* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download The Economics of Austerity and the Vicious Spirals of Greece
Debtors Anonymous wikipedia , lookup
Government debt wikipedia , lookup
Household debt wikipedia , lookup
European debt crisis wikipedia , lookup
Public finance wikipedia , lookup
1998–2002 Argentine great depression wikipedia , lookup
Greek government-debt crisis wikipedia , lookup
Greek government-debt crisis countermeasures wikipedia , lookup
The Economics of Austerity and the Vicious Spirals of Greece Nikolai Vike Master´s thesis for the degree Master of Economic Theory and Econometrics Department of Economics UNIVERSITY OF OSLO May 2016 II The Economics of Austerity and the Vicious Spirals of Greece III © Nikolai Vike 2016 The Economics of Austerity and the Vicious Spirals of Greece Nikolai Vike http://www.duo.uio.no/ Trykk: Reprosentralen, Universitetet i Oslo IV Summary After Greece joined the European Monetary Union in 2001 the country accumulated many macroeconomic and financial vulnerabilities. Easy access to international funds at low borrowing costs in combination with high economic growth reduced the real value of debt and stimulated to increased borrowing by governments in several euro-countries in order to finance fiscal deficits which further worsened their current-account deficits, especially in Greece and Portugal. Greece’s large and negative current-account balance made the country especially prone to a financial crisis as the country relied heavily on foreign capital inflows. After the financial crisis in 2008, capital inflows into Greece froze and the country had to reduce its deficits. In 2009, new revisions about earlier reported macroeconomic numbers where revealed and they turned out to be much worse than earlier reported. Fiscal mismanagement and deception through misreported statistics throughout the period from 2001 when Greece joined the euro harmed investor confidence when the true numbers were revealed, hence increasing borrowing costs and raised the spreads on sovereign bonds. The sharp decline in capital inflows from surplus countries in combination with soaring interest rates on sovereign debt made it impossible for Greece to re-pay its debt. Since then, Greece has received three bailout packages from the IMF and the European community. The loans where disbursed in smaller amounts conditional on whether Greece managed to satisfy several conditionality criteria which were included in the deal. Greece had to reach strict fiscal targets underway which forced the country to implement a mix of structural reforms and fiscal austerity. The goal of this thesis is to analyse and discuss the effectiveness and risks associated with such policy in crisis-stricken Greece, using two different macroeconomic models. Based on the standard definition of sustainable debt by the IMF, chapter two shows in this model with a risk premium extension by Mehlum (2012) that, by increasing the primary surplus through austerity in order to achieve a sustainable debt level, interest rates on bonds will increase as a response to the austerity and the uncertainty that such measures represent. By extending the model to include a negative relationship between austerity and economic growth, the model contains an unstable equilibrium at a lower level of the debt stabilizing primary surplus than otherwise. The model can be used to show that a significant debt relief could eliminate the unstable equilibria and the threat of V a vicious spiral in the market for sovereign debt. However, in the extended version of the model this is not the case. With a negative relationship between austerity and growth, an unstable equilibrium still exists even after the debt relief. Thus, any significant adverse economic shock to any of the variables in the model could force Greece back into difficulties. The model implies that, in order to avoid a vicious spiral in the market for sovereign debt, Greece needs a debt restructuring in order to stay away from the crisis zone where risk premiums and growth reductions are continuous threats. In order to remain in the good and stable equilibrium, Greece needs economic growth. The model shows how the ECB instrument of outright monetary transactions could eliminate the bad equilibrium by promising to intervene in the market for sovereign debt and secure a maximum price on bonds. The very existence of the instrument could eliminate the fear of a vicious spiral and the promise of intervention could be enough. However, the extended version of the model shows that, as long as there is a negative relationship between the debt stabilizing primary surplus and growth, the promise of intervention is no longer enough and the ECB could be forced to intervene. According to Gali et al. (2007), Christiano et al. (2011), DeLong and Summers (2012), Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) among many others, there is much to gain from fiscal stimulus during a recession as the fiscal multiplier exceeds unity. Based on a Keynesian model as shown in Holden (2015), chapter three shows how the extraordinary circumstances of the Greek crisis might result in a distress premium which somewhat offsets the positive effects from debt-financed fiscal stimulus. The interlinked crises of sovereign debt, growth and banking, in combination with the insecurity and distress associated with a possible Grexit, could give rise to so much distress that any debt-financed fiscal stimulus could loose its effect through increased distress premiums. Normally, as shown by DeLong and Summers (2012), fiscal stimulus during a recession will increase expected inflation and reduce the risk spreads - further reducing the real interest rate. However, the IS-DP-model could imply the opposite. Next, by using a model by Mehlum (2014), chapter three further discusses how austerity during a recession could result in a total collapse of the economy as a result of continuously increased recession premiums. Fiscal austerity could also reduce the beneficial effects from the ECB instruments of targeted longer-term refinancing operations and the corporate sector purchase programme. The ECB is increasing supply of credit in an environment where fiscal austerity depresses demand. Fiscal austerity also brings with it severe political and social effects. As argued by Sinn (2014), even though fiscal austerity could improve Greek competitiveness if also surplus countries are willing to simultaneously reduce their advantage in trade, differential inflation could lead to a rebalanced eurozone. But this is difficult to achieve in a monetary union with a central bank that follows a mandate of achieving price stability. This thesis suggests that fiscal austerity during a recession implies several risks and should be delayed VI until Greece is no longer threatened by all the possible adverse effects discussed throughout. The Greek crisis contains so many interlinked vulnerabilities that a solution calls for bold and coordinated measures beyond austerity. Any beneficial effects that austerity might imply could in all likelihood not be achievable in a distressful economy threatened by vicious spirals and social strife. VII Preface Even though writing this thesis has been a demanding challenge, it has most of all been an enjoyable and inspiring time. The process brought me from writing my basic bulletpoints at Blindern in early January to proudly making my final notes while sitting in an Athenian garden-café with a good view over the Acropolis in late April. When I found myself among the monuments of the Acropolis or in front of the Greek Parliament it really hit me how ironic it is that Greece - the birthplace of democracy - is now the European center stage of economic and political drama. First of all I would like to thank my supervisor, Professor Halvor Mehlum, for helping me formulate a research question which perfectly fitted my interests and ideas, and for his excellent guidance throughout the semester. I would like to thank my brother, Magnus Ripegutu Vike, for sharing his linguistic expertise. I would also like to thank my fellow students and good friends, Snorre Solli, Kjetil Tveit Moen, and Suzanna Rye for commenting on earlier drafts of the thesis and for kind and motivating words throughout the process. VIII Contents List of Figures X List of Tables XII 1 Introduction 1 2 The Greek Crisis and Recovery: Fiscal Corrections with Adverse Effects in the Market for Sovereign Debt 4 2.1 Fiscal Aspects of Monetary Integration: Why the Experiment Should Work 4 2.2 What Went Wrong? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 2.3 An Overview of the Greek Debt Crisis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 2.3.1 An Unbalanced Eurozone 7 2.3.2 Greece after 2007 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 10 2.4 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The Sustainability of the Greek Sovereign Debt . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 2.4.1 Examples of Models of Debt Crises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 2.4.2 The Algebra of Sustainable Debt and Some Theories on Debt Accumulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19 2.4.3 The Vicious Spiral between Investor Confidence, Growth, and Sustainability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 2.4.4 Outright Monetary Transactions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 3 Vicious Spirals in the Real Economy 3.1 32 The Effectiveness of Fiscal Stimulus during Crises . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 3.1.1 The Fiscal Multiplier . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 3.1.2 The Interlinked Crises of Greece and the Distress Premium . . . . . 35 3.2 Fiscal Austerity and Prior Actions: Distortionary Tax Increases and Government Spending Cuts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41 3.3 Fiscal Austerity: A Temporary Recession or Another Vicious Spiral? . . . 44 3.4 3.3.1 The Fiscal Multiplier and the G-T Contradiction . . . . . . . . . . 44 3.3.2 The Recession Premium and the Armoury of the ECB . . . . . . . 46 Expansionary Fiscal Contractions and the Confidence Fairy . . . . . . . . . 49 IX 3.5 3.6 Beyond the Keynesian Effects: Social and Political Effects of Austerity in a Recession . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52 The Way Ahead . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54 4 Conclusion 58 Bibliography 62 Appendices 68 A The Model 69 X List of Figures 2.1 2.2 Source: Eurostat. Average general government budget balance between 2003-2007 as percent of GDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 Source: Eurostat. Current Accounts in the Eurozone in 2007 as percent of GDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 2.3 Source: Macrobond. Quarterly evolution of Greek public debt . . . . . . . 12 2.4 Source: Macrobond. Greek unemployment rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 2.5 Source: Macrobond. 10-year yields on government bonds among four european countries . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 2.6 Source: Eurostat. Evolution of Greek gross government debt as percent of GDP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 2.7 The possibilities of a vicious spiral and the effects of a debt relief in the case of (i) fixed rate of interest (ii) risk premium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26 2.8 Alternative (iii): The vicious spiral between investor confidence, growth, and sustainability and the effects of a debt relief . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 2.9 The effects of Outright Monetary Transactions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29 3.1 Typical (Y, i)-diagram with a fixed exchange rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 3.2 IS-DP: The effect of a positive shock to government expenses with distress premium in a monetary union . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40 3.3 Source: European Commission AMECO database. The evolution of indirect taxes, direct taxes and social contributions in Greece as percent of GDP. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42 3.4 Source: European Commission AMECO database. The evolution of Greek total general government expenditures as percent of GDP between 2008-2016. 43 3.5 Source: European Commission AMECO database. The convergence between Greek total expenses and revenues as percent of GDP between 2008 - 2016. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44 3.6 IS-RP: The effect of a negative shock to government expenses with an endogenous recession premium in a monetary union . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47 XI List of Tables 2.1 Source: The Bank of Greece, Eurostat, and AMECO. Economic Statistic Table for Greece between 2007-2016 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16 XII Chapter 1 Introduction The Greek debt crisis led the country into a recession in late 2009 with a debt-to-GDP ratio at an unsustainable level. As a member country of the European Monetary Union (EMU) Greece could not use monetary policy as a stabilizing tool and was therefore left with internal devaluation after the financial crisis hit Europe. The resulting sharp decline in wages and GDP growth made it even more difficult for Greece to honour its debt. Greece was therefore forced to negotiate an adjustment programme in 2010 in order to receive a bailout package from other European governments and the IMF (International Monetary Fund). But Greece fell into deeper recession and the first bailout package would later be followed by two more. The programmes included several conditionality criteria of structural reforms where fiscal austerity was inevitable. Those programmes were supposed to improve the unsustainable debt level, reduce the primary deficits, safeguard financial stability and modernize the State. While the programme did result in lower primary deficits, it also led to social and political turmoil and further macroeconomic instability. From 2009 and up until the end of 2015, primary deficits have been reduced from 10 to 3 percent of GDP. However, during the same period unemployment rose from 12.7 percent to 25.1 percent and wages were cut. In addition, bond yields soared while the debt-toGDP ratio continued to increase and real GDP growth continued to decline, as if there was a vicious spiral. Every country that spend beyond their means will eventually face a period of cuts. But as the Greek debt crisis has shown - austerity pushed too far may create significantly adverse effects and disturbances during the period of adjustment. According to the classical Keynesian theory, cuts or increases in taxes and government expenses are driven by a multiplier which further magnifies the original action. Thus, countries facing a downturn should use expansionary fiscal policy, and use contractionary fiscal policy only to cool down an overheated economy. However, in order to minimize the amount of financial aid, Greece’s creditors such as the IMF and the European Financial Stability Facility (which later evolved into the current European Stability Mechanism (ESM)) required the Greek government to agree on fiscal consolidation in 1 order to get the debt level and primary deficits under control as fast as possible. Strict fiscal discipline might not only mean minimized costs for the creditors, but it could also create expansionary effects in the Greek real economy. This policy proved to be costly for all parts as the austerity brought with it severe adverse economic, political and social effects. From a Keynesian point of view, some of the actions taken have been contradictory and inefficient - pushing Greece closer to a bad equilibrium than towards prosperity. The economics of austerity seems to trigger a polarized debate among economists. Some argue that a combination of structural reforms and fiscal consolidation is the cure that will save a country from further misery. Structural reforms may create a more productive economic base, while austerity measures provide a signal of a commitment to restore fiscal discipline, hence lay the foundations for optimistic expectations and expansionary effects (Fels and Froehlich, 1986; Hellewig and Neumann, 1987). More importantly, since the European debt crisis was a result of significant imbalances in current accounts and competitiveness, internal devaluation and austerity are required in order to truly fix the underlying problems that lead to a crisis in the first place (Sinn, 2014). However, others argue that the difference between reforming a bad administrative structure and economic austerity has been lost in crude financial thinking and suggest that the way of practising fiscal policy should return to the Keynesian way of thinking about economics, where austerity should be used as a mechanism to cool down an overheated economy, and should not be analysed without considering the adverse political and social costs that are doomed to follow if used during a recession (Stiglitz, 2002; Krugmann, 2013; Wolf, 2014; Sen, 2012, among others). The goal of this thesis is to discuss these opposing views and cast more light on the relative costs and benefits associated with each. Was the Greek crisis a result of excessive spending over income? Did the austerity measures prove to be successful in restoring growth and improving the underlying conditions which lead to a crisis in the first place? How does fiscal austerity affect public finances? How does a fiscal expansion affect the Greek real economy in a recession? How does fiscal austerity affect the Greek real economy in a recession? These questions will be discussed in this thesis. The thesis is structured as follows: chapter 2 gives a short overview of the Greek debt crisis and discusses key macroeconomic variables of Greece and how they developed during the last decade. The next section takes a closer look on the algebra of sustainable sovereign debt and the theories of strategic debt accumulation and self-fulfilling debt equilibria. Then I analyse the evolution of public debt by applying a model which captures the links between debt, interest rates, growth, and investor confidence and discuss the factors which might trap the debt level in a bad equilibrium. The analysis builds on a model by Mehlum (2012) and is extended by modelling the link between austerity and economic growth. Chapter 3 starts by briefly discussing the Keynesian model as described by Holden (2015) and the fiscal multiplier before further discussing the the factors which 2 could make the multiplier large or small in times of crisis. Next, I introduce a variable of distress and analyse why expansionary fiscal policy in Greece might work insufficiently when the fiscal stimulus is financed by foreign loans which only increases the debt level and adversely affects a banking sector in distress. This variable might also be a function of several other extraordinary circumstances of the Greek economy, making a positive fiscal multiplier somewhat offset by the negative effects from continuously increased distress premiums. The next section gives a short overview of the austerity measures and prior actions Greece has implemented in order to receive bailout packages from the IMF and the ESM. Then the Keynesian model is further extended to include an endogenous recession premium as suggested by Mehlum (2014) in order to model an environment where fiscal austerity during a recession creates a vicious spiral in the real economy. The chapter further discusses the theory of expansionary fiscal contractions and other theories which provides some arguments in support of austerity during a downturn. Finally, the chapter discusses some political and social adverse effects of austerity. Chapter 4 concludes and will shed more light on the polarized debate which characterizes the economics of austerity. Keywords: Fiscal austerity, recession, current account, sovereign debt, risk premium, economic growth, vicious spiral, debt-to-GDP ratio, government expenses. 