Iraq to
allow precise estimation. The estimates are fully consistent with those in
the first two rows but are almost completely uninformative about the output
multiplier. They do, however, rule out larger positive or negative values of
the consumption multiplier.
The fourth row reinforces the message of the earlier rows by showing
that the results for just the period enclosing the World War II expansion
and contraction of military spending are virtually identical to those for the
whole period. Essentially all the identifying power comes from the large
movements during World War II.
The fifth row looks at the years enclosing the Korean War. The estimates
are similar to those found for the periods including World War II but have
much larger standard errors, especially for the output multiplier.
The last two rows of table 1 break World War II into its expansion phase,
ending in 1944, and a phase containing the military contraction and the
resumption of normal economic conditions, from 1945 to 1949. One of
the strengths of the parsimonious specification I use is its ability to deliver
useful results with a small number of observations. The results are interesting
because many economists—most recently, Lawrence Christiano, Martin
Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo (2009)—believe that the multipliers are
higher when the economy is slack. The U.S. economy was extremely slack
in 1939, the first year of the expansion phase in the table. The results here
give no support to the view of higher multipliers in a slack economy. The
downward multipliers found for the period from 1945 to 1949 are virtually
identical to those for the expansion from slack starting in 1939. Both are
measured with good precision.
Robert Barro and Charles Redlick (2009) consider similar evidence in
a regression framework that includes tax rates and other determinants
of GDP along with government purchases. They use data starting in 1917
and so take advantage of World War I, another period when the military
component of purchases rose dramatically. Their estimates of the output
multiplier range from 0.59 to 0.77; the estimate for all data starting in 1917
is 0.64, with a standard error of 0.10. Their estimates of the consumption
multiplier are close to zero. They do not report results without the tax variables, but it appears that their inclusion somewhat increases the estimates.
Thus, tax increases with negative effects tend to coincide with increases in
government purchases.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
192
Page 192
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
The most important lesson from the data on military purchases is that all
the real information comes from big wars. The standard errors in table 1
reflect this fact, rising sharply when the big wars are omitted. Another way
to see the point is to observe that the regression coefficient is
mz =
∑ Δz Δg
∑ ( Δg )
t
t
t
2
τ
τ
Δzt
∑ Δg ( Δg )
2
t
(2)
=
t
t
∑ ( Δgτ )
2
τ
=
∑W
t
t
Δzt
.
Δgt
Here Δzt is the change in real GDP or consumption as a fraction of initial
real GDP less its mean, and Δgt is the change in military purchases as a fraction of GDP less its mean. Thus, the overall estimate of the multiplier is a
weighted average of year-to-year observed multipliers, where the weights Wt
depend on the square of the growth in military purchases.
Figure 1 shows these weights calculated from the data on military purchases and real GDP. The only visibly positive weights are for the two wars.
Of the two, World War II is vastly more informative. There is little hope of
learning much about the multipliers from any data after the mid-1950s. Note
that the weights are the same for the output and the consumption multipliers.
I conclude that the regression evidence from big wars demonstrates that
the government purchases multiplier is probably at least 0.5, based on the
hypothesis that the net effect of biases is downward. World War II does not
yield a higher estimate of the multiplier than does the Korean War, despite
the fact that the buildup starting in 1940 was from a much more slack economy than the one starting in 1950. Possible explanations for the failure to
find the expected relationship between initial slack and the multiplier include
more aggressive command interventions in the earlier mobilization and the
fact that World War II involved enormous expansions in motor vehicles,
ships, and aircraft, all highly specialized industries subject to bottlenecks.
I.B. Estimates from Vector Autoregressions
VARs are a more powerful approach to measuring multipliers, in principle. The simple regressions in the previous section take all the movements
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 193
193
ROBERT E. HALL
Figure 1. Annual Weights Implicit in OLS Estimates of Output
and Consumption Multipliersa
Weight
0.35
0.30
0.25
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
1935
1945
1955
1965
1975
1985
1995
2005
Source: Authorís calculations.
a. Each weight derives from the square of military spending in that year.
in real GDP and consumption not attributable to changes in government
purchases as noise, captured by the residual. Even if these movements arise
from driving forces that are uncorrelated with military purchases, so that
the estimated multipliers are unbiased, the estimates have a high sampling
error. A VAR can soak up much of the noise by associating it with other
causal factors, thus generating more precise estimates than a simple regression. Further, a VAR can take account of effects that are correlated with
changes in government purchases that result in biases in the simple regressions. Probably the main effect of this type is that from the tax rate, although
this correlation can be captured in a simple regression as in Barro and
Redlick (2009). By far the biggest increase in government purchases over
the sample included in the VARs reported below occurred during the Korean
War, when tax rates also increased substantially.
Olivier Blanchard and Roberto Perotti (2002), Jordi Galí, David LópezSalido, and Javier Vallés (2007), Perotti (2008), Andrew Mountford and
Harald Uhlig (2008), and Valerie Ramey (2009) estimate VARs subject
to a variety of identification schemes, all of which basically rely on the
exogeneity of movements of government purchases. Blanchard and Perotti
consider two versions of their VAR, one with a deterministic trend and
the other with a stochastic trend. Ramey estimates elasticities rather than
multipliers; I convert these to multipliers by dividing by the ratios of
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
194
Page 194
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
Table 2. Literature Estimates of Government Purchases Multipliers
from Vector Autoregressionsa
Estimate
Source
Type of
multiplier
Blanchard and Perotti (2002, table 4)
Output
Galí, López-Salido, and Vallés
(2007, table 1)
Output
Consumption
Perotti (2008, figure 3)
Output
Consumption
Mountford and Uhlig (2008, table 4)
Output
Ramey (2008, figure 10a)
Outputb
Ramey (2008, figure 10b)
Consumptionc
On
impact
After
4 quarters
After
8 quarters
0.90
(0.30)
0.41
(0.16)
0.07
(0.10)
0.70
(0.20)
0.10
(0.05)
0.65
(0.39)
0.30
(0.10)
0.02
0.55
(0.80)
0.31
(0.34)
0.11
(0.19)
1.00
(0.50)
0.30
(0.20)
0.27
(0.78)
0.50
(0.25)
−0.17
0.65
(1.20)
0.68
(0.45)
0.49
(0.28)
1.20
(0.50)
0.40
(0.25)
−0.74
(1.95)
0.90
(0.35)
−0.09
Source: Literature cited.
a. Numbers in parentheses are standard errors.
b. Ramey (2008) states results for both output and consumption as elasticities, which here have been
converted to multipliers.
c. Separate elasticities were estimated for durables, nondurables, and services, so standard errors for
total consumption are unavailable.
government purchases to GDP and to consumption of nondurables and services. Ramey’s innovation is to identify shocks to government purchases
from events presaging rises in military spending, which she weights by the
present value of the predicted increase in military purchases.
Table 2 shows the estimated multipliers for real GDP and in some
cases consumption for the above five studies at three points in time after an
innovation in government purchases: on impact, after four quarters, and
after eight quarters. None of the estimated output multipliers is as high
as 1 at impact. The impact multipliers range from 0.3 to 0.9. The variation
arises from differences in identification strategies. Perotti, and Galí and
his coauthors, find consumption multipliers as high as 0.49, whereas
Ramey’s estimates are only slightly positive or negative. The difference
again arises from her identification strategy rather than the other authors’
use of the innovation in all government purchases. The standard errors in
table 2 indicate the wide range of uncertainty in the responses, especially
at longer lags. Note that all of these studies use the same data, so that their
estimated coefficients are highly correlated with each other. The standard
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 195
ROBERT E. HALL
195
errors are indicative of the overall uncertainty from VARs; they would not
be smaller for an average across the various estimates.
One important difference between these earlier VAR estimates and
the question pursued in this paper is that government purchases rose very
persistently in response to innovations over the period from 1948 to the
present. The Korean War was the exception to the general rule that military
spending is transitory: it remained high after the end of that war because of
the intensification of the Cold War. By contrast, the increase in government
purchases to offset a recession is intended to be transitory.
I.C. Conclusions on the OLS and VAR Estimates
Empirical work using simple regressions or more elaborate VARs finds
output multipliers in the range from 0.5 to 1.0, with a few exceptions, and
consumption multipliers in the range from somewhat negative to 0.5. All
of this work is limited in its ability to measure multipliers for the period from
1948 onward by the lack of variation in government purchases, especially
in its most exogenous component, military purchases. Figure 1 showed that
essentially all the information comes from World War II and the Korean
War. Both the simple regressions and the VARs infer the multipliers
entirely or mainly from the rise in military spending starting in 1940 (for
the simple regressions only) and again in 1950, and the VARs are probably
only partly successful in adjusting for taxes and other confounding forces.
Thus, one cannot say that the evidence rules out multipliers above 1.0. In
the rest of the paper, I will speak as if the evidence clearly supports an
output multiplier a bit below 1 and a consumption multiplier a bit negative.
To avoid painful repetition, I will not comment each time on the weakness
of the evidence on this point.
II. Multipliers Derived from Structural
Macroeconomic Models
Today, most research-oriented macroeconomic models combine, in varying proportions, ideas from dynamic optimization. In the majority of
these models, households choose consumption to balance present against
future satisfaction, according to the life-cycle-permanent-income principle,
although some households may face binding borrowing constraints. In
almost all models, firms choose inputs so as to maximize firm value, subject
to the wage for labor and the rental price for capital. In many models, firms
are price-setting monopolists facing fairly but not fully elastic demand. A
popular assumption is that a firm keeps price constant for an extended
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
196
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 196
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
period of random length, after which the price pops to its value-maximizing
level. Few modern macroeconomic models embody any monetary sector.