3 Chapter 2 The Greek Crisis and Recovery: Fiscal Corrections with Adverse Effects in the Market for Sovereign Debt 2.1 Fiscal Aspects of Monetary Integration: Why the Experiment Should Work The Maastricht Treaty of 1992 sets the ground rules for the European Monetary Union. Some of the criteria of sound fiscal policy that must be satisfied in order to join the union are that each member country’s annual government deficit must not exceed 3 percent of GDP, and that the debt-to-GDP ratio is not exceeding 60 percent, as later defined in the Stability and Growth Pact of 1997. Member countries that achieve those goals over the medium term will make it possible for the automatic stabilizers to play freely1 . This is the ”preventive arm” of the pact. The Stability and Growth Pact also contains a ”dissuasive arm” through the ”Excessive Deficit Procedure” (EDP) which ensures a correction process in every country that fails to satisfy the conditions. The dissuasive arm further contains a set of sanctions that will be imposed on any member state that fails to implement the EDP in due time. Dornbusch (1997) analyses whether so much attention to fiscal issues is at all relevant in a monetary union. By using an application of the Barro-Gordon model where the authorities minimize a loss function for a given expected rate of inflation, it serves to show how such an often used modelling framework implies how debt is a risk 1 The pact allows the time horizon to vary, depending on country-specific circumstances such as the level of debt and the growth rate. Such country-specific medium-term budgetary objectives (MTOs) adds flexibility to the pact. However, one could argue that such flexibility may give rise to opportunistic interpretations, discussions and conflicts. 4 factor for sound monetary policy2 . The higher the level of debt, the more tempting it is for the authorities to inflate away parts of it, and the higher is the optimal level of inflation. Thus, limits on debt and deficits are necessary to avoid such temptations. However, Dornbusch suggests three arguments of why the focus on such limitations is overdone. First, he argues that: the provisions for the European Central Bank assure that the institution is independent, cannot solicit or accept guidance, and cannot finance governments. The extra provision of no bailouts of public debts eliminates an immediate spillover effect of poor public finance to the central bank or countries‘ budgets. Thus, insistence on debt provisions is overkill, and the dash for fiscal probity that is under way is not justifiable by a concern for sound money. (Dornbusch, 1997, p. 222) The no-bailout clause in the original Maastricht treaty implied that any national government that failed to meet its debt obligations had to declare sovereign default. This clause should have had the desired effect that the euro countries should not borrow excessively. When default is the only option if a crisis occurs, countries should not have any incentives to borrow more than they can repay (no moral hazard). Second, he argues that: the static game laid out above [the Barro-Gordon framework] seriously misrepresents the opportunities for inflationary strategies to accomplish debt reduction. In any multiperiod game there will be punishment, and that means higher nominal interest rates and worsening of trade-offs. (Dornbusch, 1997, p. 222) As governments understand the real costs associated with this spiral, the application of the Barro-Gordon model loses some validity. Finally, he explains how a worsening of one country’s debt will not pose a threat to the overall stability of the union as bonds are substitutes. The market provides discipline as investors substitute away from holding bonds considered more risky than others. E.g. a worsening of Greek debt will be a Greek problem as investors shift from Greek bonds to, say, German bonds. Thus, there is an adjustment in all yields as the spread of Greek bonds over German bonds will rise. This adjustment implies that a debt crisis in one individual country will not spread to other euro countries. As Greece must struggle with a higher interest rate on its debt, Germany benefits from a reduced interest rate and a beneficial ”safe-haven” response. ”Hence there is one more reason why the insistence on fiscal criteria in the EMU is vastly overdone” (Dornbusch, 1997, p. 223). 2 The original model is found in Barro and Gordon (1983). 5 2.2 What Went Wrong? History shows that the no-bailout clause was not credible enough to avoid excessive debt accumulation as several countries continued to accumulate debt after joining the union. The low credibility of the no-bailout policy made the euro-countries realize that future EMU-policies would not necessarily coincide with the once optimal plan of no bailouts resulting in a time-consistency problem for the EMU policymakers. When the European debt crisis did happen, the no-bailout policy seemed no longer optimal as the costs associated with letting a highly indebted country default was larger than actually assisting in its recovery. Letting a highly indebted country default would imply that the creditor countries would face large economic losses. There would also be symbolic costs associated with the failure of creating a stable and strong European union. This further damaged the reputation of the no-bailout clause and provided countries with further incentives for excessive spending. In addition there already existed other international economic institutions that could provide financial assistance during times of crisis, such as the IMF with a clear mandate of achieving global macroeconomic stability. The convergence of bond yields between 2000 and 2009 reflected that investors did not expect any sovereign default to occur as the costs would be to great. Having discussed moral hazard and the time-consistency problem, this establishes a counterargument to Dornbusch’s main message and provided a rationale for the Stability and Growth Pact. As long as there are possibilities of large fiscal imbalances among countries within the euro area, strong and well enforced common fiscal targets are needed in order to ensure the singleness of monetary policy. But even with such rules in place, a crisis did occur. This could be a consequence of the flaws within the Stability and Growth Pact itself. Some argue that there is an asymmetric incentive structure, an incentive gap, in the pact as there are sanctions for failing to meet the criteria but no rewards from achieving them (see for example van den Noord, 2007). And as argued by Sapir (2007, p. 89), national authorities may not share a sense of ownership towards the rules of the pact, and the general population may not fully understand the rationale behind it. In addition: [...]the 3 percent rule is not based on rational economic analysis. It is an arbitrary number. Thus, intelligent people (policy makers) will not subject themselves to a rule that is perceived as unintelligent, especially when these policymakers face strong commitments vis-à-vis their electorate during a recession. They will put the rule aside. (De Grauwe, 2007, p. 184) Meeting the criteria was crucial for countries that wished to be a part of the EMU, but as soon as this mission was completed, incentives changed. Then, ”the only ”stick” left to the EU authorities was the less tangible risk of uncertain and delayed pecuniary sanctions 6 and loss of reputation. Since SGP stipulated that fiscal positions have to be close to balance or in surplus ”over the medium run”, there was no clear timetable for compliance” (van den Noord, 2007, p. 41). This, combined with weaknesses in enforcement, prevented the Stability and Growth Pact to work sufficiently as a preventive and dissuasive pact. Thus, a period of fiscal convergence in the late 1990s happened as countries focused on achieving the fiscal targets in order to join the monetary union. However, this ended in a period of divergence during the 2000s as several member countries found it optimal to run large deficits and increase their public spending (more on this in section 2.4.2) rather than comply to the pact. One of the member countries that diverged the most was Greece. Greece represents a tragic case when it comes to sound fiscal policy and it is no secret that the country has a long history of excessive spending, government budget deficits and high debt levels. According to Dornbusch, paying much attention to fiscal issues is overdone, but this turned out to be clearly wrong in the case of Greece, especially since the no-bailout clause had little or no credibility and the dissuasive arm of the Stability and Growth Pact were insufficient to prevent deviation. In 2010, Greece received its first bailout package from the IMF in addition to bilateral loans from other euro governments. Since 2012 the situation became so severe that the prospect of leaving the eurozone emerged. But was it simply the case that the Greek tragedy, and the broader European sovereign debt crisis, was solely a problem of excessive public spending? Or was it more a problem of the broader unbalanced economic structure of the eurozone? The next section will discuss in more detail how Greece’s mismanaged economy ended in a nightmare for the EMU and themselves - a nightmare in which there is no imminent awakening. 2.3 2.3.1 An Overview of the Greek Debt Crisis An Unbalanced Eurozone Greece joined the euro in 2001 after a long period of adjustment away from high inflation, large government deficits and a high exchange rate relative to its trading partners. In the following years between 2003-2007, Greece and many other euro countries experienced a significant accumulation of macroeconomic and financial vulnerabilities as they fell for the temptation to take advantage of the highly liquid banking system and the economic benefits which followed after the creation of the euro. Easy access to international funds at low borrowing costs in combination with high economic growth reduced the real value of debt and stimulated to increased borrowing by governments in several euro countries in order to finance fiscal deficits which further worsened their current-account deficits, especially in Greece and Portugal. Excessive public spending stimulated private investment 7 Figure 2.1: Source: Eurostat. Average general government budget balance between 20032007 as percent of GDP which translated into larger current-account deficits, i.e. the twin deficit. In other countries, such as Ireland and Spain, the debt accumulation was mainly private as the credit boom significantly increased consumption and investment in these countries. However, private debt accumulation was evident also in several other euro-countries. By looking at loans to the private sector from domestic banks and other credit institutions as percent of GDP, Lane (2012, pp. 52-53) shows how especially Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece, and Spain experienced significant increases in private credit dynamics between 1998 and 2007, while Germany’s and France’s credit dynamics were relatively stable at a high level through the period. E.g while Greek private sector loans increased from 56.5 percent of GDP in 2002 to 84.4 percent in 2007, German private credit dynamics were relatively stable around 110 percent. Figure 2.1 shows the average general government budget balance between 2003-2007 among several countries in the eurozone3 . Among the countries who would later be hit hardest by the European debt crisis it is clear that Ireland and Spain performed remarkably well as the debt accumulation was mainly private, while Italy was just marginally below the Maastricht criteria. Among the countries that would not be severely hit by the crisis, i.e. Germany, Netherlands, and Belgium, the figure shows that they all ran fiscal deficits. The large deficit in Greece was not solely a result of too high public spending - it was mainly due to an ineffective administrative State which made possible an extreme level of tax evasion which created a large difference between expenses and revenues (Wolf, 2014, p. 46). In his article Why austerity is the only cure for the eurozone the German Finance Minister Wolfgang Schäubel writes ”Whatever role the markets have played in catalysing the sovereign debt crisis, it is an indisputable fact that excessive state spending has led to unsustainable levels of debt and deficits that now threaten our economic welfare” (Schäuble, 2011). However, according to figure 2.1, the argument is not persuasive as the most well performing countries during the crisis did all 3 According to Eurostat, the general government sector comprises central government, state government, local government, and social security funds. 8 Figure 2.2: Source: Eurostat. Current Accounts in the Eurozone in 2007 as percent of GDP run deficits, while Ireland and Spain - who were hit hard by the debt crisis after 2007, performed remarkably well. Consider next the current account imbalances which developed after the adoption of the euro. The governments and private sectors in Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece, and Spain enjoyed the credit boom up until 2007 which resulted in increased inflation above the eurozone average, increased prices and wages. Thus the countries became current-account deficit countries with excessive spending over income, relying more on foreign capital inflows. Other countries such as Germany, Netherlands and Belgium focused on reducing labour costs and improve productivity so to further improve their competitiveness, making them current-account surplus countries (see e.g. Holden, 2012; Wolf, 2014, pp. 74-85; and Lane, 2012). Figure 2.2 illustrates current account imbalances in 2007. First of all, the figure says something about the direction of the capital flow. High-saving-surpluscountries such as Germany, Netherlands, and Belgium invested much of their savings in the dynamic economies of the south. According to Wolf (2014, pp. 59-85) the pattern also suggests strengthening of external competitiveness in surplus countries and declining competitiveness in the deficit countries: Moreover, these losses of competitiveness were inevitably associated with longlasting changes in the structure of economies: in surplus countries, industries that produce tradable goods and services, particularly export-oriented manufacturing, expanded, as in Germany. In countries with external deficits, the opposite happened: businesses oriented to the domestic economy, such as construction and retail, expanded, as in Spain. (Wolf, 2014, p. 63) And as further explained by Sinn (2014), the periphery countries lost their competitiveness by simply becoming too expensive. The export sector has more potential for productivity growth, thus the imbalance ran the risk of further diverging productivity. The increas9 ing difference in current accounts and competitiveness created unsustainable imbalances where a financial crisis would have large asymmetric impacts. In 2008 a financial crisis did hit Europe, resulting in a sudden stop of capital inflow into deficit countries. The subsequent worsening of primary deficits was therefore in part a consequence of a crisis not the reason. Comparing figure 2.1 and 2.2, one could argue that current account imbalances do a better job in predicting which countries would suffer the most after a financial crisis. If the debt crisis was fiscal in its roots, it is impossible to see from figure 2.1 that it should be Germany who ended up as a safe haven country after the crisis. Since the problem that led to the European debt crisis was the loss of competitiveness among periphery countries, Sinn argues that the eurozone needs to re-balance: The realignment is necessary to achieve debt sustainability and regain competitiveness, and competitiveness is a prerequisite for new growth. Keynesian demand stimuli is not sustainable. At best it is an improvement in capacity utilization. Sustainable growth, by contrast, will only result if a country is truly competitive in the sense of being inexpensive enough, given the nature and quality of its products, to enjoy high demand for its products from abroad and to be an attractive business location. (Sinn, 2014, p. 5) The challenge is that the current accounts are jointly determined so that surplus countries would need to become more expensive in order for deficits countries to be able to regain competitiveness. Sinn calls for an opposite Keynesian policy where deficit countries need austerity and internal devaluation in order to regain competitiveness whereas surplus countries could benefit from fiscal expansion and inflation. Austerity is a rough medicine and brings with it adverse economic, social, and political effects and is experienced as a punishment by any country who gets such a medicine imposed on them. Therefore, such policies raise a moral question. According to Wolf: ”The surpluses entail deficits and vice versa. Because they are jointly determined, it is logically impossible to say that countries in deficit are responsible for their plight while those in surplus are guiltless. That is childish moralism” (Wolf, 2014, p. 63). The deficits of Greece were made possible by the investments from the surplus countries. This is only one aspect of the heated debate regarding the economics of austerity. 