Rather, consistent with modern central bank practice, the economy has a
Taylor rule relating the interest rate to the rate of inflation. Finally, models
view households as having preferences that govern labor supply, but they
may permit a varying gap between labor demand and labor supply, on the
view that the wage is sticky in the shorter run but clears the labor market in
the longer run.
I omit consideration of macroeconomic models used in proprietary
forecasting. I do not have access to information about the underlying
economic principles of those models. In particular, I do not comment on
the analysis by Christina Romer and Jared Bernstein, which uses an average of multipliers from “a leading private forecasting firm” and the Federal
Reserve’s FRB/US model (Romer and Bernstein 2009, p. 12). I do find that
their fairly high estimate of the output multiplier is in line with the findings
of a model applied to the conditions of 2009 with the federal funds rate at
its lower bound of zero.
The class of models favored by academic macroeconomists and many
central banks has a neoclassical growth model at its core. With prices
adjusted frequently to firm value–maximizing levels and wages adjusted frequently to market-clearing levels, the economy grows reasonably smoothly
along a full-employment path, with some volatility associated with changing
rates of productivity growth, changing levels of market power, changing
preferences, and other driving forces. A topic of intense debate is how much
of the observed volatility of output and employment would occur without
price and wage stickiness.
Two recent developments in general-equilibrium macroeconomics are
worth noting. First is the development of coherent theories of unemployment, which are replacing oversimplified ideas that unemployment is just
the gap between labor supply and labor demand. Second is the recognition
that the models are missing truly important features of financial markets,
especially the widening of spreads that occurs in a financial crisis and recession between the interest rates that private sector borrowers pay and the
safe government rate.
My discussion of models and their implications for the output multiplier
for government purchases adheres to the general philosophy of the class of
models sketched above. I begin with the neoclassical growth model core.
A single equation from that model—the first-order condition for balancing
consumption of goods and services against work effort—has played a
huge role in the literature on government purchases multipliers over the
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 197
197
ROBERT E. HALL
past 30 years. When that equation is given its full role, as in a simple
neoclassical model, the consumption multiplier for government purchases
is quite negative. Much of the history of commentary on government purchases multipliers looks for alterations in the model that boost the consumption multiplier toward or even above zero, in accord with the empirical
studies that do not generally find very negative values.
The consumption-work trade-off is irrelevant in a sticky-wage model,
because workers can be off the labor supply function implied by the firstorder condition. But an otherwise neoclassical model with a sticky wage
cannot have much of an output multiplier, and it cannot have a nonnegative
consumption multiplier, as I will show.
II.A. The Neoclassical Starting Point
Suppose people have preferences described by the within-period utility
function
(3)
c1 − 1 σ
h1 + 1 ψ
−γ
.
1−1 σ
1+1 ψ
Here σ describes the curvature of utility with respect to consumption of
goods and services, c; it is the intertemporal elasticity of substitution and
the reciprocal of the coefficient of relative risk aversion. The parameter ψ
describes the curvature of utility with respect to the volume of work, h, and
is the Frisch elasticity of labor supply. Finally, the parameter γ controls the
overall disamenity of work.
With the price of goods and services normalized at 1 and a real wage of w,
the first-order condition for the optimal mix of consumption and work is
(4)
wc −1 σ = γh1 ψ .
Under what conditions will an increase in government purchases (or any
other source of higher employment and output) actually raise work effort h?
If work effort does rise, the real wage must fall, given that the capital stock
is a state variable whose level cannot change immediately. For h to rise, the
left-hand side of the equation must rise, despite the fall in the real wage.
The only way for the product to fall is for c−1/σ to rise by a higher proportion
than the wage falls. This rise requires, in turn, that consumption fall.
Much of the history of formal macroeconomics of the past three decades
rests on this issue. In this model any driving force that raises product
demand and thus employment and output must depress consumption,
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
198
Page 198
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
contrary to the evidence and common sense. The real business cycle model
broke the conundrum by invoking a stimulus that raised wages: it took
bursts of productivity growth to be the driving force of employment fluctuations, rather than the changes in product demand that had generally
been the primary driving force in earlier models. But the real business
cycle model implies that an increase in government purchases achieves an
increase in hours of work and output by depressing consumption through
wealth and intertemporal substitution effects. The model is fundamentally
inconsistent with increasing or constant consumption when government
purchases rise.
Parameter values that alleviate but do not avoid the property of consumption declines with higher government purchases are low values of
intertemporal substitution, σ, and high values of the elasticity of labor
supply, ψ. Advocates of the real business cycle model have adopted the
second enthusiastically but have been less keen on low σ, because σ = 1
(log of consumption) is needed to match the absence of a trend in hours of
work as real wages have risen. Another helpful feature of preferences is to
introduce complementarity of consumption and hours, but again this cannot deliver an increase in consumption along with an increase in hours of
work. I discuss complementarity in section II.D.
To see how the basic marginal-rate-of-substitution condition limits
the multiplier, consider the simplest static general-equilibrium model. The
technology is Cobb-Douglas:
y = hα .
(5)
Capital is fixed and normalized at 1. The real wage is the marginal product
of labor:
(6)
w = αh −(1− α ) .
Output is divided between consumption and government purchases g:
(7)
y = c + g.
Combining the first-order condition from equation 4 and the two previous
equations, I get a single equation to describe general equilibrium:
(8)
( y − g)
−1 σ
=
γ 1+α1 ψ −1
y
.
α
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 199
199
ROBERT E. HALL
It is convenient to normalize the model, without loss of generality, so
that output is 1 at a designated level of government purchases g. This
implies
γ = α (1 − g )
(9)
−1 σ
.
Then the output multiplier is
(10)
my =
dy
α
=
.
dg α + σ (1 − g ) (1 − α + 1 ψ )
Because α ≤ 1 and ψ > 0, the conclusion follows, under the assumptions
adopted so far, that the output multiplier cannot exceed 1. Further, the output multiplier is an increasing function of the labor supply elasticity ψ, an
increasing function of the labor elasticity of production α, and a decreasing
function of the consumption curvature parameter σ. Conditions under which
the output multiplier is close to 1 are the following: highly elastic labor
supply (large ψ) and low diminishing returns to labor (α close to 1); high
curvature of utility in consumption (σ close to zero); or government purchases close to all of output (g close to 1).
Because all output is either consumed or purchased by the government,
the consumption multiplier is simply the output multiplier less 1. Thus,
under the assumptions I have made so far, the consumption multiplier is
never positive.
Note that the expansion in output that occurs in this economy with an
increase in government purchases g results in a lower wage: employers
would not be willing to increase employment and lower the marginal product of labor if the cost of labor did not decline. The parameter ψ controls
the response of labor supply to the lower wage. A higher value of ψ results
in a larger decline in hours from the decrease in the wage, in the substitution sense (again, ψ is exactly the Frisch wage elasticity of labor supply).
The reason that a higher value of ψ results in a larger increase in hours
when g increases is the income effect, which also depends on ψ. The consumption curvature parameter σ also enters the income effect. For parameters that bring the multiplier close to 1, the income effect is swamping the
substitution effect. Notice as well that the labor elasticity α enters the output
multiplier because it controls the wage depression accompanying the
increase in output. With α close to 1, diminishing returns are weak and
the substitution effect is correspondingly smaller, so there is less offset to
the income effect.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
200
Page 200
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
The elasticity of the production function with respect to the labor input,
α, is widely believed to be around 0.7. The critical (and controversial)
parameter in the model is ψ. Empirical work with household data suggests
that ψ lies in the range from 0.2 to 1.0 (see the papers cited in the appendix
to Hall 2009). With σ at the fairly standard value of 0.5 and g at 0.2, the
output multiplier is about 0.4, at the low end of the range of empirical
findings, and the consumption multiplier is −0.6, out of line with all of the
empirical evidence.
I will now consider a set of modifications of the model that improve its
match to the evidence. These incorporate, in turn, variations in the markup of
price over cost, unemployment, complementarity of consumption and hours
of work, and a negative response of investment to changes in government
purchases. The last modification requires moving to a dynamic model.
II.B. Endogenous Markup of Price over Cost
The neoclassical model assumes competition in output and labor markets. The New Keynesian branch of macroeconomics drops that assumption in favor of market power in product markets and makes the extent of
market power depend on the state of the economy. Forces, such as higher
government purchases, that expand output also make the economy more
competitive, with a lower markup of price over cost.
New Keynesian and many other macroeconomic models take the product
price as sticky. In a monetary economy, this hypothesis can take the form
of a sticky nominal price level combined with variations in factor prices.
My approach is to continue to normalize the price of output at 1, so that the
implication of price stickiness is that factor prices are inside the competitive
factor-price frontier. Firms have market power. That power is high in slumps
and low in booms; hence, markups are countercyclical. The relationship
between price stickiness and countercyclical markups has been noted by
many authors, notably Julio Rotemberg and Michael Woodford (1992).
Sticky-price models generally derive the variable markup from the Calvo
pricing model and Spence-Dixit-Stiglitz preferences, but I will take it for
now as a primitive feature of the economy. I build this feature into the
earlier model with a constant-elasticity relationship between the markup
and output: µ(y) = y−ω. I continue to normalize the reference level of output,
the point where I take the derivative for the multiplier, at 1. Now the wage
equals the marginal revenue product of labor,
(11)
w=
1
αh −(1− α ) .
y− ω
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 201
201
ROBERT E. HALL
The output multiplier becomes
(12)
my =
dy
α
=
.
dg α + σ (1 − g )[1 − (1 + ω ) α + 1 ψ ]
The more responsive the markup to changes in output (the higher ω), the
higher the output multiplier. Further, the output multiplier can now exceed 1,
and thus the consumption multiplier can be positive. The condition for an
output multiplier above 1 is
(13)
ω>
1− α +1 ψ
.