4 . 2.3.2 Greece after 2007 At the onset of the financial crisis, Greece ran a current-account deficit of almost 15 percent of GDP and a government-budget deficit of around 10 percent of GDP. The country 4 For a more complete overview of the origins of the European sovereign debt crisis, see Holden (2012), Lane (2012), Wolf (2014), and Abbas et al. (2014). 10 mainly relied on running a foreign-capital surplus as it ran both a current-account -and a budget deficit after high spending by successive governments relative to revenues raised. But as the foreign-capital surplus is very responsive to risk and uncertainty, the outbreak of the worldwide financial crisis was the starting point for a sudden stop in capital inflow which decreased the foreign-financial surplus, forcing Greece to lower its deficits. Since currency devaluation is not an option in a monetary union, Greek wages fell and GDP was reduced through internal devaluation resulting in a recession which increased the debt-to-GDP ratio. 2009 was a critical year for Greece as new revisions about Greek debt and primary deficits were made and published by the newly elected government led by Prime Minister Georgios Papandreou, and it turned out to be a lot worse than earlier reported. The budget deficit forecast for 2009 was revised from around 6 percent to GDP to around 12 percent. Fiscal mismanagement and deception through misreported statistics throughout the period from 2001 when Greece joined the euro harmed investor confidence when the true numbers were revealed, hence increasing borrowing costs and raised the spreads on sovereign bonds. The sudden stop in capital inflow in combination with low investor confidence made it almost impossible for Greece to finance its deficits. Greece was the first country to be shut out of the bond market in May 2010 when Greek government bonds got junk status and the private capital market froze5 . The country was in desperate need of financial aid in order to avoid default. Since then, Greece and its creditors have agreed upon three bailout packages in total. The first package of 110 billion euro bailout loan were agreed upon in May 2010 where 80 billion were financed in the form of bilateral loans from by the euro area Member States and additional 30 billion came from the IMF. The time horizon of the package was three years, but this proved to be too short a time by far in order for Greece to satisfy the conditionality. Hence, the first package was soon followed by a second package of 164.5 billion euro loan (an additional 130 billion plus the undisbursed amount from the first package) agreed upon in 2012, financed by the EFSF and the IMF. The loans were to be transferred in smaller disbursements during the next three years given that the conditionality criteria were met. The conditionality can be summarized into the four areas of restoring fiscal sustainability, safeguarding financial stability, enhancing growth, competitiveness and investment, and developing a more modern State with a public administration. The last point was motivated by the fact that Greece have had a highly inefficient tax system with a high degree of tax evasion, one of Europe’s most generous pension systems, and an inefficient public administration with a poor history of fiscal discipline. However, the criteria were not met, meaning that funds were often withheld until they were (Kuttner, 2013, p. 148). When the EFSF programme expired in June 2015, 130.9 billion euros were still outstanding. A third bailout loan of 5 Greece did not re-enter the bond market before July 2014 11 Figure 2.3: Source: Macrobond. Quarterly evolution of Greek public debt 86 billion euros, provided by the ESM and the IMF, was agreed upon in 2015 in order to further repay the creditors, pay down interest and recapitalize banks6 . The Greek public debt has been steadily increasing up until the bailout packages. Figure 2.3 shows the quarterly evolution of the Greek public debt from 2005-2015, reaching an all time high of approximately 369 billion euro in December 2011. The large drop in 2012 corresponds to the component of the second bailout package which included ”Private Sector Involvement” (PSI) which resulted in a face value loss of 53.5 percent on 97 percent of all privately held Greek bonds. According to Arslanap and Tsuda (2012), Greek sovereign debt held by domestic banks at that time were about 15 percent of the total, making the public sector exposed to a banking crisis and the banking sector exposed to sovereign default. About 10 percent of the total were held by domestic nonbanks. The debt relief put downward pressure on the debt crisis but resulted in large losses among banks and nonbaks which held Greek bonds. Except from the PSI, the debt continued to rise after the two first packages. By dividing the the total amount into smaller disbursements, providing them conditionally on good behaviour, clearly undermined the effectiveness of the loans. Figure 2.4 shows the unemployment rate between 2004-2015, being above 25 percent between 2013-2015. The unemployment rate was averaging approximately 16 percent between 2004-2015. According to the Greek National Statistical Service, the unemployment rate for workers between 20-24 years old exceeded 55 percent in 2013, and exceeded 70 percent for youths between 15-19 in the same year. As the budget deficit was reduced through austerity measures during 2011-12, increased unemployment followed as a side effect. 6 A complete overview of the amounts and dates of the disbursements is available at: http://ec.europa.eu/economy finance/assistance eu ms/greek loan facility/index en.htm 12 Figure 2.4: Source: Macrobond. Greek unemployment rate Figure 2.5 illustrates the treasury yields on 10-year Greek government bonds compared to those of Germany, Italy, and the United Kingdom. Except from the British pound, the sovereign debts are denominated in a common currency, the euro. This implies that the yield curves mainly reflect the credit-risk perceptions for each individual country. From the 1990s to the beginning of the 2000s there was a period of convergence as the countries prepared their entry into the EMU. Greece had experienced high inflation and exchange rates vis-à-vis its trading partners, but managed to improve its position as the country prepared to meet the Maastricht criteria through fiscal adjustments. The interest rate on Greek bonds converged later than the interest rate on the countries’ debt as Greece was the last country to join the eruo in 2001. The figure shows that the interest rates on both German and British debt have been relatively stable trough the period. German debt has benefited from a safe-haven response as the Greek and Italian debt have been perceived as more risky, exactly in line with Dornbusch’s argument of market discipline. It is clear that ”Germany [one of Greece’ major creditors], the country that gave us the word schadenfreude, has been profiting from the misfortune of others” (Kuttner, 2013, p. 115). In the case of the United Kingdom, the country always has the opportunity to print new money in order to pay down debt. Because of this opportunity the interest rates on British debt have followed almost the same safe pattern as those of Germany. The low spread on sovereign debt between 2000 and 2009 reflects how investors perceived the credit risk within the EMU as low and a fiscal crisis as unlikely, and there were no longer any risks associated with exchange rates - resulting in a period of harmony in the sovereign-debt market. This probably also reflected that the no-bailout clause of the Maastricht treaty had little or no credibility. However, a large increase in Greek yields started in 2009-10 when the true national statistics were revealed, the capital inflow into Greece froze, and Greece received its first bailout package. It is interesting to note how the yields remained relatively stable during 2008 and 2009 even though the financial crisis 13 had spread to Europe. According to Lane (2012), during those years, investors may have not fully anticipated a sovereign-debt crisis, as the main focus was on saving the banking system. However, this changed as the distress in the banking sector soon became a problem of macroeconomic fundamentals. Even though Greece got its first bailout package in 2010, the interest rate continued to increase until the beginning of 2012. This says something about how investors interpreted the austerity package and its ability to save Greece and how the austerity affected confidence. In addition, the announcement of the PSI component of the second package and the complicated negotiations concerning its magnitude contributed to drive the interest rate further upwards. The final agreement on the second bailout package, the implementation of the PSI, and the announcement of new monetary policy instruments created by the ECB who was ”ready to do whatever it takes” to stabilize the eurozone (discussed in depth in later sections) made the interest rate decline in 2012. Hence, even though the history is repeating itself through diverging interest rates on sovereign debt, the divergence during the last years is happening for fundamentally different reasons than in the case of 1990. At the time of writing, the interest rate on Greek bonds is again increasing. Finally, table 2.1 summarizes Greek key macroeconomic numbers in a table. Especially interesting are the government budget balance and debt-to-GDP ratio which were never close to meet the Maastricht criteria. As austerity slowly reduced the budget- and primary balance from 2009, the Greeks has suffered from adverse side effects such as reduced minimum wage and increased unemployment. There were also significant side effects in the overall growth of the economy. The annual change in real GDP growth from 2009 has been negative throughout except from 2014. Greek GDP growth had its worst year in 2011 with a growth rate of -9.1 percent. In 2014 the real growth rate turned positive, but at the time of writing the growth rate is again negative. The European Commission projects a real GDP growth rate of -0.7 in 2016. The austerity measures are supposed to improve Greek competitiveness. The current-account deficit has been almost continuously reduced since 2008, but this is mainly a result of a larger reduction in imports relative to the reduction in exports since 2007. According to Sinn: The reason for the current account deficit improvements is primarily a strong decline in imports, which did not signal an improvement in competitiveness but was simply a result of the recession. Declining incomes and mass unemployment constituted an income effect that necessarily reduced imports. (Sinn, 2014, p. 7) The GDP price deflator in table 2.1 shows that prices have fallen from 2013 and onwards relative to the 2010 base-year. Thus, cheaper domestic goods and services could shift demand from imports towards domestic oriented goods and services. Further, the price 14 Figure 2.5: Source: Macrobond. 10-year yields on government bonds among four european countries 15 Table 2.1: Source: The Bank of Greece, Eurostat, and AMECO. Economic Statistic Table for Greece between 2007-2016 Year 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 Nominal GDP 232.7 242.0 237.5 226.0 207.0 191.2 180.4 177.6 175.7 174.4 Public debt 239.9 264.7 300.9 330.4 356.0 304.8 319.2 317.1 314.4 322.7 103.1 109.4 126.7 146.2 172.0 159.4 177.0 178.6 179.0 185.0 Primary balance -2.2 -5.4 -10.1 -5.4 -3.0 -3.7 -8.4 0.4 -3.5 0.5 Budget balance -6.7 -10.2 -15.2 -11.2 -10.2 -8.8 -12.4 -3.6 -7.6 -3.4 3.3 -0.3 -4.3 -5.5 -9.1 -7.3 -3.2 0.7 -0.2 -0.7 8.4 7.8 9.6 12.7 17.9 24.5 27.5 26.5 25.1 24.0 4.5 4.8 5.17 9.09 15.74 22.81 10.05 6.92 8.86 9.41 -15.6 -15.8 -12.5 -13.11 -10.3 -4.2 -2.2 -3.0 -1.8 -1.4 92.8 96.8 99.3 100 100.8 100.4 97.9 95.6 94.7 94.7 92.7 96.7 94.6 100 105.8 108.5 106.6 104.6 96.5 98.5 817.83 862.82 862.62 876.62 683.76 683.76 683.76 Debt-to-GDP ratio Real GDP growth rate Unemployment rate Treasury yield on 10-year gov’ bonds Current account balance GDP price deflator Price deflator exports of goods and services Minimum wage 730.30 794.02 Notes: Nominal GDP: at current prices in billion euros (AMECO). Public debt: general government consolidated gross debt in billion euro (AMECO). Debt-to-GDP ratio: general government consolidated gross debt divided by nominal GDP at current prices (AMECO). Primary balance: net lending or net borrowing as percent of GDP, excluding interest (AMECO). Budget balance: general government net lending or net borrowing (AMECO). Real GDP growth rate: percentage change (in volume) on precious year (Eurostat), where the number for 2016 is a forecast by the European Commission. Unemployment rate: unemployed persons as a share of the total labour force (AMECO). Treasury yield on 10-year government bonds: yearly average yields expressed in percentages (the Bank of Greece), where the interest rate for 2016 is calculated as the average rate applying from January-April. Current account balance: balance on current transactions (percentage of GDP at market prices) with the rest of the world (AMECO). GDP price deflator: average of national growth rates weighted with current values in euro with base-year 2010 (AMECO). Price deflator exports of goods and services: average of national growth rates weighted with current values in euro with base-year 2010 (AMECO). Minimum wage: in EUR/month (Eurostat). deflator for exports of goods and services has not changed much from the base year of 2010. Export prices have declined by even less than the GDP price deflator. Thus, as the austerity has reduced the primary surplus and the current account at the expense of unemployment and growth, little has happened to improve Greek competitiveness as the current-account deficit has been reduced because of increased unemployment rather than lower relative prices. ”Plainly, Greece [...] have a particular long way to go to achieve debt sustainability, but practically none of the necessary adjustment has taken place yet, despite the fact that the crisis has lasted already more than five years” (Sinn, 2014, p. 6). To summarize, the fact that Greece joined the monetary union with misreported statistics about key macroeconomic variables put the Maastricht Treaty and Dornbusch arguments to a test. Greece had clearly violated the debt-to-GDP and budget deficit criteria. However, the excessive spending and current-account deficit of Greece were made possible 16 by foreign-capital inflow from surplus countries such as Germany. ”Yes, the Greeks should have paid their taxes and run their government more responsibly. But the fact that they behaved in this way was really no secret. Caveat creditor - let the lender beware- is a good motto” (Wolf, 2014, p. 182). Thus, the financial crisis, in combination with reduced investor confidence when the true statistics of Greece went public, resulted in an asymmetric shock of huge proportions. The no-bailout condition needed to be relaxed in order to save Greece from default, resulting in three bailout packages in total between 2010-15. The conditionality and austerity measures agreed upon during the bailout negotiations proved to be costly as they resulted in severe adverse effects. This triggered the debate about whether economic recovery and structural reforms in the eurozone should indeed be done through fiscal austerity or Keynesian expansions and debt restructuring. The remaining part of this chapter will discuss this further. 2.4 The Sustainability of the Greek Sovereign Debt 2.4.1 Examples of Models of Debt Crises In 2011 Greece partially repudiated on its debt after investors accepted a 53.5 percent face value loss in their Greek debt holdings. It is the fear of such losses that drives the interest rate on bonds. The rate of interest is dependent upon investor’s confidence in the the country’s ability to honour its debt and the history of repudiation. A history of repudiation gives reasons for investors to be pessimistic about the country’ repayment ability which again opens the possibility of several equilibria and self-fulfilling expectations in the market for sovereign debt. Calvo (1988) develops a model where he shows how partial repudiation often is a best response for the government. In this economy, multiple debt equilibria exist and they are a function of consumers’ expectations about future repudiation. He models taxation as distortionary i.e. the deadweight cost of taxation is an increasing convex function of the tax level. The fact that taxation, here the only way to pay down debt, has a cost gives the government an incentive to renege on the debt. But repudiation also comes with a cost which is proportional to the amount being repudiated, and this cost is also financed by taxation. Without describing the two-period model in detail, multiple equilibria exist because consumers’ expectations about possible repudiation is reflected in the interest rates on government bonds. Those expectations are based on the level of existing debt, the cost of repudiation, and the governments optimal taxation. If the consumers believe that the level of taxation is not sufficient in order to pay the debt in full, they will demand a higher interest rate which makes it more difficult for the government to actually do so. Thus, debt repudiation is a self-fulfilling prophecy. Calvo writes: our results suggest that postponing taxes (i.e. falling into debt) may generate 17 the seeds of indeterminacy; it may, in other words, generate a situation in which the effects of policy are at the mercy of people’s expectations - gone would be the hopes of leading the economy along an optimal path. (Calvo, 1988, p. 648) According to this theory there are possibilities of several equilibria. Relative to the good equilibrium where optimistic expectations and low interest rate result in full downpayment of the debt, the bad equilibrium is Pareto-dominated as everyone would be better off in the good equilibrium case. Though not modelling Greek default as a best response in a game theoretic sense in the model used later in this chapter, the model builds on the idea that the interest rate is driven by expectations which creates several equilibria in the bond market. Building on this theory and inspired by the Mexican debt crisis of 1994-95, Cole and Kehoe (2000) develop a model which shows how a self-fulfilling debt crisis can be triggered by loss of confidence in the government. For given values of fundamentals such as the government’s debt level, its maturity, and the existing capital stock, the ability of the government to roll over its debt is determined by the probability the investors assign to the governments ability to repay in the future. They characterize three zones: the crisis zone, the default zone, and the no-crisis zone. By applying this model to Greece one could find several interesting implications. Suppose the extremely high debt level puts Greece in the crisis zone so that a debt crisis can occur with a positive probability. Then, according to the model, investors will anticipate a possible default, hence the price the investors are willing to pay for government bonds is depressed. This makes it more difficult for the government to roll over its debt and is therefore forced to reduce government spending. In the final step of the game the consumers make an optimal decision about consumption and capital accumulation, taking future productivity and the previous moves made by the financial markets and the government as given. If the government defaulted in the previous period or the consumers expect a default in the future, this may harm the governments reputation which affects the productivity of the economy in future periods. This will in turn result in lower output and consumption and enable a subsequent crisis. Greece is then trapped in a bad equilibrium as lower investor demand, reduced government spending, lower consumption and capital accumulation are mutual best responses by all agents in the economy. The assumption that a debt crisis can be triggered by pessimistic beliefs among investors in the financial market gives the government incentives to pay down its debt faster in order to avoid the spiral. Moving across the threshold from the crisis zone to the non-crisis zone will boost investor demand, reduce interest rates on government bonds, and increase productivity as investors and consumers no longer assign any probability to the possibility of default. The model shows the importance of getting the debt level stabilized at a sustainable level as this will have positive effects on 18 the overall economic performance. Countries can find themselves in very different equilibria with only small differences in fundamentals. The authors conclude that ”overall, our model implies that the only way to avoid debt crisis is to avoid the conditions on fundamentals that make them possible: in particular, relatively high levels of debt with a short maturity structure” (Cole and Kehoe, 2000, p. 110). The model applied next will focus on a similar link between debt, interest rate, and economic activity, and is thus inspired by the body of work mainly attributable to these authors. 