α
If ψ = 0.5, the markup elasticity ω needed to deliver an output multiplier of 1
is 3.3, far above the plausible range. With ω = 0.5, the output multiplier is
0.5 and the consumption multiplier is −0.5.
II.C. Unemployment and the Employment Function
Even today, many general-equilibrium models struggle to explain the
volatility of employment without explicit consideration of unemployment. But good progress has occurred in this area. Monika Merz (1995)
and David Andolfatto (1996) introduced unemployment as described by
Dale Mortensen and Christopher Pissarides (1994) into otherwise neoclassical models. Blanchard and Galí (2007) did the same for the New
Keynesian model. With a Nash wage bargain, the wage is sufficiently
flexible that fluctuations in driving forces of reasonable volatility cause
almost no movement in unemployment, as Robert Shimer (2005) showed
in an influential paper. Blanchard and Galí introduced sticky, non-Nash
wages to generate realistic unemployment volatility. Hall (2009) developed a more general framework based on a broad family of bargaining
solutions and with standard preferences to replace the linear preferences
in Mortensen-Pissarides.
That framework describes an employment function n(w, λ) that gives
the fraction of the labor force employed (1 minus the unemployment rate).
Here w is the wage in the sense of the marginal product of labor; the actual
compensation paid to workers may differ because of two-part pricing and
wage smoothing. λ is the marginal utility of consumption. Its inclusion as
an argument arises because of the diminishing marginal rate of substitution between consumption and work. A second function, h(w, λ), is the
Frisch supply function for hours of work per employed worker (not to be
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
202
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 202
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
confused with hours per person, the variable considered in models that
disregard unemployment). I assume that an efficient relationship between
worker and employer results in the setting of hours on the basis of the
marginal product of labor, and I show that this assumption results in a
reasonable account of the movements of hours per employed worker. For
the purposes of studying a transitory alteration in the economy such as
countercyclical government purchases, λ can be taken to be roughly constant, so the functions become n(w) and h(w). Further, the size of the labor
force does not change significantly in response to the forces causing the
business cycle, so I can standardize it at 1 and write the total volume of
work effort as n(w)h(w). This object replaces the labor supply function in a
general-equilibrium model.
I take the Frisch elasticity of hours per employed worker—the elasticity
of h(w)—to be 0.7, based on research surveyed in the appendix to Hall
(2009). This elasticity is a cousin of the compensated elasticity of labor
supply and must be nonnegative according to the standard theory of household behavior. This elasticity is far below the level needed to explain the
observed volatility of total hours of work per person.
The employment function n(w) is not the result of household choice.
Rather, as in the Mortensen-Pissarides model, it is determined by the interaction of jobseekers and employers in the labor market. If the marginal
product of labor rises and compensation paid to workers does not rise as
much (compensation is sticky), then employers put more resources into
recruiting workers, the labor market tightens, and unemployment falls. Thus,
with sticky compensation, n(w) is an increasing function of the marginal
product of labor, w. The stickier compensation, the higher the elasticity.
I find that the elasticity is 1.2 (Hall 2009, table 1, p. 300). Compensation
is quite sticky: under a Nash bargain, the elasticity would be only barely
positive.
The elasticity of work effort n(w)h(w) is, accordingly, 1.9. The conclusion of this analysis is that the use of a standard labor supply specification
with a fairly high elasticity, namely, 1.9, properly captures both the lower
elasticity of the choice of hours by employed workers and the elasticity
resulting from sticky compensation in a search-and-matching setup following Mortensen and Pissarides. For almost 30 years, a chorus of criticism
(including, I confess, my voice) fell upon Finn Kydland and Edward Prescott
(1982) and the proponents of general-equilibrium models with elastic
labor supply. Now it turns out that their specification fits neatly into the
Mortensen-Pissarides framework, with Nash bargaining replaced by some
other type of bargaining that results in a sticky level of compensation.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 203
203
ROBERT E. HALL
With the Frisch wage elasticity ψ raised to 1.9, the output multiplier
becomes 0.8 and the consumption multiplier −0.2, an important step toward
realism.
II.D. Consumption-Work Complementarity
Although the empirical finding of a somewhat negative consumption
multiplier is hardly new (see Hall 1986), the model considered here so far
yields consumption multipliers that are rather more negative than those
estimated in empirical studies. One further ingredient, consumption-work
complementarity, helps to close the gap. Florin Bilbiie (2009) shows that
complementarity cannot turn the consumption multiplier positive in models
that lack a negative response of the markup to increases in output, but it
can bring the multiplier close to zero. Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo
(2009) discuss the role of complementarity in connection with variable
markups and cite a number of earlier treatments of this subject for preferences that assume a particular pattern of complementarity.
In the Frisch framework, as laid out in Hall (2009), complementarity
means that goods and services consumption rises when the wage rises,
with marginal utility held constant. Equivalently, it means that the marginal utility of consumption rises when an individual moves from nonwork
to work or when the individual works more hours. I have not found any
studies of the cross effect in a Frisch system or in other representation
of preferences. But the dependence of consumption on work levels, with
wealth or marginal utility held constant, has been the subject of an
extensive recent literature. Mark Aguiar and Erik Hurst (2005) provide a
well-known study of the subject. The “retirement consumption puzzle”—
the drop in consumption of goods and services upon cessation of work—
is resolved nicely by complementarity. A retired person relies more on
home production and less on purchases in the market, given the availability of time previously devoted to work. The same point applies to changes
in consumption during a spell of unemployment, with the possibly important difference that retirement is more likely to be a planned, expected
event than is unemployment. Some of the decline in consumption observed
among the unemployed may be the result of imperfect insurance markets
and lack of liquid savings.
Hall and Paul Milgrom (2008) set out a family of preferences with
complementarity:
(14)
c1 − 1 σ
h1 + 1 ψ
− χc1−1 σ h1+1 ψ − γ
.
1−1 σ
1+1 ψ
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
204
Page 204
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
Positive values of the parameter χ introduce an increase in the marginal
utility of consumption c that depends on hours of work h (provided, as I
assume, σ < 1). I use the following parameter values: σ = 0.4, ψ = 1.54,
χ = 0.334, and γ = 1.1. The Frisch elasticities for these parameter values are
—own-price elasticity of consumption: −0.5
—wage elasticity of hours of work: 1.9
—elasticity of consumption with respect to the wage: 0.4.
See the appendix to Hall (2009) for a discussion of the household-level
evidence on the own-price elasticity of consumption and the cross elasticity.
In the latter case, the evidence relates to the decline in consumption that
occurs at retirement or upon unemployment. Hall and Milgrom show how
to calculate the cross elasticity to match the consumption decline.
With the negative of the elasticity of the markup, ω, at 0.5, the output
multiplier is 0.97 and the consumption multiplier is −0.03, figures easily
consistent with the empirical evidence.
III. Dynamic Modeling
The output multiplier is relatively high in the static model because of the
income effect. In a dynamic version of the model, the analogue of the
income effect is the wealth effect: when people feel poorer because of
current and future government purchases, they work harder. When the
program of purchases is transitory, as I assume throughout this paper,
the wealth effect can be much smaller than the corresponding static income
effect. Put differently, the wealth effect would be comparable to the static
income effect if the increase in purchases were permanent, but if the increase
is transitory, people will smooth their work effort and consumption. They
accomplish the smoothing by investing less. The economy thus pays for
temporary government purchases in part by cutting investment rather than
by increasing output, so the output multiplier is smaller.
To incorporate the investment effect, one needs a dynamic model that
characterizes the investment process. I will use James Tobin’s now-standard
approach, based on the distinction between installed capital and newly produced investment goods. The price of installed capital is q in units of
investment goods, which I take to be the same as consumption goods, in a
one-sector model. The flow of investment equates the marginal benefit of
investment, the price q, to the marginal installation and acquisition cost,
which I take to be linear in the flow of investment as a fraction of the earlier
capital stock:
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 205
205
ROBERT E. HALL
(15)
qt = κ
kt − kt − 1
+ 1.
kt − 1
The parameter κ measures the capital adjustment cost: if κ = 0, q is always 1
and there are no adjustment costs. If κ is large, most fluctuations in the
demand for capital are absorbed by the price of installed capital, q, rather
than causing changes in the amount of installed capital. In that case the
decline in investment when government purchases increase will be small,
and the earlier analysis of a static economy will yield a fairly accurate estimate of the output and consumption multipliers.
Capital rents for the price
(16)
bt = qt −1 ( rt + δ ) − Δqt .
The interest rate rt is the net marginal product of capital; δ is depreciation.
Capital demand in period t equals capital supply as determined in the previous period:
(17)
(1 − α )
yt
= kt − 1 .
μbt
At the beginning of a period, the stock of installed capital is kt−1; people
choose hours of work ht. At the end of the period, output yt becomes
available and is allocated to government purchases gt, consumption ct , and
investment, including adjustment cost, resulting in the new capital stock, kt.
The law of motion for capital is
κ ( kt − kt − 1 )
kt +
= (1 − δ ) kt −1 + yt − ct − gt .
2
kt − 1
2
(18)
I continue to consider only a real model and to embody sticky prices in the
form that matters for my purposes, the countercyclical markup that a sticky
product price implies.
Worker-consumers order their paths of hours and goods consumption
according to the utility function in equation 14. The first-order condition
for the optimal mix of consumption and work is
(19)
wc −1 σ [1 − χ (1 − 1 σ ) h1+1 ψ ] = h1 ψ [ − χ (1 + 1 ψ ) c1−1 σ − γ ].
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
206
Page 206
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
The economy’s discounter is
(20)
mt,t +1 = β
ct−+11σ 1 − χ (1 − 1 σ ) ht1++11 ψ
.
ct−1 σ 1 − χ (1 − 1 σ ) ht1+1 ψ
The Euler equation for consumption is
(21)
(1 + r ) m
t +1
t,t + 1
= 1.
Following a government purchases shock, purchases decline from an
initial level g + g– with a rate of persistence of φ:
(22)
g t = g + gφ t .
Capital at the end of period T is required to be at the economy’s stationary level: kT = k*. For reasonably large T, the result is very close to the
infinite-horizon solution. I use the value k0 = k* for the initial capital
stock before the government purchases shock. I use the solution to the
nonstochastic perfect-foresight model as a (close) approximation to the
impulse response of a stochastic model to an innovation in government
purchases in an AR(1) equation with persistence φ. I take T = 80 quarters, but the model has the turnpike property that makes T essentially
irrelevant to the results as long as it is more than a decade. I take the
parameter κ that controls capital adjustment cost to be 8 at a quarterly
rate, corresponding to 2 at an annual rate, a representative value from the
literature on this subject.
Table 3 gives parameter values for the base case and for a number of
variants, to illustrate the roles of the various features added to the original
neoclassical model. I picked the value of the markup response parameter,
ω = 0.7, to yield a reasonable value of the output multiplier. All the other
parameters are drawn as described earlier from my review of earlier
research.
For the cases described in table 3, table 4 shows some of the properties
of the dynamic model in terms of impulse response functions, comparable
to those shown earlier for the structural VAR results. The first pair of
columns, labeled “On impact,” reports the multipliers, defined as the immediate effects of one dollar of increased government purchases on output or
consumption, in dollars of real GDP. In the base case the multipliers are 0.98
for output and −0.03 for consumption. After four quarters the output effect
becomes smaller, 0.68, and the consumption effect remains essentially the
Source: Author’s calculations.
Base
Constant markup
No adjustment cost
No complementarity
Less elastic labor supply
0.4
0.4
0.4
0.5
0.4
1.54
1.54
1.54
1.9
0.5
Labor supply
elasticity
ψ
0.334
0.334
0.334
0.0
0.334
Complementarity
of work and
consumption
χ
1.103
1.103
1.103
1.102
0.617
Labor weight
γ
8
8
0
8
8
Capital
adjustment
cost
κ
0.7
0.0
0.7
0.7
0.7
Markup
response
ω
11:35 AM
Case
Consumption
curvature
σ
1/26/10
Table 3. Parameter Values for the Neoclassical Model and Variants
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
Page 207
Source: Author’s calculations.
0.98
0.60
0.98
0.92
0.40
Output
multiplier
Output
multiplier
0.68
0.41
0.69
0.65
0.24
Consumption
multiplier
−0.03
−0.16
−0.03
−0.15
−0.25
−0.02
−0.12
−0.02
−0.10
−0.21
Consumption
multiplier
After 4 quarters
0.48
0.28
0.48
0.46
0.13
Output
multiplier
−0.01
−0.10
−0.01
−0.07
−0.18
Consumption
multiplier
After 8 quarters
11:35 AM
Base
Constant markup
No adjustment cost
No complementarity
Less elastic labor supply
Case
On impact
1/26/10
Table 4. Government Purchases Multipliers Derived from Impulse Response Functions
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
Page 208
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
ROBERT E. HALL
11:35 AM
Page 209
209
same, at −0.02; after eight quarters they shrink even further. Recall that the
increase in government purchases declines at a 30 percent annual rate, so
that much of the change in the response is the direct result of the decline in
the stimulus from the extra purchases.
Eliminating the New Keynesian property of a markup ratio that
declines with output and replacing it with a constant markup of zero (that
is, dropping ω from 0.7 to 0; second row of table 4) alters the responses
dramatically. The impact multipliers become 0.60 for output and −0.16 for
consumption, both of which are small relative to the earlier evidence. Again,
these become even smaller as the impulse dies out over four and eight
quarters.
On the other hand, removing adjustment costs for capital formation
(third row of table 4) has essentially no effect. The reason is simple. If
the output multiplier is about 1 and the consumption multiplier is zero, the
effect of government purchases on investment must be about zero (here the
closed-economy assumption is important). To put it differently, one effect
of the government purchases is to drive up the real interest rate and inhibit
investment. The second effect is the accelerator: investment increases
because businesses add capacity to serve the demand for more output. In
the base case the two effects offset each other. Because nothing happens to
investment when government purchases increase, adjustment costs are
irrelevant to their effect on other variables.
The fourth row of table 4 shows that dropping the complementarity of
work and consumption has a small downward effect on the output response
and a larger downward effect on the consumption response, pushing it into
unrealistic territory. Thus, complementarity—a feature of household production and preferences well supported by recent research—helps to make
the model’s properties fit the data.
The bottom row of the table shows the overwhelming importance of
elastic labor supply (including the large part of the elasticity arising from
unemployment) in bringing the model into agreement with the data. With
less elastic labor supply, all the other features of the model, including
the price stickiness that accounts for the variable markup, leave its output
response at about a third of the realistic value and its consumption response
deeply negative. Although I favor modeling the elastic response with a
labor supply function, the New Keynesian literature (not to mention its
Keynesian predecessors) speaks of the same response as wage stickiness.
Some of this distinction is only one of vocabulary, but I will show later
that a sticky wage does not result in as realistic a model as does elastic
labor supply.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
210
11:35 AM
Page 210
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
IV. Other Issues
In this section I address three issues: whether estimates of the government
purchases multiplier are affected by such factors as the frequency of price
adjustment and the response of the central bank; how the estimates change
when nominal interest rates are near their zero lower bound; and whether
they change noticeably when the model includes a wealth effect.
IV.A. Is an Analysis without Consideration
of the Price Level Appropriate?
In most modern macroeconomic models, including all of those to be
discussed in section VII, the central bank intervenes in the economy to
stabilize the price level or the rate of inflation. Consequently, the bank’s
policy rule is part of the model, and the government purchases multipliers
depend on this rule. The more draconian the response to inflation, the
lower the multipliers. The analysis in this paper does not ignore this point
but puts it in the background: the central bank’s policy rule is one of the
determinants of the elasticity ω of the markup of price over cost.
To explore the relationship between the standard New Keynesian model
and the reduced-form approach taken in this paper, based on the negative
response of the markup ratio to output, I created a version of the New
Keynesian model embodying all the same features and parameters as the
benchmark model just discussed, altered to include the Calvo (1983)
sticky-price specification with a parameter θ, the quarterly probability that
a price remains fixed, and an elasticity of demand ⑀ = 5 facing each producer whose price is sticky. The model also includes a standard Taylor rule
governing the path of the price level in relation to the interest rate. The
online appendix to this paper gives a full description and code for the
model.1
In the New Keynesian model, the stickiness of prices is the fundamental
source of variation in the markup of price over cost: such variations occur
when firms are hit by demand surprises that raise marginal cost during the
time when the price is fixed. Marginal cost rises because firms move up
their short-run marginal cost functions, and because the wage rises. Many
New Keynesian models invoke sticky wages as well as sticky prices, but I
continue to rely on a high wage elasticity to explain larger movements in
employment in the face of small changes in wages.
1. Online appendices for all papers in this issue may be found on the Brookings Papers
webpage (www.brookings.edu/economics/bpea) under “Conferences and Papers.”
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 211
211
ROBERT E. HALL
Table 5. Price Persistence, Multipliers, and Markup Elasticities
in a New Keynesian Model
Price
persistencea θ
0.60
0.70
0.80
0.89
0.90
0.95
Output
multiplier
Consumption
multiplier
Elasticity of the
markup ratio ω
0.60
0.62
0.68
0.95
1.02
1.60
−0.21
−0.20
−0.18
−0.07
−0.04
0.20
0.06
0.13
0.29
0.75
0.84
1.24
Source: Author’s calculations.
a. Probability that the price remains fixed in a given quarter.
Table 5 reports the multipliers corresponding to varying degrees of
price stickiness, as controlled by the parameter θ. A value of θ between 0.8
and 0.9 delivers an output multiplier in the range just below 1 and a consumption multiplier that is only barely negative. The implied frequency of
price change is between 20 percent and 10 percent per quarter. Christiano,
Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2009) take θ to be 0.85.
I conclude that the reduced-form approach taken in this paper, based on
a negative elasticity of the markup ratio with respect to output, provides
a reasonable basis for inferring the effects of changes in government
purchases on output and consumption. From the perspective of the issues
studied in this paper, it is not necessary to take separate stands on the
various ingredients of a nominal model, including the frequency of price
adjustment and the response of the central bank. What matters is the reduction in the markup when output expands. The model here is compatible
with any explanation for that negative relationship, including explanations
that do not depend on sticky prices, such as that of Rotemberg and Garth
Saloner (1986).
IV.B. The Importance of the State of the Economy
The output and consumption multipliers are derivatives of two endogenous variables with respect to an exogenous shock. They are not fundamental structural parameters invariant to the state of the economy. Quite
the contrary, the multipliers are themselves endogenous. The state of the
economy in 2009 provides a perfect example. With extreme slack in
the economy and the federal funds rate at essentially zero, there are good
reasons to believe that the government purchases multipliers are higher
than in normal times.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
212
Page 212
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2009) find that the government
purchases multiplier in a New Keynesian model becomes large when the
economy hits the zero nominal interest rate bound. In a model with an
output multiplier of 0.9 in normal times, the multiplier rises to 3.9 when
the nominal bank interest rate hits the zero bound and the central bank
loses the ability to stimulate the economy by cutting that interest rate.