2.4.2 The Algebra of Sustainable Debt and Some Theories on Debt Accumulation This section will describe a standard model of sustainable debt as often applied by the IMF. The notation used in this section is taken from Mehlum (2012). By definition, debt is sustainable if the level of debt does not grow faster than the GDP and it is possible to hold the debt-to-GDP ratio constant over time. The evolution of debt, ∆B, is determined by down payment, H, and interest on the existing debt, r ∆B = rB − H (2.1) Suppose that g denotes the growth rate of GDP. Since a sustainable debt level by definition does not grow faster than the GDP, then the maximum change in public debt the government can afford according to the definition of sustainability is given by ∆B = gB (2.2) Finally suppose that the amount of resources for downpayment are determined by the size of the primary surplus, denoted a, as a fraction of GDP and rewrite the requirement for sustainable debt into (2.3) gB = rB − aY where (2.2) have been inserted into (2.1) and B denotes a sustainable debt level. It follows that the sustainable debt ratio, S, is S= B a = Y r−g (2.4) Thus, the higher the economic growth and primary surplus, the higher the debt level could be and still be sustainable. Consider the Greek numbers for 2015 which showed a real GDP growth rate of -0.2 percent and a primary balance of -3.5. According to 19 the IMF, the effective interest rate7 was projected to be 2.1 percent conditional on full implementation of the program (IMF, 2015, p. 19). By using this interest rate as an approximation for the true borrowing costs on official Greek borrowing, this corresponds to a sustainable debt level of approximately -85 percent of GDP8 , while the actual debt level is 179.0! This implies that the only sustainable scenario for Greece, given the large deficit and absence of growth, is to be a creditor - not a debtor. Thus, in the current economic environment, Greece is extremely far from achieving a constant debt-to-GDP ratio over time according to equation (2.4). The fact that Greece is far from able to keep its debt-to-GDP ratio constant over time is illustrated in figure 2.6. The figure illustrates the evolution of the Greek gross government debt as percent of GDP compared to Germany and the entire euro area. The ratio has been increasing almost the entire period, except from a small decline in 2012 due to the PSI and bailouts. According to the IMF, debt sustainability is defined as an debt-to-GDP ratio less than 120 percent. In the figure, this threshold were crossed in 2008 and the debt has been unsustainable ever since. By comparing figure 2.6 and figure 2.3 it is clear that the drop in the debt-to-GDP ratio in 2012 is small relative to the large drop in public debt which was made possible through the debt relief the same year. However, table 2.1 shows an extremely low GDP growth rate of about -10 percent of GDP. Thus, even though private holders of Greek debt accepted a face value loss which reduced Greece’s total debt burden, the debt-to-GDP ratio was reduced by only a modest amount because of the low growth of the Greek economy. This clearly shows how a debt relief has a limited effect on the debt-to-GDP ratio if the economy is not able to produce any economic growth. At this point it is relevant to ask why and how several Greek governments could allow such an enormous debt accumulation. The elevating debt-to-GDP ratio after 2007 is clearly a result of the sudden stop in capital inflow which significantly increased the real value of debt as the economy went into a recession. But why the high level of debt in the first place, besides the institutional failures of the EMU? Typical macroeconomic textbook explanations for debt accumulation is mainly about tax smoothing and the strategic debt accumulation theory from political economy. Consider the model of tax smoothing by Barro (1979). The intuition is that, assuming that marginal distortion of raising tax revenues is increasing in the amount of tax revenues raised, smoothing taxation minimizes the distortions. This implies that running a bud7 ”Defined as interest payments divided by debt stock at the end of the previous year” (IMF, 2015, p. 19). 8 S= −0.035 0.021−(−0.02) = −85 percent. 20 Figure 2.6: Source: Eurostat. Evolution of Greek gross government debt as percent of GDP get deficit might actually be an optimal response by the government when anticipating a fall in future government expenditures. When economic shocks are anticipated, such as wars or recessions, fiscal imbalances might be preferable as changes in the tax policy creates distortions9 . This provides a rationale for debt accumulation through debt issuance. However, Greece has shown a systematic tendency towards high deficits regardless of the variation in government expenditures which casts some doubt on whether this model is a good approximation for Greece. Suppose current Greek policymakers may believe that the future policy will be set by political opponents who they disagree with, hence the current policymakers use their position to distribute resources in a way they see most appropriate, and by doing so excessively they restrain the government spending of future governments by running strategic deficits. Alesina and Tabellini (1990) argue that the equilibrium stock of public debt in democracies tends to be larger than what is socially optimal because of the uncertainty of whom will be appointed in the future. Given this uncertainty, and with sufficient polarization between political parties who disagree on the composition of public expenditures, each party will not fully internalize the full cost of public debt. Since deficits and debt accumulation represent future tax distortions and less scope for public spending, the party in power is concerned about the trade-off between those negative effects with the probability of staying in office and of who is paying the bill in the future. Hence, democracies exhibits higher deficits and debt levels than in the case of a social planner appointed for9 Within the Keynesian framework we can show that, by setting G = T and assume a balanced budget, the multiplier increases compared to the case when keeping T fixed, implying budget deficits/surpluses when G varies. Hence, any negative shock to the interest rate is more destabilizing when running balanced budgets as the IS-curve is less steep in this case. 21 ever. In Greece during the last three decades, PASOK (Panhelleninc Socialist Movement) and ND (New Democracy) alternated in power until the election in 2009. Whether the model of Alesina and Tabellini applies to Greece in this period depends on the degree on polarization between the two parties. According to Pappas: ”Greek polarization has been strategic polarization, pursued deliberately by pragmatic parties competing to grab the state single-handedly and control its resources” (Pappas, 2013, p. 40). As the deficits and debt grew rapidly under both parties, one could argue that the model implications could contribute in explaining parts of the excessive government spending up until 2009. The two-party system of Greece might also have led to continuously delayed stabilization. Policymakers may agree that the deficit should be lower but still being unable to agree on the policy which can achieve it. ”Specifically, inefficient deficits can persist because each policymaker or interest group delays agreeing to fiscal reform in the hope that others will bear a larger portion of the burden” (Romer, 2012, p. 617). Alesina and Drazen (1991) develops a mathematical model and illustrate that the larger the benefits of continuing to delay relative to accept the reform, the more likely is a war of attrition. Delayed stabilization is a function of political polarization and the authors mention several examples of this. For example after WWII there was an agreement to reduce the large deficits that resulted after the war but there was often much disagreement over what groups in society that should pay in form of increased taxes, and this delayed the fiscal stabilization in several countries. The authors assume that the pre-stabilization process is characterized by inefficient methods of financing government expenditures and widespread political lobbying which are direct costs for all. However, a stabilization agreement means moving away from inefficiency which benefits all. How long the delay will last is determined by how long it takes before one political part (representing a socio-economic group) agrees on bearing a disproportionate share of the tax increase. Agreement happens when the cost of delay is less than or equals the cost of postponing reforms. But as the debt level increases, so too does the difference between the payoffs for the winners and losers. Thus, each political part will devote more time to lobbying in order to induce its rivals to concede. The model of Alesina and Drazen assumes two polarized parts which has been the case with ND and PASOK in Greece up until 2009. However, after the crisis, the two-party system changed into an ”extremely polarized form of multipartism” (Pappas, 2013, p. 43) The theory is still appealing in a way that, as policy is set by several parties representing several socio-economic groups, this may delay reforms depending on the heterogeneity between them. This has been especially evident from the complex bargaining processes over structural reforms and austerity measures since the first adjustment programme. However, one could also argue that the scope of the current Greek crisis is of a magnitude so great that the cost of delaying fiscal corrections clearly outweighs any gains from delay. 22 2.4.3 The Vicious Spiral between Investor Confidence, Growth, and Sustainability ”I will have my bond” - Shylock, in William Shakespeare’s ”The Merchant of Venice” Subsection 2.4.2 showed how a high primary surplus only had a positive effect on the level of sustainable debt. However, since primary surpluses represent fiscal consolidation it may be reasonable to assume that the variable will affect both the interest rate and economic growth. Now suppose there is a critical level of primary surplus so that if the primary surplus needed for debt sustainability exceeds this critical level it will affect investor’s confidence. As a response to crossing this level, investors demand a risk premium in order to be willing to buy sovereign debt. With a high level of debt in combination with low economic growth and high borrowing costs, Greece is forced to accomplish a high primary surplus, i.e. a high a, through austerity measures which hamper further growth and increases unemployment. Hence, investors demand a risk premium, e(a), which again affects the required a for sustainable debt as it increases the borrowing costs for the government. This assumption is consistent with several empirical findings. According to von Hagen et al. (2011), their empirical strategy identifies a significant relationship between budgetary positions and risk premiums on government bonds in the euro area countries relative to safe haven German bonds. They use data up until 2009 and find that markets penalise fiscal imbalances in the form of fiscal deficits and debt much more strongly than before. During the post Lehman-crisis they find that elasticities for deficit differentials (relative to a benchamrk country) are three to four times larger than earlier, and those for debt differentials are seven to eight times larger (higher debt differential is often accompanied by higher interest rates and low growth, further affecting the required a and risk premiums). The euro area countries should, they argue, pay much more attention to their budgetary positions in order to safeguard against the high costs of public debt. For Greece, relatively weak fiscal performance explains around half of the increase in spreads during the financial crisis according to he authors. Laubach (2009) finds that the estimated effects of government deficits and debt on interest rates are statistically significant and economically relevant. The risk premium increases by 4 basis points per percentage increase in the debt-to-GDP ratio over 60 percent. This method is suggested by the IMF staff when they forecast the future borrowing cost. In their report they suggest that: Borrowing from the market is assumed at an average maturity of 5 years and average nominal interest rate of 6.25 percent for the next several decades. 23 This is calibrated as follows: the market cost of Greek debt prior to the crisis - when there was limited differentiation of risk and spreads were compressed - was about 5 percent, to which an additional modest spread is considered. (IMF, 2015, p. 6) The modest spread could alternatively, they argue, be based on the empirical finding by Laubach. An additional source of risk premium may be the the lending institutions themselves. As the IMF and the ESM are the senior creditors (they get paid back first) we could argue that the loans contribute to continuously raise the risk premium by private financial institutions as they know that the Greek government will use the next decades to re-pay senior creditors. Private investors get what is left over. It is ironic if the IMF projections of future interest rates should turn out to be underestimated since the IMF itself may be one of the determinants behind the risk premium through its bailout packages and senior creditor status. Having established how risk premiums may play a key role in determining the level of sustainable debt, consider next the possibility of a link between public debt and economic growth. According to Reinhart and Rogoff (2010) there is a negative association between total debt and growth. They argue that, whereas the link between growth and debt seems relatively weak at ”normal” debt levels, median growth rates for countries with public debt over roughly 90 percent of GDP are about one percent lower than otherwise; average growth rates are several percent lower. However, their analysis does not consider the issue of reverse causality. Kumar and Woo (2014) run a panel regression with data from 1970 to 2008 and provides evidence of a slowdown in annual real per capita GDP growth of around 0.2 percent points per year on average when following a 10 percentage point increase in the public debt-to-GDP ratio, significant at a 1 percentage level. They further find that, by including an interaction term between initial public debt and foreign liabilities (a dummy variable that equals 1 if foreign liabilities exceed 89 percent of GDP) the adverse impact of debt on growth is approximately two times larger in countries where foreign liabilities are high, such as in Greece10 . On the other hand, Panizza and Presbitero (2014) find by using an instrumental variable approach that the link between debt and growth disappears when they correct for endogeneity. This suggests an extension to the model used in this chapter where, as in the case with risk premium, a high level of debt is negatively associated with economic growth. But instead of modelling growth as a direct function of the debt level, this model builds on the Keynesian paradigm where debt adversely affects growth through the fiscal consolidation needed in order to achieve the debt stabilizing primary surplus. It is important to emphasize that, since this model does not assume a causal link from debt to growth, the link exists only because of the 10 The net external debt position of Greece crossed the 89 percent of GDP threshold in 2000:Q2 according to Eurostat 24 chosen policy of austerity and the preference for achieving sustainable debt. As Panizza and Presbitero argue: Our finding that there is no evidence that the public debt has a causal effect on economic growth is important in the light of the fact that the negative correlation between debt and growth is sometimes used to justify policies that assume that debt has a negative causal effect on economic growth. (Panizza and Presbitero, 2014, p. 21) Taking these