In the simple New Keynesian model of the previous section, the central
bank follows a Taylor rule that increases the nominal interest rate by 1.5 percentage points for each percentage point of inflation. At the zero bound,
the coefficient becomes zero. The output multiplier rises from 0.95 to 1.72
and the consumption multiplier from −0.07 to 0.26.
IV.C. The Wealth Effect
Much of the modern literature on multipliers takes the key difference
between neoclassical real business cycle (RBC) models and traditional models to be the former’s inclusion of a wealth effect on consumption. Galí,
López-Salido, and Vallés (2007, p. 228, footnotes omitted) provide a clear
statement of the standard view of the difference between the two models:
The standard RBC and the textbook IS-LM models provide a stark example of such
differential qualitative predictions. The standard RBC model generally predicts a decline
in consumption in response to a rise in government purchases of goods and services
(henceforth, government spending, for short). In contrast, the IS-LM model predicts
that consumption should rise, hence amplifying the effects of the expansion in government spending on output. Of course, the reason for the differential impact across those
two models lies in how consumers are assumed to behave in each case. The RBC model
features infinitely-lived Ricardian households, whose consumption decisions at any point
in time are based on an intertemporal budget constraint. Ceteris paribus, an increase in
government spending lowers the present value of after-tax income, thus generating a negative wealth effect that induces a cut in consumption. By way of contrast, in the IS-LM
model consumers behave in a non-Ricardian fashion, with their consumption being a function of their current disposable income and not of their lifetime resources. Accordingly, the
implied effect of an increase in government spending will depend critically on how the latter
is financed, with the multiplier increasing with the extent of deficit financing.
A related issue is that some critics of the use of temporary increases
in government purchases have argued that their effect is blunted by the
public’s expectation of higher future taxes. The model says the opposite:
the expectation of higher future taxes lowers wealth, stimulates work
effort, and discourages consumption. The output multiplier is higher and
the consumption multiplier more negative in a model with the wealth
effect than without it. Other critics believe that the public is unaware
of the future burden of higher government purchases and are skeptical of
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 213
213
ROBERT E. HALL
stimulus estimates that include the wealth effect. To evaluate this issue,
I examined the response of the model with elastic labor supply and an
elasticity of the markup with respect to output, ω, of 0.6 to an immediate increase in purchases followed by a decline at a rate of 30 percent
per year. This model embodies the wealth effect. I compared the multipliers in that model with those in an otherwise identical model in which
the increase in immediate purchases was paid back, so to speak, by a
decrease in purchases at the end of the solution period with the same
present value. Recall that the immediate increase is g, the persistence
rate is φ, and the economy’s discount factor is β. The repayment in the
last period is
T
(23)
g
⎛ 1⎞
⎜⎝ β ⎟⎠ 1 − βφ .
This alteration in the model lowers the output multiplier by 0.022 and makes
the consumption multiplier 0.001 point more negative. These changes are
in the expected direction but are trivial in magnitude. I conclude that it
hardly matters whether the public anticipates the future taxes needed to
finance a temporary increase in government purchases. Ricardian neutrality
is irrelevant in this respect.
This calculation also demonstrates the unimportance of the wealth
effect for temporary increases in government purchases. The standard view,
quoted above, applies to permanent increases but not to the type of temporary increase that occurs in a countercyclical stimulus.
V. Sticky Wages
The results so far rely on what I have elsewhere called “equilibrium wage
stickiness” (Hall 2005). The wage and the volume of work together represent an equilibrium in the bargain between worker and employer, but
because the wage responds weakly to changes in labor demand, employers find it desirable to recruit more aggressively when demand is strong;
their efforts tighten the labor market and reduce unemployment. An earlier view of wage stickiness rejects the equilibrium concept and supposes
that the wage can be sticky in the sense of preventing a worker-employer
pair from achieving bilateral efficiency. Hall (2009) argues that this disequilibrium sticky-wage view is unnecessary to an understanding of
employment fluctuations—equilibrium stickiness is enough. Here, on the
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
214
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 214
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
contrary, I explore briefly the implications of an extreme form of disequilibrium sticky wages, namely, a fixed real wage. For a discussion of the
details of a different and less extreme form in New Keynesian models
based on Calvo wage setting, see Jesús Fernández-Villaverde and Juan
Rubio-Ramírez (2009). This version of the model differs from the earlier
version in that the consumption–work effort condition of equation 19 no
longer holds, and the wage w is now fixed at its stationary value for the
baseline level of government purchases. The effect is to make labor supply infinitely elastic at the fixed wage, rather than fairly elastic around a
wage determined by wealth.
The fixed-wage model implies that the output and consumption multipliers are exactly zero. Absent the markup response, this proposition follows
directly from the observation that firms hire up to the point that the marginal
revenue product of capital equals the wage. The response of the markup
does not alter this proposition. Putting the markup response into the profitmaximization condition for the firm’s choice of labor input and restating in
terms of labor input h1 and capital k0 yields what I call the extended labor
demand function:
1
(24)
1 ⎤ 1− α(1+ ω )
⎡
h1 = ⎢αk0(1− α )(1+ ω ) ⎥
.
w⎦
⎣
With k0 at its historical, preshock level, the only potentially endogenous
variable here is the wage. If it is fixed, labor input in the first postshock
period is also fixed, and so output and consumption are fixed.
By contrast, in the baseline model of this paper, where the wage is endogenous, a change in the wage can alter employment and output. Now comes
the surprise: the labor demand function extended to include the markup
response, in the above equation, slopes upward! In the base case α = 0.7
and ω = 0.7, so 1 − α(1 + ω)= −0.19, and the exponent on the wage in the
extended labor demand function is more than 5. The baseline model gets
its brisk response of employment and output from a small wage increase
that stimulates both demand and supply.
In the fixed-wage case, a strong response does emerge once time goes
by and the capital stock expands, thus increasing labor demand. Figure 2
compares the impulse response functions for the fixed-wage and the baseline models. The fixed-wage response builds slowly for an extended period.
Output remains high even 15 years after the shock to government purchases,
many, many years after purchases have returned to normal.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 215
215
ROBERT E. HALL
Figure 2. Impulse Response Functions for the Baseline and Fixed-Wage Models
Response (dollars per initial dollar
of government purchases)
Fixed wage
1.6
1.4
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
Baseline (elastic labor supply)
0.2
12
24
36
Quarters
48
60
72
Source: Author’s calculations.
VI. Departures from the Life-Cycle Model of Consumption
One of Keynes’s contributions to macroeconomic theory was the consumption function, where current consumption depends mainly on current
income. As the life-cycle model became the standard framework for thinking about consumption behavior, researchers developed hybrid models in
which some households have full access to capital markets, and therefore
smooth consumption according to the life-cycle principle, while others—
those who would borrow if they could—are constrained to consume current
income. Despite a quarter century of research within this framework, substantial disagreement prevails about the fraction of consumption governed
by the life-cycle model. Note that the issue is the fraction of consumption,
not the fraction of consumers. Given that more prosperous households are
surely less likely to be constrained, the fraction of constrained consumption is less than the fraction of constrained consumers.
To the extent that the factual premise of this paper holds—that the output
response to government purchases is robust and close to dollar for dollar,
whereas the consumption response is essentially zero—the idea that consumption responds mainly to current income is completely unsupported.
The reason is that the ratio of the consumption response to the output
response is the perfect instrumental variables estimator of the marginal
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
216
Page 216
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
propensity to consume if a simple consumption function links output
(income) and consumption. If one takes the evidence in table 1 seriously,
the marginal propensity to consume is slightly negative and estimated
with precision, provided at least the Korean War is included in the sample. Obviously, a negative marginal propensity to consume is profoundly
inconsistent with the idea of a consumption function, so the appropriate
conclusion is that important forces other than current income, such as the
forces implicit in the life-cycle model, determine consumption. Despite the
problems with inference based on the behavior of consumption during wars,
I think the hypothesis that current income has a large effect on consumption
faces an uphill battle with the data.
The standard view of the government purchases multiplier—as expressed,
for example, in the quote from Galí and coauthors in the previous section—
is that a Keynesian consumption function delivers fairly high multipliers.
If the consumption function reflects borrowing constraints on the
unemployed, some alteration of the labor supply part of the earlier model
is needed: the notion of a constraint takes labor income as exogenous,
not partly the choice of the worker. The development of a full model with
heterogeneous households, some facing more limited choices than discussed
earlier, is beyond the scope of this paper. Instead, I will pair the consumption function with another assumption of many Keynesian models, that of
wage rigidity, as discussed in the previous section. Employers choose total
hours of work, h, so as to equate the marginal revenue product of labor to the
prescribed wage. I drop both the consumption Euler equation (equation 21)
and the first-order condition for labor supply (equation 19) and replace them
with a Solow-style consumption function,
(25)
ct = (1 − s ) yt ,
–. For consistency
and the earlier assumption that the wage is a constant, w
with the other results in this paper, I choose the saving rate s to be its stationary value in the neoclassical model, just under 0.2. Note that this is the
saving rate out of gross output and includes depreciation, which is why it
exceeds normal ideas about net saving, which treat it as saving out of income
net of depreciation.