considerations into account, modify equation (2.4) into the following expression of sustainable debt as shown by Mehlum (2012) S= B a = Y r0 + e(a) − g(a) (2.5) where I have extended the model to include a negative relationship between growth and sustainability. In this expression r0 is the risk free interest rate, the risk premium satisfies e(a) = 0 when a < a∗ and e0 (a) > 0 when a ≥ a∗ . This captures the link between sustainability and investor confidence according to Mehlum (2012). In my extension I assume that g 0 (a) < 0 when a ≥ a∗, and g 0 (a) = 0 otherwise. This captures the negative link between sustainability and economic growth. In order to simplify the discussion, assume that the critical threshold a∗ is the same for both the risk premium and growth. This way of modelling sustainable debt differs from the simple equation in (2.4) as a large primary surplus no longer has a solely positive effect on sustainable debt. Now the model also incorporates some possible adverse effects of fiscal corrections by using the ideas of Calvo (1988) and Cole and Kehoe (2000) where expectation-driven risk premiums give rise to several debt equilibria within different crisis zones. By rearranging equation (2.5) in order to get a on the left hand side the expression becomes a= B (r0 + e(a) − g(a)) Y (2.6) which is the primary surplus needed in order for actual debt, B, to be sustainable. An increased interest rate r0 may thus have asymmetric effects in countries with small differences in fundamentals. Assume that Germany is in the non-crisis zone by being below the critical threshold a∗ and Greece is in the crisis zone by being above it. An increase in r0 increases a in both countries, but the effect is more complex in Greece. Equation (2.6) shows that a higher a leads to a further increase in the costs of borrowing in Greece but not in Germany. Increased borrowing costs trigger more austerity and austerity adversely affects borrowing costs. Thus, there is a vicious spiral between the two. In fact, Germany may benefit as investors shift from holding Greek debt to holding German debt instead. In addition, an increased a reduces growth in Greece, whereas growth is unaffected in 25 Germany. Lower growth increases the debt stabilizing primary surplus which again implies even more austerity - damaging growth even further. This is another vicious spiral. Next, consider the following three different alternatives within the model, illustrated in figures being different versions of the one found in Mehlum (2012): (i) Suppose first there is no relationship between investor confidence, growth and sustainability so that equation (2.4) holds and that the interest rate on bonds is simply given by the fixed risk free rate of interest i.e. r = r0 . This is illustrated in figure 2.7. In the figure there is only one intersection which implies a stable equilibrium point A0 . A marginal increase in a from point A0 implies that the government runs a larger primary surplus than what is needed in order to achieve sustainability at the given rate of interest. Then it is optimal to reduce the surplus until point A0 . A marginal decrease in a from point A0 implies the opposite. With no relationship between risk premium, growth and sustainability, a vicious spiral is not a possibility within the model. In this setting, a debt relief from B0 to B1 tilts the curve illustrating the primary surplus upwards - implying an even lower optimal a in point A1 . A debt relief has a unambiguous positive effect. The larger the debt relief, the steeper the curve becomes, hence shifting the equilibrium more to the left. Alternative (ii): r = r0 + e(a) r C1 a= B1 (r Y a= − g) B0 (r Y − g) C0 r0 A1 Alternative (i): r = r0 A0 a a∗ Figure 2.7: The possibilities of a vicious spiral and the effects of a debt relief in the case of (i) fixed rate of interest (ii) risk premium 26 (ii) Now suppose there is a negative relationship between sustainability and the risk premium so that the interest rate is given by r = r0 + e(a). After the threshold a∗ there is then a kink in the interest rate curve. This is illustrated in figure 2.7. While point A0 represents a stable equilibrium, point C0 represents an unstable one. A marginal decrease in a from point C0 implies a reduced interest rate and a good spiral towards point A0 . A marginal increase in a from point C0 implies a jump in the interest rate which again increases the required a - creating a vicious spiral. A debt relief from B0 to B1 tilts the curve illustrating the debt stabilizing primary surplus upwards, just as in the previous alternative. This implies that the good equilibrium becomes possible at lower levels of a as in point A1 . In addition, the unstable equilibrium is moved from point C0 to C1 . Thus, a vicious spiral is less likely and possible only at extremely high levels of a. A large enough debt relief could fully eliminate the bad equilibrium, as illustrated by the tilted, dashed curve. If Greece is initially in point C0 , a debt relief will push the a to the beneficial side of the unstable equilibrium so that the good spiral would kick in and continue until A1 . (iii) Finally, consider the model extension and suppose that the required a for sustainability affects growth negatively. Then the curve illustrating the debt stabilizing primary surplus will kink at the threshold a∗ as shown in figure 2.8, assuming that the threshold is equal for both e(a) and g(a). By comparing the unstable equilibrium point C0 with the one in the previous alternative, the figure shows that the vicious spiral is created earlier and from lower values of a when modelling growth as a function of the debt stabilizing primary surplus than if not. If austerity is seen as a necessity when the debt level is large as the government tries to achieve the required a for sustainability, the fiscal consolidation directly affects interest rate and growth negatively. The austerity measures end up making the debt level even more unsustainable by triggering a vicious spiral. In this model, a debt relief from B0 to B1 tilts the curve representing equation (2.5) upwards as shown in figure 2.8. The effect is identical to the ones in the previous examples up until a∗ . However, instead of eliminating the vicious spiral after a significant debt relief, the adverse effect on growth results in an intersection in the unstable equilibrium point C1 . The debt relief has a modest effect in eliminating the existence of a possible vicious spiral. But, if Greece is initially in C0 before the debt relief, the effect is still unambiguous and sets in motion the good spiral towards A1 . But a bad equilibrium is still present in the economy, so any large adverse shock to any of the variables in (2.6) may force Greece back into difficulties. To conclude, if Greece is indeed in a bad equilibrium the country would benefit greatly from a debt relief. The alternative is the risk of getting into a vicious spiral and default as a result of a tragic hunt for sustainable debt under worse and worse conditions. 27 r = r0 + e(a) r C1 r0 A1 a= B1 (r Y − g(a)) a= B0 (r Y − g(a)) C0 A0 a a∗ Figure 2.8: Alternative (iii): The vicious spiral between investor confidence, growth, and sustainability and the effects of a debt relief 2.4.4 Outright Monetary Transactions The interest rate on Greek 10-year bonds has followed a U-shaped pattern between 2012 and 2016. The large drop in the interest rate in 2012 was mainly a result of the debt relief and the launch of the second bailout package. But suppose that the interest rate was affected by the optimism originated from the announcement of the OMT-programme developed by the ECB the same year, though the programme was mainly designed to prevent a vicious spiral in Spain and Italy by decreasing borrowing costs on Spanish and Italian debt. The programme was developed with the aim of reducing the divergence in bond yields and ”[...] to safeguard the monetary transmission mechanism in all countries in the euro area” (ECB, 2012). Achieving to reduce the divergence in bond yields would not only reduce borrowing costs for governments and reduce the probability of a vicious spiral in the market for sovereign debt, but also have positive effects in the real economy as ”changes in long-term government bond-yields are an important driver of corporate bond yields and bank lending rates - either through arbitrage relations or through sovereign bonds directly serving as a benchmark for the pricing of loans and other assets” (Cæuré, 2013). By undertaking OMTs in the secondary market for sovereign bonds in the euro area, conditional one a set of criteria the governments needed to fulfil, the ECB could eliminate some of the ”unfounded fears” for the vicious spiral discussed above11 . 11 This is not a violation of the Article 123 of the EU Treaty as the secondary market is not considered as direct financing of governments. 28 By promising to intervene after the client country had signed up on the austerity programme and, for whatever reason, the interest rates on the country’s bonds should still be distressed, the ECB was implicitly guaranteeing an maximum interest rate and minimum price on sovereign debt. Though never used, the instrument turned out have an effect on interest rates i.e. the promise of intervention was enough. Figure 2.5 shows, for example, how the interest rate on Italian debt fell after the announcement. If investors in the bond market believed that the possible intervention by the ECB would result in a maximum interest rate on bonds, this could eliminate the bad equilibrium and hence the vicious spiral. As the instrument gave the ECB a stronger role as a lender of last resort, confidence returned which further affected the bank-sovereign link positively as the the banking sector could reduce its fear for sovereign default. Figure 2.9 illustrates the possibility where the OMTs could eliminate the vicious spiral. In the case of alternative (ii) of the model; r r = r0 + e(a) a= C( ii) r0 C( iii) A0 B (r Y − g) r = rOM T s a= B (r Y − g(a)) a a∗ Figure 2.9: The effects of Outright Monetary Transactions by guaranteeing a maximum interest rate through intervention in the secondary market for bonds, the ECB could eliminate the unstable equilibrium in point C( ii) and put an end to the vicious spiral in the case of g 0 (a) = 0. Only point A0 remains and the promise of intervention would be enough. Consider now alternative (iii) with the adverse effect on growth. Point C( iii) in figure 2.9 is still an unstable equilibrium which means that a marginal increase in a from that point will force the ECB to intervene in order to stop the spiral. The promise of intervention would no longer be sufficient. Thus, the model shows that there may exist possible scenarios where the ECB no longer can manage to control the diverging interest rates only though the existence of the instrument, but rather being enforced to use it. Again, a debt restructuring and growth-promoting policies which could 29 reduce the debt-to-GDP ratio and establish the economy in A0 is preferable. The instrument was created in order to reduce the interest rate on sovereign debt. However, in the model used here, low economic growth is a main determinant behind the bad outcomes. Since the implementation of the instrument is conditional on austerity and austerity negatively affects growth - there is indeed a contradiction. The plan does not add up as the adverse effects of fiscal corrections imposed in order to get assistance through the OMTs reduces growth and makes the implementation of the instrument only more unlikely as the fiscal targets become harder to achieve in the first place. ”If a country were to violate the conditions of its agreed programme, ECB support would cease. But this would also be when the market’s panic was greatets” (Wolf, 2014, p. 57). Instead of sending a clear message that speculating in sovereign debt does not pay, the instrument loses its credibility as the the countries need to sign up on the austerity programmes beforehand. As governments and private investors see this contradiction, the instrument loses its credibility and interest rates may again elevate. Thus, the U-shaped yield-curve on Greek sovereign debt. In the debt sustainability analysis (DSA) for Greece, developed by the IMF staff, the conclusion is that the Greek debt may become sustainable in the future but will remain highly vulnerable. They write that ”with debt remaining very high, any further deterioration in growth rates or in the medium-term primary surplus relative to the revised baseline scenario discussed here would result in significant increases in debt and gross financing needs [...]. This points to the high vulnerability of the debt dynamics” (IMF, 2015, p. 10). This analysis is based on a set of underlying assumptions about future macroeconomic variables where e.g. the analysis assumes that real GDP growth will grow steadily up to 3 percent in 2018 and the primary surplus will stabilize at 3.5 percent in 2018 and onwards, conditional on full implementation of the programme. If this should not be the case, IMF suggests that doubling the maturity on existing and new loans, with further financing needs and debt relief, would be needed. This is in line with the model where a debt relief could generate a far more achievable debt stabilizing primary surplus. By providing a large enough debt relief to Greece so the country could exit the crisis zone, Greece could relax the focus on fiscal consolidation and rather develop expansionary policies directly enhancing growth. Some economists argue that this should have been done long ago. E.g. according to Kuttner: ”Had Merkel backed Greek recovery and reform from the outset, or even left open the possibility of aid, there would have been far less downward pressure on the bonds. Instead, she adamantly refused to help, virtually inviting the speculative attacks” (Kuttner, 2013, p. 134). However, there are many theoretical reasons for why a debt relief is not considered a solution which was briefly touched upon in subsection 2.3.1 which referred to Sinn (2014). The debt-equilibrium model has only provided a first step 30 in order to say something about the risks of fiscal austerity as way of recovering. This chapter analysed some of the adverse effects that fiscal austerity could have on the public finances. But how does austerity during a recession affect aggregate demand and supply? Does fiscal consolidation have different effects when used during recessions than if used during normal times? Is there a possibility for a vicious spiral also in the real economy? How, and to what extent, could the pressure on the public finances affect aggregate demand? In order to fully tackle the debate on fiscal austerity, the next chapter will discuss these questions using a classical demand-driven Keynesian model before a more concluding discussion follows. 31 Chapter 3 Vicious Spirals in the Real Economy 3.1 The Effectiveness of Fiscal Stimulus during Crises 3.1.1 The Fiscal Multiplier In order to analyse how fiscal stimulus and fiscal austerity affects the real economy in a recession, this chapter leaves the debt-equilibrium model of the previous chapter and instead builds on a demand-driven Keynesian model as presented in Holden (2015). The building blocks and the derivation of the Investment - Saving relation (the IS-curve) is described in the appendix of this thesis1 . Since Greece is a member country of the European Monetary Union it implies that the country has a fixed exchange rate against all other member countries within the union. Uncovered interest rate parity holds and the expected rate of devaluation inside the monetary union is ∆E e = 0 so that (A.7) becomes i = iF (F for foreign) where the ECB is the institution conducting monetary policy on the behalf of the entire block of EMU countries. This section uses the IS-equation given by (A.10) Y = 1 (z C − c1 z T − c2 (i − π e ) + z I − b2 (i − π e )+ β 1 − c1 (1 − t) − b1 + a1 + a3 Y n G + z N X + a2 E − a3 (1 + π e − β + z π ) and the Phillips Curve given by (A.8) π = πe + β Y −Yn + zn Yn In a figure, this corresponds to a horizontal curve representing the fixed interest rate and an IS-curve which is decreasing in the interest rate since ∂Y < 0. This is illustrated in ∂i figure 3.1 1 All equations referred to as (A.