The relevant equations from the earlier model are the equation for
–,
employment conditional on the wage w (equation 24), evaluated at w = w
and the law of motion of the capital stock,
κ ( kt − kt − 1 )
kt +
= (1 − δ ) kt −1 + yt − ct − gt .
2
kt − 1
2
(26)
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 217
217
ROBERT E. HALL
Figure 3. Impulse Response Functions for the Fixed-Wage Model with Consumption
Proportional to Output
Response (dollars per initial dollar
of government purchases)
0.8
Output response
0.6
0.4
0.2
Consumption response
12
24
36
Quarters
48
60
72
Source: Author’s calculations.
The model behaves as a Solow growth model, converging to stationary
values of output, capital, and consumption, which I take to equal their
values in the baseline model.
Figure 3 shows the impulse response functions for the consumption
function model. Because the model embodies a fixed wage, the immediate
response of both output and consumption is zero. The responses build over
time but are not as strong as in the case of a fixed wage as shown in figure 2.
Not surprisingly, the simple consumption function delivers a distinctly
positive consumption multiplier, not far below the output multiplier. The
intertemporal substitution response that depresses consumption in the model
with life-cycle consumption is absent.
The relationship between this model and the simple expenditure model
of the purchases multiplier is easy to explain. The simple expenditure
model takes investment as exogenous. Letting i denote investment and
neglecting time subscripts,
(27)
y=
i+g
,
s
the standard expenditure solution with multiplier my = 1/s. In contrast, the
consumption function model makes investment endogenous, declining when
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
218
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 218
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
output rises. Government purchases crowd out investment in this model.
Because consumption has to rise by more than 80 percent of the increase in
output, crowding out is severe in the presence of a consumption function.
A number of investigations of the role of partial borrowing constraints,
discussed in the next section, suggest that they can increase the output
multiplier under conditions different from the model studied here, which is
extreme. This model takes wages as fixed for 20 years, and it assumes that
all consumption is tied to current income, contrary to the conclusions of
the literature on borrowing constraints.
VII. Multipliers Inferred from New Keynesian
Structural Models
The term “New Keynesian” refers to the class of models combining a full
treatment of the production side of the economy, life-cycle consumption
behavior, sticky wages, and markup ratios that respond negatively to output
increases because of sticky prices. Another name often used for the class is
dynamic stochastic general-equilibrium or DSGE models. These models
are widely used in recent macroeconomic research, especially at central
banks. Although the characterization of the effects of monetary policy has
been the main use of New Keynesian models, four studies have examined
responses to government purchases.
Galí, López-Salido, and Vallés (2007) consider a fairly standard New
Keynesian model, with one nonstandard element: a fraction of consumers
λ simply consume all their labor income rather than follow the life-cycle
principle. Although these authors also consider a competitive labor market with a flexible wage, I will discuss only their results for a sticky
wage, for the reasons discussed earlier in this paper: a sticky wage appears
to be essential to generate meaningfully positive government purchases
multipliers. The results of Galí and coauthors confirm this proposition.
In their baseline model, they take the quarterly persistence of the effect
of the government purchases shock to be 0.9, about the same as the
annual persistence of 0.7 that I used earlier. At their preferred value of
the fraction of consumption subject to rule-of-thumb behavior, λ = 0.5,
the output multiplier on impact is 1.9 and the consumption multiplier is
1.0 (Galí and others 2007, figure 3, p. 250). With life-cycle consumption
behavior, λ = 0, the output multiplier is 0.75 and the consumption multiplier is slightly negative. Intermediate values of λ come close to matching the consumption multipliers found in the VARs reviewed earlier in
this paper.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 219
ROBERT E. HALL
219
López-Salido and Pau Rabanal (2006) find similar results in a model
based on a leading New Keynesian model, that of Christiano, Eichenbaum,
and Evans (2005). With some consumption governed only by current income
and the remainder by the life-cycle principle, the impact output multiplier
is just above 2 and the consumption multiplier just above 1 (Christiano and
others 2005, figure 1, p. 19). With the standard New Keynesian specification where all consumption follows the life-cycle principle, the output
multiplier is slightly above 1.0 and the consumption multiplier is slightly
negative.
Günter Coenen and Roland Straub (2005) study the New Keynesian
model of Frank Smets and Raf Wouters (2003), an outgrowth of the
Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans model. They consider both the original model and one altered so that about a quarter of consumption tracks
current income rather than following the life-cycle principle. For the
original model, the consumption multiplier is −0.14 on impact, and the
output multiplier is 0.68 (1 plus the consumption multiplier of −0.14 plus
the investment multiplier of −0.18) (Smets and Wouters 2003, figure 1,
p. 457). When about a quarter of consumption is constrained, the consumption multiplier is −0.05 on impact, and the output multiplier is 0.77
(1 plus the consumption multiplier of −0.05 plus the investment multiplier of −0.18).
John Cogan and coauthors (2009) also use the Smets-Wouters New
Keynesian model to measure the output multiplier. Their model assumes
that all consumption follows the life-cycle principle. For the transitory burst
of government purchases in the February 2009 stimulus bill, they find an
output multiplier of about 0.5 (Cogan and others 2009, figure 2, p. 12).
These four papers make similar assumptions about the single most
important feature of a model with respect to multipliers, namely, the
response of the markup ratio to increases in output. The first two illustrate
the importance of the controversial issue of the fraction of consumption
governed by the life-cycle principle. Absent a substantial departure from
the life-cycle principle, the models agree that the output multiplier is
between 0.5 and 1.0 and that the consumption multiplier is around zero,
values consistent with the OLS and VAR evidence.
VIII. Negative Response of the Markup Ratio to Output
Rotemberg and Woodford (1999) provide a complete discussion as of a
decade ago of the many empirical and theoretical issues relating to variations in the markup ratio.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
220
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 220
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
VIII.A. Earlier Research on Cyclical Changes in the Markup
Research on variations in the markup of price over marginal cost falls
into two categories: models where alterations in competition are a driving
force of the business cycle or are part of such a driving force, and models
where markups fall passively when output expands, because product prices
are sticky but some elements of cost are not. For purposes of understanding the effects of fiscal policy, the issue is the markup, not price stickiness
itself. Thus, both strands of research are relevant to the issue of the output
multiplier for government purchases. One easy way to tell the two strands
apart is to see whether sticky prices are derived, as in the first set of models,
or assumed, as in the second. From the perspective of the fiscal issue, it
does not seem to matter which way the model gets to the property of a
countercyclical markup. Rotemberg and Woodford (1999, pp. 1112–29)
survey this literature thoroughly.
VIII.B. Theoretical Models with Countercyclical Markup
Rotemberg and Saloner (1986) launched the modern literature on the
relationship between competition and economic activity. The starting point
is a model of oligopoly in which a collusively determined high price is an
equilibrium because rivals will revert to competition to punish a deviator
who tries to capture a large volume of sales by beating its rivals’ price for
one period. The potential deviator compares the immediate profit in one
period with the present value of its share of the collusive profit. Deviation
is more likely when demand is temporarily strong, so that the immediate
profit exceeds that present value. Some episodes in real-world oligopolies
seem to fit the model.
Rotemberg and Woodford (1992) carried the idea of a declining markup
in a boom over to a general-equilibrium setting. Since the publication
of their well-known paper, it has been understood that a countercyclical
markup is an important ingredient in models that take demand fluctuations
as a driving force.
Miles Kimball (1995) provides an extensive discussion of the role of
markup variation in a sticky-price New Keynesian setting.
Mark Bils (1989) developed a model of countercyclical markups based
on customer loyalty. In an expanding economy where customers are
seeking suppliers of products they have not previously consumed, sellers
compete aggressively and customers enjoy low prices. Markups are low.
In a slump, customers buy from their established suppliers and do not look
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 221
221
ROBERT E. HALL
for suppliers of new goods. Sellers respond by setting higher prices to
reflect the less elastic demand of their customer base.
Chris Edmond and Laura Veldkamp (2009) consider the effect of changes
in the distribution of income over the business cycle. They conclude that
booms are periods when income shifts toward lower-income consumers
with more elastic demand, so that the optimal markups of sellers fall. To the
extent that increases in government purchases compress the distribution of
income in the same way as other driving forces, this mechanism would support the assumption in this paper about the negative relationship between
output and markups.
VIII.C. Empirical Research on the Cyclical Movements
of the Markup Ratio
If the markup ratio falls in booms and rises in recessions, the share of
income captured by labor should rise in booms and fall in recessions, given
that the markup adds to the income of business owners. In other words,
labor’s share should be procyclical. To formalize this idea, note that marginal cost is
w
,
∂Y ∂L
(28)
where w is the wage, Y is output, and L is labor input. This relationship
comes from the envelope theorem property that a cost-minimizing firm is
indifferent among increases in any of its inputs. Then the markup ratio µ is
μ=
(29)
p
w
∂Y ∂L
=
pY L ∂Y
wL Y ∂L
=
α
,
s
where α is the elasticity of output with respect to labor input and s is the
share of labor compensation wL in total revenue pY. If the elasticity α is
constant—the Cobb-Douglas case—the intuition about the relationship
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
222
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 222
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
Figure 4. Markup Ratio and Employment, 1948–2009
Index
Percent
1.04
1.02
Cobb-Douglas index of the markup ratioa (left scale)
105
1.00
0.98
0.96
100
0.94
0.92
95
0.90
0.88
0.86
Employment rateb (right scale)
90
1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005
Source: Author’s calculations.
a. Reciprocal of the Bureau of Labor Statistics index of the labor share of income.
b. One minus the unemployment rate.
between labor’s share and the markup is confirmed: a countercyclical
markup requires a procyclical labor share.
To check this proposition against U.S. data, I construct two series
from Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) data. One is the reciprocal of the
BLS index of the labor share (BLS series PRS84006173), which I call the
Cobb-Douglas index of the markup ratio. The other is the employment
rate, which is 100 minus the standard unemployment rate (BLS series
LNS14000000). According to the simplest version of the countercyclical
markup hypothesis, the markup index should move in the opposite direction
from the employment rate: as employment grows in a boom, the markup
index should decline.
Figure 4 shows the two series. Although their relationship is far from
systematic, it is clear that they tend to move in the same direction: booms
are times when the markup index rises along with employment, and recessions are times when the markup index falls with employment. To put it
differently, business owners’ share of income does not fall in booms, on
account of lower markups; rather, it rises. The two most recent expansions
are the leading examples of declining labor and rising business shares; the
markup index reached an all-time high at the most recent cyclical peak at
the end of 2007.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
ROBERT E. HALL
11:35 AM
Page 223
223
Figure 4 is only a first cut at testing the countercyclical markup hypothesis. Research has focused on two factors omitted from the figure. One
is the measurement of the labor share of compensation. In the numerator
of the share, wL, the appropriate measure of the wage is the marginal
cost to the firm of adding another hour of work. If the incremental hour is
more expensive than the average hour, the use of the average wage in the
numerator will understate the true value of labor’s share. If the understatement were the same in booms and slumps, it would not affect the
conclusion to be drawn from the figure. But if the incidence of higher
marginal wages is greater in booms than in slumps, the properly calculated share will be less countercyclical than the one based on the average
wage, and the Cobb-Douglas index will be less procyclical or possibly
even countercyclical, as the hypothesis requires. Bils (1987) pursued this
approach.
The second factor omitted from the figure is variation in the elasticity
of the production function, α. If the elasticity of substitution between
labor and capital is less than 1, the elasticity falls if the labor-capital ratio
rises: low substitution means that production saturates in one input if that
input rises relative to another. The markup ratio is the elasticity divided
by the labor share. If the elasticity falls more than in proportion to the
labor share as the economy expands, the true markup ratio could fall
even though the Cobb-Douglas index of the markup ratio rises. Christopher Nekarda and Ramey (2009) pursue this approach. They conclude
that the variation in the labor elasticity of the production function with an
elasticity of substitution of 0.5 is insufficient to deliver a countercyclical
markup ratio.
Bils (1987) estimated the cyclical movements in the markup ratio by
estimating the changes in the marginal cost of labor and applying the
envelope theorem to infer changes in the marginal cost of output. He found
that a larger fraction of workers are subject to the 50 percent overtime
premium requirement of the Fair Labor Standards Act in booms than in
recessions. Given that employers could have avoided the increase in the
marginal cost of labor by using more of other factors, but did not, he inferred
a corresponding increase in the marginal cost of output. Then he found that
prices are not as cyclical as marginal cost, leading to the inference that the
markup of price over marginal cost must shrink in booms and widen in
recessions. Nekarda and Ramey (2009) revisit Bils’s findings in much the
same framework, but with new, broader data and sufficient alterations to
reverse the finding in favor of procyclical markup ratios. They discuss evidence that the effective overtime premium is not the statutory 50 percent that
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
224
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 224
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
Bils used, but rather may be 25 percent. They also question the definition
of the business cycle that Bils employed. Extension from manufacturing to
the entire economy appears to be the most important factor distinguishing
their work from Bils’s.
The framework in Bils’s and in Nekarda and Ramey’s work is robust
in a number of important ways. First, it makes no assumptions about the
supply of capital services. The results apply with any type or magnitude
of capital adjustment costs and variable utilization of installed capital
(see Rotemberg and Woodford 1999, p. 1079). Second, they apply for any
type of pricing, including customer pricing where the choice of the price
depends on complicated intertemporal factors. The price is taken as data.
Customer pricing should be visible in the data as higher profits and lower
labor shares in slack markets, when firms are exploiting their installed
base. Firms should forgo profit in strong markets, when it pays to set prices
low to sign up new customers who will remain loyal when conditions
weaken.
One important factor bearing on the measurement of cyclical fluctuations in markup ratios has escaped empirical consideration so far, to my
knowledge. Employers may smooth wage payments to their workers rather
than pay a wage equal to current marginal revenue product, as assumed in
the research on the cyclical behavior of the labor share. Jonathan Thomas
and Tim Worrall (1988) present a representative model where employers
insure workers against some of the idiosyncratic risk of working for a
particular firm. In their model the wage payment remains constant as
long as it remains within the bargaining set of the worker and the firm. For
employment relationships with substantial match-specific capital, the wage
can remain constant despite large changes in demand for the firm’s products. The result is a substantial bias in favor of a countercyclical labor share
and thus a procyclical markup ratio. Although this issue is well understood,
no good solution has appeared so far.
Pissarides (2009) surveys the literature on wage flexibility and finds a
strong consensus that the wages of newly hired workers are more sensitive
to the business cycle than are the wages of continuing workers. This finding
supports the hypothesis of wage smoothing.
I conclude that the cyclical behavior of the labor share does not provide direct support for the hypothesis of a countercyclical markup ratio.
The simple Cobb-Douglas markup ratio derived from the labor share is
distinctly procyclical. Attempts to adjust it through improved measurement
of the marginal wage and through consideration of fluctuations in the labor
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 225
ROBERT E. HALL
225
elasticity of the production function do not seem to deliver big enough
adjustments to overcome this procyclical character. In the absence of effective adjustments for wage smoothing, however, I believe the hypothesis of
a countercyclical markup ratio is still an open issue.
VIII.D. Indirect Evidence on the Cyclical Behavior
of the Markup Ratio
Bils and James Kahn (2000) use inventory movements to shed light on
the cyclical movements of marginal cost. Earlier research, based on a fixed
target ratio of inventories to sales, had concluded that procyclical inventory
investment showed that marginal cost falls in booms, because otherwise
firms would schedule the investment during times when production was
cheap, in times of low output. Bils and Kahn demonstrate that the movements of marginal cost cannot be big enough to induce such rescheduling
of production. They go on to show that countercyclical markups do alter
inventory holding cost enough over the cycle to explain the movements
of inventories, if the target inventory-sales ratio is itself sensitive to the
holding cost, given an extreme assumption about the cost of labor. The
assumption is that all of the procyclical movement of measured productivity is actually variation in work effort. Under this assumption, labor becomes
cheap in booms of the type that last occurred in the early 1980s, in the
recovery following the recession of 1981–82. That assumption is not only
extreme but unverifiable. In any case it fails to account for the events of the
following three business cycles, when productivity rose during recessions.
It strains credulity that people were working harder than usual in the troughs
of 1991, 2001, and today.
Research on the response of prices to cost increases has some bearing
on the behavior of the markup ratio. To the extent that prices remain fixed
when costs rise, the markup ratio falls. As I noted earlier, models incorporating the popular Calvo price-stickiness mechanism have this property.
Bils and Yongsung Chang (2000) studied highly disaggregated prices. They
found stronger responses of prices to changes in materials and fuel costs
than to changes in wages, productivity, and output (taken as a measure of the
position of the firm on its marginal cost schedule). The weaker response to
wages is consistent with wage smoothing, which introduces an error of
measurement. The quick response to certain categories of cost is inconsistent
with the Calvo model. Bils and Chang favor theories of price stickiness
based on modern limit pricing models, where firms deter entry of rivals by
depressing the profits available to entrants.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
226
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 226
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
Table 6. Effects of the February 2009 Stimulus Measure and of an Alternative,
Front-Loaded Measure
Item
Actual stimulus purchases, fiscal year
(billions of dollars)
Actual stimulus purchases, calendar yeara
(billions of dollars)
GDP (billions of dollars)
Actual stimulus purchases, calendar year
(percent of GDP)
Effect on GDP (percent)
Hypothetical front-loaded stimulus purchases,
calendar year (percent of GDP)
Effect on GDP (percent)
2009
2010
2011
Sum
34.8
110.7
76.3
221.8
62.5
102.1
57.2
221.8
13,700
0.46
14,043
0.73
14,604
0.39
1.57
1.10
0.71
1.28
0.50
0.70
0.35
3.08
1.56
1.35
0.94
0.62
2.90
Sources: Congressional Budget Office; author’s calculations.
a. A small amount of purchases, projected by the Congressional Budget Office to occur in fiscal 2012,
is omitted from the figure for calendar 2011.
IX. Application to the Government Purchases Stimulus
of 2009
The fiscal stimulus measure passed in February 2009 included increases
in federal purchases of goods and services. The top row of table 6 gives
the Congressional Budget Office’s estimates of likely purchases under
the measure by fiscal year (October through September). The second row
restates the figures by calendar year, assuming equal spending within the
fiscal year by quarter. The third row gives rough estimates of GDP for the
three years 2009, 2010, and 2011, and the fourth row states the stimulus
purchases as percents of GDP. The fifth row shows the results of inserting
the fourth row into the model with the preferred parameter values. These are
the base case values in table 3, but with the markup-response parameter ω
set at 1.29 to match the response in the New Keynesian model at the
constant nominal interest rate of zero that prevailed when the policy was
adopted in February 2009. I substitute the fourth row into the model
in place of the exponentially declining pattern used in the earlier runs
of the model. This row shows the powerful anticipation effects in the
model, based on the assumption that, as of the beginning of 2009, decisionmakers believed that purchases of the magnitude shown in the table would
materialize in the three years. The purchases stimulus raises GDP in 2009
by 1.10 percent, with further effects of 1.28 percent in 2010 and 0.70 percent in 2011. The model disputes the common view that the long ramp-up
in purchases will delay the effects of the stimulus until long after they would
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
11:35 AM
ROBERT E. HALL
Page 227
227
be most beneficial. Rather, announcing future purchases delivers immediate stimulus. Back-loading is a desirable feature of a stimulus program. All
this is according to a simple model that overlooks many potentially important features of the economy. The calculations also rest critically on the
projection that the stimulus purchases will ramp down in 2011 and end in
2012, a proposition that is under dispute.