#) in this chapter is found in appendix A. 32 i RR0 iF IS0 Y Y0 Figure 3.1: Typical (Y, i)-diagram with a fixed exchange rate This framework can be used in order to analyse the effectiveness of fiscal stimulus in the real economy, which is the main goal of this section. Since fiscal policy is the only policy tool left for Greece to use, discussing the size of the fiscal multiplier is a necessary startingpoint. First, consider what the multiplier might look like in Greece during a recession. Since Greece has not yet fully returned to the bond market, assume that the country must rely on assistance from other member states of the eurozone in order to fund the stimulus. A shock to G gives 1 ∂Y = >0 ∂G 1 − c1 (1 − t) − b1 + a1 + a3 Yβn where c1 and b1 are assumed not to be so large that the multiplier becomes negative. Expansionary fiscal policy, then, gives increased GDP. The multiplier can become large through two important mechanisms. The first one is through the stabilizing mechanism given by c1 (1−t). c1 is the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) and describes by how much consumption increases after a marginal increase in after tax disposable income. The lower the tax rate, t, the smaller part of the increase in income is confiscated by the government so the higher is the positive consumption response in the multiplier. Total private disposable income increases less than the initial GDP increase because total taxation increases and total welfare expenses decreases as economic growth reduces unemployment - an automatic stabilizer. It is no secret that much of Greece’s economy operates in a semiformal setting which results in significant tax evasion. This implies that the t in the multiplier overestimates the actual rate of tax collection by the government. Taking into account the significant tax evasion implies much stronger consumption response after the shock, i.e a lower automatic stabilizer. However, as will be discuss below, tax evasion also implies significant losses of 33 government revenues which only worsen the pressure on public finances. The second effect which increases the multiplier is through the accelerator effect captured by the marginal propensity to invest parameter b1 . Increased GDP improves the expectations for future sales, hence firms invest in more capital in order to meet those expectations. It is reasonable to assume that the marginal propensity to invest is low in the Greek economy as the private sector bankruptcies and uncertain economic prospects severally reduce the expectations of future sales and hamper the environment for investments. However, increased GDP may increase profits which again makes it easier to finance further investments - an effect called the financial accelerator. There are in addition two mechanisms which reduce the multiplier. The first is through increased imports captured by the propensity to import parameter a1 . Some of the increase in demand will be focused towards foreign goods, and this reduces net exports. The n second effect is through a3 Yβn . In the Phillips-curve, the term β Y Y−Yn would be negative in Greece as the level of GDP is below its potential (the AMECO database reports a Greek output gap of -8.1 percent of potential GDP in 2015). This implies significant slack and unused capacity in the economy. Increased GDP through fiscal stimulus will narrow the negative output gap which further reduces the deflationary pressure, resulting in reduced net exports. By how much the effect from the output-gap to inflation increases inflation depends on the size of the pass-through parameter β. The higher the β, the more passes through and the lower the deflationary pressure becomes. According to Keyens: ”In an open system with foreign-trade relations, some part of the multiplier of the increased investment will accrue to the benefit of employment in foreign countries, since a proportion of the increased consumption will diminish our own country’s favourable foreign balance” (Keynes, 1936, p. 120). This is what Sinn (2014) warns to be artificial and unsustainable Keynesian stimuli. The European sovereign debt crisis was triggered by a competitiveness problem, and reduced net exports after a fiscal expansion does nothing to tackle the underlying problem. Greece’s tradable goods need to become cheaper, but fiscal stimuli generates the opposite effect. Many economists have attempted to estimate the size of fiscal multipliers and the underlying parameters after the Great Depression. Carroll et al. (2014) calibrate c1 in fifteen European countries and find that the annually average (aggregate) value of the parameter in each country significantly depends on the inequality distribution within each country and is higher among the poorest and unemployed. They also find that c1 depends on whether the income shock is transitory or permanent, and the distribution of wealth between liquid and illiquid assets which determines the fraction of wealth that can be adjusted in order to smooth consumption. The authors calibrate a Greek average c1 ranging from 0.1 to 0.35 depending on the measure of wealth. Matching the distribu34 tion of liquid assets they find that Greece has the highest average estimate together with Spain with 0.35 and 0.38 respectively. The estimate for the unemployed is 0.62 and is the largest of the sample. Since Greece (together with Spain) has the largest Gini-coefficient, calculated for the level of net wealth/liquid assets, the relative consumption response to fiscal stimulus is among the largest in the sample because of the large proportion of low income households. In another study, by extending a classical DSGE model to include sticky prices and hand-to-mouth consumers (or rule-of-thumb consumers) who behave in a non-Ricardian fashion, Gali et al. (2007) find that the multiplier effect is larger the larger the share of this kind of consumers - which is more the case during recessions. This immediately suggests a policy response where, in order to ensure a high annually average c1 as possible in the Greek economy during transitory income shocks, the fiscal stimulus should be targeted at the poorest and unemployed part of the population. By using panel estimation, Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (2012) found that the multiplier is much greater during a recession than during an expansion, exceeding unity in the former state of the world. ”The results [...] suggest that fiscal policy activism may indeed be effective at stimulating output during a deep recession, and that the potential negative side effects of fiscal stimulus, such as increased inflation, are also less likely under these circumstances” (Auerbach and Gorodnichenko, 2012, p. 92). Similar findings can be found in Christiano et al. (2011) and DeLong and Summers (2012) among others. See e.g. Ramey (2011) for an overview on earlier literature on the fiscal multiplier. Based on this discussion it turns out that there is much to gain from using expansionary policy in Greece during a recession, especially if the stimulus is targeted at the poorest part of the population. However, every crisis is unique and in the case of the current Greek tragedy there might be more to it than this. 3.1.2 The Interlinked Crises of Greece and the Distress Premium The fact that Greece is in a recession and experiences significant pressure on both the banking sector and on its sovereign debt suggests an extension to the Keynesian model in Holden (2015). Suppose now the interest rate entrepreneurs and households face is determined by the interest rate set by the ECB and the risk premium given by the relation i = iF + d (3.1) where the risk premium, d, is an increasing function of distress which is supposed to capture how the banking sector interprets the sustainability of the fiscal stimulus. Assume that the distress variable is the same for all entrepreneurs and households and is dependent on the sustainability of the economy in line with the theory in the previous chapter. 35 Call equation (3.1) the DP relation (the distress premium relation - inspired by Mehlum (2014)). ”During a boom the popular estimation of the magnitude of both these risks, both borrower’s risk and lender’ risk, is apt to become unusually and imprudently low” (Keynes, 1936, p. 145). Thus, according to Keynes, the estimation of risk varies with the business cycle. During times of economic distress, then, the risk premium may increase to be ”unusually and imprudently high”. As discussed above, the literature suggests that fiscal stimulus could be very beneficial in a crisis situation. On the other hand, the model includes a distress-effect which could offset this through shifts in the DP-curve. How might these two forces work together - applied to the Greek tragedy? No autonomous central bank and semi-sovereignty: De Grauwe (2011) argues that the reason for the diverging interest rates on sovereign debt between Spain and the UK is because Spain has lost its capacity to issue new debt in a currency over which they have full control, which is not the case in the UK who has its own central bank. Of course this applies for all Member States in the eurozone. The fact that Greece does not control its own central bank makes the Greek economy highly vulnerable to speculative attacks against sovereign debt. Debt matters in a monetary union, and significantly so. This was discussed in depth in chapter 2. However, the main point I want to emphasize here is that the only policy tool Greece has left is fiscal policy. But since Greece is shut out of the bond market, the only way for the government to make use of this tool is dependent on the grace of other eurozone countries and their willingness to assist. Those governments are overly concerned over minimizing their financial assistance and eliminate any incentives for moral hazard which makes conditional loans the only alternative provided. Greece has become a semi-sovereign where the only chance for fiscal stimulus is by receiving foreign loans which only increases the debt-to-GDP ratio - causing economic distress as it puts more pressure on the debt-part of the crisis. One could also argue that each debt-financed stimulus package comes at the expense of less democratic sovereignty. The more Greece is at the mercy of its creditors, the more unattractive the Greek banking sector might become because of the anticipation of social and political turmoil in the future. Debt, growth and banking: The unfortunate institutional features of the EMU has then led Greece to rely on foreign debt. The distress caused by this might be reflected in several aspects of the crisis. The Greek crisis is threefold: negative growth, unsustainable sovereign debt and illiquid banks. These three aspects of the economy are interlinked and interact with one another in many ways, as discussed by Shambaugh (2012). For example, ”the problems of weak banks and high sovereign debt are mutually reinforcing, and both are exacerbated by weak growth but also in turn constrain growth” (Shambaugh, 2012, p. 157). While Greece remains in a recession with three such interlinked crises, it is likely 36 that economic distress will remain significant even after the implementation of measures that could solve one of them. Such connections would likely create very bad conditions in order for expansionary fiscal policy to work sufficiently without the necessary coordination with this and other policy instruments. Greek banks suffer from low liquidity and are also dependent on new recapitalization trough bailout packages from foreign creditors2 . In their Covered Bond Programme Prospectus for 2016 the Greek financial institution, Alpha Bank Group, writes that: Since the end of 2009, the severity of pressure experienced by the Hellenic Republic in its public finances has restricted the access of the Issuer to the capital markets for funding because of concerns by counterparty banks and other lenders[...] As a result, maturing inter-bank liabilities have not been renewed, or have been renewed only at higher costs. (Alpha Bank, 2016, p. 40) As the fiscal stimulus comes at the expense of more pressure on the public finances, this may further magnify this effect as banks cut back on interbank lending and lending to the private sector by raising the interest rate. Borrowing at higher interest rates to replace funds that where provided much cheaper before increases the risk for insolvency. An increased debt-to-GDP ratio might be interpreted as an increase in the probability of sovereign default, and as described in the previous chapter, changes in long-term government bond-yields are an important driver of bank lending rates as sovereign bonds are directly serving as a benchmark for the pricing of loans and other assets (Cæuré, 2013). The risk premium as a function of distress may increase as a response - making a self-fulfilling prophecy more likely through increased number of non-performing loans (NPLs), private bankruptcies, and reduced growth. Lower growth may result in falling asset prices which damage the bank’s balance sheets and worsen their competitiveness with foreign banks even further: [...] worsening macroeconomic conditions and increasing unemployment, coupled with declining consumer spending and business investment and the worsening credit profile of corporate and retail borrowers, the value of assets collateralising secured loans, including houses and other real estate, could decline significantly. Such a decline could result in impairment of the value of the Issuer’s loan assets or an increase in the level on non-performing loans, either of which may have a material adverse effect on business, financial condition, results of operations and prospects. (Alpha Bank, 2016, p. 40) Lower growth again increases the real value of debt and so the story goes. In addition, tax evasion puts even more pressure on public finances which damages the credibility of the 2 The 3rd bailout package of 86 billion euro from the ESM and the IMF with a duration of three years (2015-18) includes up to 25 billion euro for bank recapitalization. 37 administrative capacity of the government. Greece could surely benefit from a structural reform in the tax system and an improvement to its administrative structure since a more effective and fair tax system could potentially strengthen the credibility of the State. This confidence could further divert over to the financial sector an be reflected in lower distress premiums. Projection errors: One could argue that economic distress is also dependent on how the economy is presented by reviewers and media. This is particularly interesting considering the IMF and their projections. Since the first bailout package the IMF has repeatedly been overestimating the projected economic growth rates of Greece which implies that the IMF has repeatedly underestimated the debt-to-GDP ratio and the need for a debt relief (Mehlum, 2015). This have resulted in continuous revisions and disappointments which do nothing but damage the perceived sustainability and credibility of Greek public finances. When confronted by the question of why the situation is worse than projected, the typical argument is that it is due to delayed implementation of the agreed reforms by the Greek government. Thus, by basing their projections on statistical methods which repeatedly fail and rather blame the Greeks for their underperformance, one could argue that the IMF is providing another reason for distress and uncertainty which the economy could have been far better without. Grexit: Another important reason for distress is the looming shadow of Grexit which has been widely discussed since 2012. If Greece were to leave the EMU and reintroduce the drachma as its currency, this would lead to a significant increase in all euro denominated debt - making the situation even more unsustainable. The drachma would certainly depreciate against the euro and hence reduce the value of all euro-denominated deposits in Greek banks, increase inflation and reduce the purchasing power of the average Greek citizen. ”A new currency would be sure to depreciate sharply. Inflation would soar. In the medium run, however, order would presumably be restored in some way, even at enormous cost” (Wolf, 2014, p. 305). In order to lower the exchange rate, interest rates need to increase which in turn will make it more difficult for the Greeks to pay off their debts. The Bank of Greece could print money in order to repay debt, but this will increase inflation and interest rates further and maybe end in a hyperinflation as in Germany after WWI. Many argue that a Grexit could be a better alternative rather than internal devaluation as the low value of the drachma will boost exports and tourism without facing union resistance against wage cut proposals. An open devaluation could circumvent such resistance. This is exactly what Sinn suggests when he argues that: The possibly fatal problems resulting from wage and price cuts of the order 38 required to achieve competitiveness could be avoided by exiting the euro and devaluating the new currency formally, because that is in effect a coordinated wage and price cut relative to the prices of other countries. It would redirect demand away from imports to domestic products, increase demand for the country’s exports and reduce the euro value of the country’s internal debt along with the euro value of internal prices, thus avoiding the balance sheet distortion for firms and indebted private households. (Sinn, 2014, p. 9) However, one could argue that the negative impact on the banking sector makes it difficult to expand the export sector in the first place. As discussed in section 2.3, the significant current account imbalances which evolved after the creation of the euro forced deficit countries to become more domestic oriented while the surplus countries developed an advantage in trade. Thus, the Greek export sector lags behind and is dependent on investment to expand. With a Greek banking sector in distress, such an expansion may prove to be challenging. The prospects of losing parts of your deposits led to a bank run in Greece in 2012, where the Greek citizens withdrew euros in fear of losing them otherwise. This magnifies the problem of already weak liquidity among Greek banks. As long as the Grexit discussion continues, the uncertainties and grim prospects associated with such a scenario will make Greek banks in constant need of recapitalization and investments in order to remain liquid and solvent. Because of the prolonged negotiations between the Greek government and the creditor institutions before the agreement of the ESM bailout package, capital outflows were significant as the financial market feared a disagreement and a possible Grexit further down the road. ”The loss of confidence exacerbated the economic sentiment indicators and private sector financing conditions, causing a significant outflow of deposits in the Greek banking sector of approximately 48 billion euros from 30 September 2014 to 30 September 2015” (Alpha Bank, 2016, p. 39). As there are several reasons for not investing in Greek banks as long as Grexit is a possible scenario, this will prolong the banking crisis which is interlinked with the crises of growth and sovereign debt - hindering an effective use of expansionary fiscal policy. A single departure from the eurozone may also create further distress within the countries that remain in the union. ”If countries in difficulties leave, it is just an exceptionally rigid fixed-currency system. So any departure would have a destabilizing effect: people would trust in the eurozone’s survival even less and the economic benefits of the single currency would dwindle” (Wolf, 2014, p. 305). This could further increase the costs of inter-bank-lending and hamper economic activity throughout the eurozone. Finally, consider the effects in a figure. All the above mentioned aspects and reasons for economic distress which could lead to higher interest rates implies that the original positive shock to government expenses will be reduced by a positive shift in the DP-curve. Thus, as in the previous chapter where the unsustainable economy ended in a vicious spi39 ral, such a spiral may also be created in demand-driven Keynesian economy as a banking sector in distress responds to the increased probability of default with continuously increasing risk premiums. Figure 3.2 illustrates this. The economy starts out in point A i = iF + d DP3 C iF A DP2 DP1 B DP0 IS1 IS0 Y Yd Y0 Y1 Figure 3.2: IS-DP: The effect of a positive shock to government expenses with distress premium in a monetary union with GDP equal to Y0 . Then a shock to G implies a positive fiscal multiplier which leads the economy to point B in the figure with a corresponding level of GDP given by Y1 . Further, even if increased government expenses increases GDP and inflation as predicted by the Keynesian setup, the risk premiums due to economic distress in a unsustainable economy might offset those effects. A country like Greece could end up in point C with a corresponding level of GDP given by Yd instead. Assume that d = 0 in Germany. Is it the case that any Greek borrower could simply borrow at lower costs by undertaking a loan in a bank in Berlin rather than in Athens? The risk premium any borrower has to pay is dependent on the overall creditworthiness of the borrower, hence all non-Greek banks will also include a distress premium if lending to a Greek citizen operating in a vulnerable Greek business environment. The overall macroeconomic distress and risks in the Greek economy are common risk factors for all Greek consumers and investors and is a problem not circumvented by undertaking loans in banks outside Greece. It is the common negative effects the unsustainable economy of Greece have on the creditworthiness of Greek consumers and investors which creates differences in individual borrowing costs within the union - not regional differences per se. According to Christiano et al. (2011) and DeLong and Summers (2012), increased government spending will increase expected inflation. With a nominal interest rate stuck at the zero lower bound, this implies a reduced real interest rate which increases consumption and investment further and gives an even larger multiplier during a recession. 