The bottom two rows of table 6 show the effects of an alternative, frontloaded time pattern of stimulus purchases. I assume, as in the earlier runs
of the model, that a burst of new purchases dies off at 30 percent per year
rather than rising in the second year. Unlike in the earlier runs, here the
purchases go to zero in the fourth year, to make the policy more comparable to the three-year horizon of the February 2009 stimulus measure. I
standardize the front-loaded policy to have the same total amount of purchases over the three years. The effect in 2009 is somewhat larger in the
front-loaded case than in the actual back-loaded policy, but the three-year
sum of the effects on GDP of the front-loaded policy is smaller. The model
suggests that the much-criticized slow ramp-up of the stimulus was actually
beneficial.
Table 6 makes it clear that the purchases component of the stimulus
package passed in February 2009 could not possibly have closed much of
the shortfall of GDP from normal levels. The shortfall is around $1.2 trillion
for 2009. No conceivable multiplier could permit $62.5 billion of added
purchases to close much of a gap of that magnitude.
X. Concluding Remarks
I am persuaded that GDP rises by roughly the amount of an increase in
government purchases, and possibly rather more when monetary policy
is passive because of the zero bound. I am aware that neoclassical models
have no hope of explaining such a high multiplier, even if extended to include
unemployment along the lines discussed in this paper. I am impressed by
the success of New Keynesian models in matching the observed multiplier,
because these models were developed for rather different purposes and
estimated using data containing essentially no variation in government
purchases.
Notwithstanding this success, I am concerned about the weak factual
support for the key mechanism underlying the New Keynesian explanation
of the multiplier, namely, the decline in the markup ratio that accompanies
an increase in output. The behavior of profit margins suggests on its face
that the markup ratio rises with output. The only plausible way for falling
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
228
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 228
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
markups to fit the data is through a lot of wage smoothing. I think there is
room for new ideas outside the New Keynesian framework to explain the
high value of the multiplier along with other mysteries about aggregate
economic behavior.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I am grateful to the editors and to my Brookings
Panel discussants, and to Robert Barro, Susanto Basu, Jordi Galí, Jonathan
Parker, Fabrizio Perri, Valerie Ramey, and Ricardo Reis for guidance and
comments. A file containing the calculations is available on my website.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
ROBERT E. HALL
11:35 AM
Page 229
229
References
Aguiar, Mark, and Erik Hurst. 2005. “Consumption versus Expenditure.” Journal
of Political Economy 113, no. 5 (October): 919–48.
Andolfatto, David. 1996. “Business Cycles and Labor-Market Search.” American
Economic Review 86, no. 1: 112–32.
Barro, Robert J., and Charles J. Redlick. 2009. “Macroeconomic Effects from
Government Purchases and Taxes.” Working Paper no. 15369. Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (September).
Bilbiie, Florin O. 2009. “Nonseparable Preferences, Fiscal Policy Puzzles and
Inferior Goods.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 41, no. 2–3: 443–50.
Bils, Mark. 1987. “The Cyclical Behavior of Marginal Cost and Price.” American
Economic Review 77, no. 5 (December): 838–55.
———. 1989. “Pricing in a Customer Market.” Quarterly Journal of Economics
104, no. 4 (November): 699–718.
Bils, Mark, and Yongsung Chang. 2000. “Understanding How Price Responds to
Costs and Production.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy
52: 33–77.
Bils, Mark, and James A. Kahn. 2000. “What Inventory Behavior Tells Us about
Business Cycles.” American Economic Review 90, no. 3 (June): 458–81.
Blanchard, Olivier, and Jordi Galí. 2007. “Real Wage Rigidities and the New
Keynesian Model.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 39, no. 1: 35–65.
Blanchard, Olivier, and Roberto Perotti. 2002. “An Empirical Characterization of
the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending and Taxes on Output.”
Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, no. 4: 1329–68.
Calvo, Guillermo A. 1983. “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework.”
Journal of Monetary Economics 12, no. 3 (September): 383–98.
Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles L. Evans. 2005.
“Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy.”
Journal of Political Economy 113, no. 1: 1–45.
Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo. 2009. “When Is the
Government Spending Multiplier Large?” Working Paper no. 15394. Cambridge,
Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research (October).
Coenen, Günter, and Roland Straub. 2005. “Does Government Spending Crowd in
Private Consumption? Theory and Empirical Evidence for the Euro Area.”
International Finance 8, no. 3: 435–70.
Cogan, John F., Tobias Cwik, John B. Taylor, and Volker Wieland. 2009. “New
Keynesian versus Old Keynesian Government Spending Multipliers.” Working
Paper no. 14782. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research
(March).
Edmond, Chris, and Laura Veldkamp. 2009. “Income Dispersion and Countercyclical Markups.” Journal of Monetary Economics 56, no. 6: 791–804.
Fernández-Villaverde, Jesús, and Juan F. Rubio-Ramírez. 2009. “A Baseline
DSGE Model.” University of Pennsylvania (October).
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
230
1/26/10
11:35 AM
Page 230
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Fall 2009
Galí, Jordi, J. David López-Salido, and Javier Vallés. 2007. “Understanding the
Effects of Government Spending on Consumption.” Journal of the European
Economic Association 5, no. 1: 227–70 (March).
Hall, Robert E. 1986. “The Role of Consumption in Economic Fluctuations.” In
The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change, edited by Robert J.
Gordon. University of Chicago Press for the National Bureau of Economic
Research.
———. 2005. “Employment Fluctuations with Equilibrium Wage Stickiness.”
American Economic Review 95, no. 1 (March): 50–65.
———. 2009. “Reconciling Cyclical Movements in the Marginal Value of Time
and the Marginal Product of Labor.” Journal of Political Economy 117, no. 2
(April): 281–323.
Hall, Robert E., and Paul R. Milgrom. 2008. “The Limited Influence of Unemployment on the Wage Bargain.” American Economic Review 98, no. 4 (September):
1653–74.
Kimball, Miles S. 1995. “The Quantitative Analytics of the Basic Neomonetarist
Model.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27, no. 4, part 2 (November):
1241–77.
Kydland, Finn E., and Edward C. Prescott. 1982. “Time to Build and Aggregate
Fluctuations.” Econometrica 50, no. 6 (November): 1345–70.
López-Salido, J. David, and Pau Rabanal. 2006. “Government Spending and
Consumption-Hours Preferences.” Working Paper no. 02/2006. Barcelona: la
Caixa (November).
Merz, Monika. 1995. “Search in the Labor Market and the Real Business Cycle.”
Journal of Monetary Economics 36, no. 2: 269–300.
Mortensen, Dale T., and Christopher A. Pissarides. 1994. “Job Creation and Job
Destruction in the Theory of Unemployment.” Review of Economic Studies 61,
no. 3: 397–415.
Mountford, Andrew, and Harald Uhlig. 2008. “What Are the Effects of Fiscal
Policy Shocks?” Working Paper no. 14551. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau
of Economic Research (December).
Nekarda, Christopher J., and Valerie A. Ramey. 2009. “The Cyclical Behavior of
the Price-Cost Markup.” University of California, San Diego (July).
Perotti, Roberto. 2008. “In Search of the Transmission Mechanism of Fiscal Policy.”
In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2007, edited by Daron Acemoglu, Kenneth
Rogoff, and Michael Woodford. MIT Press.
Pissarides, Christopher A. 2009. “The Unemployment Volatility Puzzle: Is Wage
Stickiness the Answer?” Econometrica 77, no. 5: 1339–69.
Ramey, Valerie A. 2009. “Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It’s All in
the Timing.” Working Paper no. 15464. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau
of Economic Research (October).
Romer, Christina, and Jared Bernstein. 2009. “The Job Impact of the American
Recovery and Reinvestment Plan” (January). Washington: Obama-Biden Transition Project. otrans.3cdn.net/45593e8ecbd339d074_l3m6bt1te.pdf.
11941-07_Hall_rev2.qxd
1/26/10
ROBERT E. HALL
11:35 AM
Page 231
231
Rotemberg, Julio J., and Garth Saloner. 1986. “A Supergame-Theoretic Model
of Price Wars during Booms.” American Economic Review 76, no. 3 (June):
390–407.
Rotemberg, Julio J., and Michael Woodford. 1992. “Oligopolistic Pricing and
the Effects of Aggregate Demand on Economic Activity.” Journal of Political
Economy 100, no. 6 (December): 1153–1207.
———. 1999. “The Cyclical Behavior of Prices and Costs.” Chapter 16 in Handbook of Macroeconomics, vol. 1B, edited by John B. Taylor and Michael
Woodford. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Shimer, Robert. 2005. “The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and
Vacancies.” American Economic Review 95, no. 1: 24–49.
Smets, Frank, and Raf Wouters. 2003. “An Estimated Dynamic Stochastic General
Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area.” Journal of the European Economic
Association 1, no. 5 (September): 1123–75.
Thomas, Jonathan, and Tim Worrall. 1988. “Self-Enforcing Wage Contracts.”
Review of Economic Studies 55, no. 4 (October): 541–53.