40 However, with a distress premium the real interest rate is not necessarily reduced since r = i − π e = iF + d − π e (3.2) so if increased expected inflation happens at the same time as an increased distress premium, the real interest rate might remain constant or even increase. This is in contrast to the argument by DeLong and Summers (2012) who argue that the risk spreads will fall after an increase in government spending as a more prosperous economy implies a lower price of bearing risk. This section has made use of the classical Keynesian paradigm with a distress premium extension. Because of the considerable slack in the economy with idle workers and free resources, in addition to a larger fraction of cash-to-mouth individuals, the fiscal multiplier after a shock to government expenses could be highly productive without any trade-off in the form of too high inflation. However, the specific Greek circumstances discussed above might trigger an offsetting mechanism through increased risk premiums in the banking sector. As the Alpha Bank describes; the severity of pressure experienced by Greece has restricted the access to the capital markets, and maturing inter-bank liabilities has only been renewed at higher costs. Thus, adding a variable of distress seems like a valid extension to the model. Moreover, reduced net exports might worsen competitiveness which was one of the underlying reasons for the crisis. Before discussing some policy suggestions which could ensure a better outcome with d = 0, the next sections will discuss and analyse the actual policy that dominates current European economic policy, namely fiscal austerity. 3.2 Fiscal Austerity and Prior Actions: Distortionary Tax Increases and Government Spending Cuts According to IMF’s definition, prior actions are measures that a country agrees to take before the IMF’s Executive Board approves financing or completes a review. They ensure that the programme has the necessary foundation to succeed, or is put back on track following deviations from agreed policies 3 . Greece is in principle free to design the prior actions as long as the actions are sufficient to reach the budgetary targets defined by the creditors. However, according to the Memorandum of Understanding the Greek government must commit to consult and agree with the Troika beforehand. As the Greek government targets to reach primary surplus targets in line with the last bailout agreement of 0.5 percent of GDP in 2016, 1.75 percent of GDP in 2017 and 3.5 percent of GDP 3 The complete factsheet is available at: https://www.imf.org/external/np/exr/facts/conditio.htm 41 Figure 3.3: Source: European Commission AMECO database. The evolution of indirect taxes, direct taxes and social contributions in Greece as percent of GDP. in 2018 and onwards (EC, 2015a), the government has implemented and planned several austerity measures in order to achieve them. This section will briefly look at how the contractionary policies are currently designed. As a part of the adjustment programme, Greece committed to reform the tax system in order to broaden the tax base and reduce the significant level of tax evasion. In addition to the structural tax reform, the government also committed to impose several austerity measures through tax hikes. For example, the government targeted to reach a net revenue gain of 1 percent of GDP annually by increasing reduced VAT rates on many items such as restaurants (from 13 percent to 23 percent) and hotel accommodations (from 6.5 percent to 13 percent), as well as a broad batch of consumption goods (from 13 percent to 23 percent). In addition, exemptions for Greek islands that are popular tourist destinations were removed except from on the most remote ones. For Greek businesses which are struggling to create profits in a period of low demand and limited access to credit, the most drastic measure is probably the increase in the corporate income tax rate from 26 to 29 percent which will likely worsen the business environment. The tax hikes and austerity measures also include; increased advance payments on profit taxes from 75 percent to 100 percent; increased solidarity tax rate on wealth for high income earners; a phasing out of the preferential tax treatment for farmers in addition to cuts in their subsidies; an increase in the tax on luxury goods such as vessels and private jets; a phasing out of special tax treatments in the shipping industry. Figure 3.3 illustrates the evolution of the different sources of government revenues between 2008 and 2016. The figure shows that indirect taxes contribute the most to government revenues. Both indirect taxes through increased VATs and social contributions through pension reforms have resulted in upward trends since the prior actions of 2015. Direct tax revenues from income and wealth have declined since 2012. This is not surprising as the tax base has been reduced due to the high unemployment rate. However, taxation and transfers are 42 Figure 3.4: Source: European Commission AMECO database. The evolution of Greek total general government expenditures as percent of GDP between 2008-2016. costly to administer and they effect the optimal consumption, -labour, and -investment decisions of firms and households - creating distortions. Hence the tax hikes may prove to be more costly for the Greek government than first anticipated. Even though the theory of distortionary taxation is not a necessary part in the Keynesian model used in this chapter, this is certainly something a Minister of Finance needs to consider in the real world. Many economists, such as Barro (1979), have showed how optimal tax policy is to smooth taxation over time, as a euro of increased tax revenue to the government is worth less than a euro because of the distortions it creates. Therefore, as the events of the 1970s and 1980s suggest very strongly, when governments become strapped for funds, they tend to rely more heavily on bonds’ issuance rather than taxation (Calvo, 1988). But Greece does not have this possibility at the time of writing. On the spending side the Greek government target to reduce military spending by 200 million euro in 2016. Additional savings corresponding to 1 percent of GDP will be achieved by reforming the pension system, mainly by creating strong disincentives to early retirement, gradually phase out solidarity grants and increase the health contributions for pensioners from 4 - 6 percent on average. Gradual budget cuts have been made in several other areas since 2010 e.g. in health care. ”In late 2012, the health system, squeezed by budget cuts, failed to pay doctors even their basic salaries” (Kuttner, 2014, p. 137). As a consequence, more and more health care costs shifted towards patients. The effects of austerity on the health sector is a general illustration of how fiscal consolidation affects the overall economy. Figure 3.4 illustrates the evolution of total general government expenditure as percent of GDP between 2008-2016. Greece experienced a strong expenditure growth up until 2011. However, after the first bailout in 2010 the expenses declined from about 50 percent of GDP to 45 percent and remained at a stable level from 2013. The austerity has resulted in yet a downward curve in 2016 , pushing expenses below 45 percent of GDP. Figure 3.5 shows the convergence between total expenses and 43 Figure 3.5: Source: European Commission AMECO database. The convergence between Greek total expenses and revenues as percent of GDP between 2008 - 2016. revenues (including capital taxes) which implies a continuously reduced primary deficit. According to the Keynesian model, contractionary policy can be achieved by increasing taxes and cutting in government expenses. As Greece do both as prior actions in order to achieve a primary surplus so to further receive bailouts, the implication is significantly reduced growth according to the model. The next section analyse this further, where the main focus will be on the risks of a vicious spiral in the real economy. 3.3 Fiscal Austerity: A Temporary Recession or Another Vicious Spiral? 3.3.1 The Fiscal Multiplier and the G-T Contradiction Section 3.1 showed that expansionary fiscal policy has the potential to be highly productive, but the beneficial effect runs the risk of being offset by increased distress premiums. The conditionality of the bailout packages reflects that the creditors are very aware of this inefficiency, thus they demand that Greece implement structural reforms to restore fiscal sustainability, safeguarding financial stability, enhancing growth, competitiveness and investment, and develop a more effective and modern State. Of course, should Greece manage to implement such reforms the country could greatly benefit from d = 0 so that the effectiveness of the fiscal policy would be enhanced. However, as discussed in section 3.2, the implementation of bold reforms is combined with strict rules regarding fiscal targets. From the creditors’ point of view, the period of adjustment must be accompanied by a period of austerity. Fiscal consolidation through increased taxation, cuts in pensions, and labour market reforms are some of the criteria Greece needs to satisfy in order to increase the primary surplus enough to satisfy the creditor’s targets and receive further 44 loans. How might the multiplier look in this case? Suppose the tax reform is implemented so that the tax rate t in the model is relatively higher than previously, and that the incidence of tax evasion is reduced. Then the government reduce its expenses. The model then implies −1 ∂Y = <0 ∂G 1 − c1 (1 − t) − b1 + a1 + a3 Yβn so a reduction in government expenses reduces GDP with the same multiplier effects as previously. According to the Phillips-curve, Greece would then experience an even larger output gap, increased deflation and idled workers as GDP falls further below its potential. Increased unemployment reduces government revenues through a reduced tax base which implies less tax revenues and social contributions to the government. Moreover, more unemployed people require welfare expenses. Thus, the reformed taxation system in Greece will now make little difference. There is a contradiction in this regard. The tax reform was supposed to increase tax revenues to the government, but in combination with a negative shock to G the effect will be somewhat offset through lower growth, increased unemployment -and welfare expenses. According to the model, if the goal is to ”restore fiscal sustainability”, increased taxes and cuts in government expenses are contradictory actions. What Greece is in fact doing is to increase the tax rate and reduce the tax base at the same time. However, net exports are expected to increase as imports are reduced. As already discussed to some extent, this is an argument in support for austerity in the deficit countries of the eurozone. As Greece’s reduced imports are other countries’ reduced exports this will also affect the country’s trading partners. Fiscal consolidation could increase the Greek trading surplus although it is at the expense of the country’s trading partners and its own citizens. If Greece is to improve their competitive position, surplus countries must accept to reduce their position by increasing overall demand for imports. Again one could propose the argument that reduced prices on Greek goods is not necessarily followed by increased exports as a Greek banking sector in distress is unable to provide the sufficient capital needed in order to expand the export sector. Banks with insufficient funds may not be able to support the parts of the economy which are to create economic growth. In their paper Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal Multipliers, Blanchard and Leigh (2013) ask whether forecasters have underestimated fiscal multipliers after the outbreak of the debt crisis. Earlier evidence suggested that the fiscal multiplier averaged 0.5. By regressing growth forecast errors on fiscal consolidation forecast made early in 2010, they find a negative and significant relationship. The coefficient on the forecast of fiscal consolidation is -1.095, ”implying that, for every additional percentage point of GDP of fiscal consolidation, GDP was about 1 percent lower than forecast” (Blanchard and Leigh, 2013, 45 p. 8). If the earlier literature used growth projections that implicitly assumed multipliers more consistent with normal times, this might have led to the repeated projections errors. Again, one could refer to the literature in the section about expansionary fiscal multipliers where all suggested that multipliers during recessions are relatively larger. This is indeed not good news for austeritarians. As emphasized by Christiano et al. (2011) and DeLong and Summers (2012); with the ECB interest rates in the zero lower bound the central bank can no longer offset the negative effects of austerity. Then the fiscal consolidation becomes especially efficacious. And yet, even though a vast empirical literature suggests that austerity is associated with large negative multipliers, austerity is still the dominant view in current European policymaking. Before discussing the theory of expansionary fiscal contractions which gives additional support to such policies, the next subsection suggests a model that shows how austerity in a recession might lead to total collapse. 3.3.2 The Recession Premium and the Armoury of the ECB A relevant and important question to ask when assuming that the Greek recession will be temporary while the economy adjusts to its new structure and implement fiscal consolidation at the same time is how long is temporary and are there any risks of being stuck in a bad equilibrium? Section 2.4.3 and and 3.1.2 showed that a bad equilibrium was possible in the market for sovereign debt and in the real economy respectively. Now consider a final scenario. Leave my extension of the RR-curve given by equation (3.1) for now and rather assume that the endogenous risk premium is a decreasing function of GDP when the economy is in a recession, as shown by Mehlum (2014). Denote potential GDP as Y ∗ , so that if GDP is less than this level the economy is in a recession. Use that iF + e + e (Y ∗ − Y ) 0 1 i= iF + e 0 if Y < Y ∗ if Y > Y ∗ (3.3) which Mehlum (2014) calls the RP-relation (risk-premium relation) and is horizontal when the economy is not in a recession, but decreasing in Y otherwise. If e1 is large, the part of the RP-curve which is decreasing in Y will be steep. Thus, the curves might intersect twice. Figure 3.6 illustrates this. Consider first the IS0 -curve with two intersections in point A0 and B0 . If Greece is in the good equilibrium A0 to the right of the threshold Y ∗ , an increase in the recession premium e would simply shift the RP-curve upwards and the multiplier will be equal to the one in section 3.1. However, if Greece is in the bad equilibrium B0 to the left of Y ∗ , the total effect on GDP will be greater after a shock to the recession premium. This can 46 i B0 A1 A0 RP0 IS0 IS1 Y Y Y ∗ Figure 3.6: IS-RP: The effect of a negative shock to government expenses with an endogenous recession premium in a monetary union be seen from the multiplier which is slightly different than before: −(c2 + b2 ) ∂Y = <0 ∂e0 1 − c1 (1 − t) − c2 e1 − b1 − b2 e1 + a1 + a3 Yβn This multiplier is greater than the earlier ones of this chapter. The adverse effect on growth results in even higher risk premiums which adversely affects consumption and investment, captured by c2 e1 and b2 e1 . Consider next the IS1 -curve which is a consequence of fiscal consolidation. Had Greece been in the good equilibrium A0 to begin with, the fiscal contraction had led the economy to point A1 without any adverse effect on the recession premium. The only implication would be a lower level of GDP. However, assume that Greece is in a recession which implies that the economy was described by the unstable point B0 before the austerity. Since this is an unstable equilibrium, the shock to G sets in motion a vicious spiral. This is illustrated by the dashed line stemming from point B0 . The vicious spiral will continue until Y where the IS-curve would be vertical. Towards this point, firms go bankrupt and the banks face more severe liquidity problems as the number of non-performing loans increases. Then the banks cut back on lending by raising the interest rate. This makes it more difficult for the remaining firms in the market to get access to credit and the number of bankruptcies increases further. Unfortunately it seems like that this is a real concern among Greek financial institutions. The Alpha Bank reported in 2016 that: The financial recession in The Hellenic Republic materially and adversely affected the liquidity, business activity and financial condition of borrowers, which in turn led to increases in non-performing loans[...] Should GDP continue to decline, further increases in non-performing loans are likely. (Alpha 47 Bank, 2016, p. 39) The spiral may force banks into insolvency, and when the economy reaches Y , economic activity is so low that there is no longer a financial market. In other words, austerity pushed to far may result in a longer-than-anticipated recession. Nobel laureate economist Joseph Stiglitz expresses similar concerns in his book Globalization and its discontents where he writes that ”a crisis can give rise to an vicious cycle wherein banks cut back on their finance, leading firms to cut back on their production, which in turn leads to lower output and lower incomes” (Stiglitz, 2002, p. 114). The combination of a debt crisis, growth crisis, and banking crisis creates expectations of future economic difficulties which may be self-fulfilling as they add fuel to the fire. According to Stiglitz: The IMF model - as in the models of most of the macroeconomics textbooks written two decades ago - bankruptcy plays no role. To discuss monetary policy and finance without bankruptcy is like Hamlet without the Prince of Denmark. At the heart of the analysis of the macroeconomy should have been an analysis of what an increase in interest rates would do to the chances of default[...]. (Stiglitz, 2002, p. 110) As investors recognize the spirals and the looming shadow of default upon both the government and private sector, investors might drive their capital out of the country. Unfortunately, capital has a tendency be withdrawn from economies that need it the most. Corporations withdraw capital from Greek businesses and less affluent Greek households would rather save their money in their mattresses. Instead of preventing the escape of capital from peripheral countries such as Greece towards safe countries such as Germany and Switzerland, deepening Europe’s regional distortions, Europe’s leaders exacerbated this effect through austerity (Kuttner, 2013, p. 113). The monetary policy decision of the ECB announced in March this year included new instruments that could ease the pressure on European banks and foster new lending. The extension of the ”Targeted Longer-Term Refinancing Operations” (TLTRO II) is meant to ease the private sector credit conditions and to stimulate credit creation by offer funding with four-year maturity at a interest rate as low as the rate on the deposit facility at the time of allotment. Separate borrowing limits depend on the quantities of outstanding loans and net lending. This implies that banks that are active in lending to the real economy will have the opportunity to borrow more from the programme. In addition, the ECB increased the combined monthly ”Asset Purchasing Programme” (APP) by 20 billion euros (from 60 to 80 billion) where the purchases will include euro-denominated corporate bonds. This is called the ”The Corporate Sector Purchase Programme (CSPP) and is intended to have a positive effect in the real economy. ”This comprehensive package will exploit the synergies between the different instruments and has been calibrated to 48 further ease financing conditions, stimulate new credit provision and thereby reinforce the momentum of the euro areas economic recovery and accelerate the return of inflation to levels below, but close to, 2 percent” (ECB, 2016). The fact that the instruments are complementary increases their effectiveness as the CSPP directly affect demand for investment while the TLTROs increases the banks ability to lend. However, while the ECB provides additional funds into a banking sector in distress, the Greek government is forced to reduce private purchasing power through austerity which constrains aggregate demand. One could argue that the TLTRO-instrument will prove less effective in Greece as the recession has forced 1.2 million Greeks into unemployment so that banks cannot find any use of the money. Again, the argument that solving one crisis while worsening others, applies. The expansionary monetary policy would most likely proven to be relatively more effective in stimulating credit demand had the highly indebted European countries been allowed to create a proper environment for investment at the same time instead of hamper growth. The president of the ECB himself, Mario Draghi, said during the press conference that: In particular, actions to raise productivity and improve the business environment, including the provision of an adequate public infrastructure, are vital to increase investment and boost job creation[...]Fiscal policies should support the economic recovery, while remaining in compliance with the fiscal rules of the European Union. (ECB, 2016) But in order to remain in compliance with the fiscal rules of the European Union, several euro-countries, especially Greece, must contract their economies to a large extent. The official fiscal targets of the EMU could work as a preventive arm in order to put a lid on excessive spending during normal times. However, fiscal targets are extremely risky as means to recover from a deep recession. If the analysis of this thesis holds, an analysis much in the spirit of Nobel laureates such as Joseph Stiglitz (2002) and Amartya Sen (2012), it is rather worrying that the ECB thinks that austerity and recovery are complementary. 3.4 Expansionary Fiscal Contractions and the Confidence Fairy So far the only argument in support for austerity as a way of recovery emphasized the importance of restoring competitiveness, as argued by Sinn (2014). This section will briefly mention some other arguments. In the discussion of why the beneficial effect of expansionary fiscal policy might be somewhat offset I assumed only that the extraordinary political, 49 social, and economic circumstances in Greece could be reflected in a risk premium in the banking sector. Arguments regarding precautionary saving and preferences for consumption smoothing did not play a role. However, those arguments are central themes within the theory of expansionary fiscal contractions which give additional support to austerity economics. Those economists who call for austerity base their theory on what Krugman (2013) ridiculed as the ”confidence fairy”. For example, the permanent income hypothesis (PIH) implies that only a permanent increase in G will have an effect on consumption. Assuming that all individuals are perfectly rational and prefer to smooth consumption over their entire life cycle, a transitory shock to G would imply approximately no change in consumption behaviour as the increase in transitory income is spread over the entire life cycle, making each financial addition to each year vanishingly small. Whether the fiscal policy is productive is dependent on how investors and households perceive the shock as permanent or transitory. Preferences for consumption smoothing might lead to precautionary saving if the private sector expects an expansionary fiscal shock to be transitory, hence further expecting tax hikes in the future since the government needs to pay back what it borrowed. As future tax hikes reduce future profits and increase the probability of weaker firms going bankrupt, households and firms may behave precautionary and save the transitory income provided through G rather than use it to increase their consumption and investment. According to Barro: ”[...]rearrangements of the timing of taxes - as implied by budget deficits - have no first-order effect on the economy” (Barro, 1989, p. 51). Some economists argue that a large public debt overhang causes precautionary saving so that the fiscal multiplier is near zero or negative if the debt-to-GDP ratio exceeds a certain threshold. Ilzetzki et al. (2013) found that the fiscal multiplier in highly indebted countries is close to zero as the financial fragility motivated precautionary behaviour. They operate with a debt-to-GDP ratio threshold of 60 percent which would certainly apply in Greece. Keynes himself mention the effect of precautionary savings when he wrote that ”the propensity to consume may be sharply affected by the development of extreme uncertainty concerning the future and what it may bring forth” (Keynes, 1936, p. 94). So if expansionary fiscal policies can be contractionary if the debt is large enough, can it be that contractionary policies might be expansionary? There are many interesting discussions and empirical evidence of expansionary fiscal contractions which contradict the implications of the Keynesian model. Fels and Froehlich (1987) argue in support of the ”German view” which implies that, reducing deficits by keeping a lid on public expenditure growth, the public sector can make room for the private sector to expand, depending on the magnitude and persistence of the cuts. Hellewig and Neumann (1987) argue that expansionary fiscal contraction might be possible through the indirect effect of expectations. If the design of the fiscal corrections is well understood and the plan 50 for the future is credible so that the lower level of public expenditures (and thus lower taxation in the future) will last, then private households may interpret the cut in public spending as a startingpoint for a time of stability, hence raising their current and planned consumption. Giavazzi and Pagano (1990) and Alesina and Ardagna (2010) tested the hypothesis. The former study shows how fiscal contractions in Ireland and Denmark in the 1980s resulted in increased consumption; cases where the German view has a serious claim to empirical relevance. The latter study shows, by studying cases of fiscal adjustments in OECD countries between 1970 and 2007, that several deficit reductions have been associated with expansions rather than with contractions. But these studies looked at countries with floating exchange rates where the beneficial effect through increased exports after a depreciation of the currency contributed to the expansion. This is not possible for a singe country within the EMU. The theory of expansionary austerity hinges on the requirement that the financial market and private households interprets austerity as ”good news”. When the above sections discussed the Keynesian model, expectations played only a minimal role through expected inflation. In austerity economics, expectations is the central theme. Krugman writes: First, our [the Keynesian types] expectations argument is a hope; theirs [the austerity types] is a plan. I want the Fed, the Bank of Japan, etc. to target higher inflation, in the hope that it might help, but it’s a hope and meanwhile we need to fight demands for fiscal austerity and even push for stimulus. The expansionary austerity types, on the other hand, are (or were) actually counting on the supposed rise in confidence to avoid what would otherwise be nasty recessions, which have in fact materialized. (Krugman, 2013) Making expansionary austerity into a general theory may prove to be dangerous as its effectiveness in the bottom line depends on interpretation. Even though empirical support that this in fact did happen in Denmark and Ireland in the 1980s, the words credibility and expectations are crucial when discussing its external validity. Given that the current crisis in Greece is much more severe and the content of the fiscal corrections are different than compared to Denmark and Ireland in the 1980s, the external validity of this finding may not hold as the credibility of government policies and expectations about future economic stability may be significantly reduced. Hence, contrasting theories and empirical evidence on what kind of fiscal policy is the most appropriate to implement in order to recover from a recession are many. Before concluding this chapter, the next section briefly discusses some non-economic and broader aspects of austerity. 51 3.5 Beyond the Keynesian Effects: Social and Political Effects of Austerity in a Recession Shortly after the agreement of the third programme in 2015, The European Commission published an Assessment of the Social Impact of the New Stability Support Programme for Greece (EC, 2015b). The document discusses how the the burden of adjustment is spread across society and what measures will help mitigate social hardships. It concludes that full implementation of the ambitious reforms will increase potential GDP and strengthen competitiveness. This would increase the tax base and government revenues which further would provide possibilities for future government investments - creating a positive spiral. The validity of the positive estimates within this document is conditional on full implementation of ambitious reforms, which is to say that there must be no adverse political and social affects during the time of adjustment that would hinder the process. As the German Finance Minister Wolfgang Schäubel simply summarized during the World Economic Forum in Davos this year: ”It’s the implementation, stupid!” However, the adverse social and political effects of austerity have been evident since the first adjustment program in 2010. The policies have resulted in a critical social tension which follows as the country’s citizens interpret the imposed austerity as a broken social contract between the government and its citizens it is supposed to protect. Since the reason for the European debt crisis was the extremely unbalanced competitive positions between surplus -and deficit countries within the eurozone, and not the fiscal position of each country per se, the fact that Germany as the largest surplus country of all now forces economic austerity upon Greece generates enormous tensions. The belief that the European sovereign debt crisis was a result of irresponsible fiscal policies has shifted current eurozone policymaking towards austerity. ”This view is not only misleading, but dangerous. That it is held by the eurozones’s strongest country is frightening” (Wolf, 2014, p. 75). The different fates after the crisis have resulted in a tense eurozone where the loosing countries, now under the mercy of the well-off surplus countries, feel that their democratic sovereignty is under attack. This may be be hard for the Greek citizens to accept - further leading to political chaos. Since 2009, Greece have had six different prime ministers and heads of care taking governments4 . Of course, any democratic government is doomed to face a major challenge convincing the public that further austerity is the key to recovery, especially when the hard policies are imposed by EU officials beyond direct democratic accountability. 4 George Papandreou (2009 - 2011), Lucas Papademos (2011 - 2012), Panagiotis Pikrammenos (May 2012 - June 2012), Antonis Samaras (2012 - 2015), Alexis Tsipras (January 2015 - August 2015) Vassiliki Thanou-Christophilou (August 2015 - September 2015) and again Alexis Tsipras (September 2015 -). 52 According to Nobel laureate economist Amartya Sen, ”the disdain for the public could hardly have been more transparent in many of the chosen ways of European policymaking” (Sen, 2012). He argues that austerity generates so many adverse effects on people’s lives that one need to look beyond the pure Keynesian effects that cuts in public spending have on aggregate demand and growth and also take seriously what such an austeritarian attack on the Greek welfare state represents in terms of social justice. According to Gøsta Esping-Andersen’s Why we need a new welafare state; the longer the economic hardship lasts, the more severe is the social consequences while ”citizens become entrapped in exclusion of inferior opportunities in such a way that their entire life chances are affected” (Esping-Andersen, 2002, p. 6). Thus, insufficient focus on job creation runs the risk of having severe consequences for the unemployed since unemployment implies personal costs which may endure long past the immediate loss of a job. The dynamic social effects of a longer-than-anticipated recession could imply a lost generation of Greece as the hardships experienced among the Greek youths correlate with a problematic employment career later in life, which increases the chances for old age poverty. ”And considering ongoing pension reforms, most of will come to full fruition thirty or forty years down the line, it is equally reasonable to believe that these very same youth will face welfare problems as they reach pension age in, say, 2050” (Esping-Andersen, 2002, p. 7). Riots and political turmoil increases the probability of capital fleeing the country and worsen the economic conditions as business -and investor confidence is damaged by the insecurity. A high unemployment rate among youths, combined with the risk that productivity might deteriorate as high quality workers seek jobs elsewhere in Europe which makes it difficult for new businesses and institutions in Greece to find qualified human capital, could further affect the long-run development of Greek institutions. By treating Greece as a semi-sovereign by imposing austerity and demands for better institutions might generate adverse forces that makes the dream of institution-building into a ineffective and distorted obsession. Especially the cuts associated with pensions and health have triggered social tensions. While the pension policy has remained generous and unaltered during the period of declining GDP, government spending on pensions stand about 15 percent of GDP in 2015. However, as unemployment has elevated, unemployed families may rely on the pensions of retired family members. Cutting pension, in combination with planned tax hikes, may thus trigger personal crises and further insecurity among the unemployed. The discontent over the removal of tax breaks and subsidy benefits for farmers, and increased pension contributions for the self-employed led to several riots in the beginning of 2016. Farmers rallied in demonstrations in Athens and started a blockade of highways across the country. 53 According to Kentikelenis et al. (2014), the health sector was hit by austerity measures leading to severe adverse health effects among the population as health care costs shifted from the government to the patients, resulting in a reduction in health-care access despite of the rhetoric of ”maintaining universal access and improving the quality of care delivery” in Greece’s bailout agreement. In addition, since the social health-insurance is linked to employment status, the increasing unemployment rate raises the number of uninsured people which force them to seek out help from non-governmental organizations mainly targeting the refugee crisis. The rapid socioeconomic change has lead to increased demand for mental health services, but service providers have scaled back such operations because of budget cuts. They point out several additional adverse effects such as the increased number of children receiving inadequate nutrition and the increased suicide rate, and conclude that ”although the adverse economic effects of austerity were miscalculated, the social costs were ignored, with harmful effects on the people of Greece” (Kentikelenis et al., 2014, p. 751). Imposed conditionality may create hostility if the way the conditionality is imposed does not consider the important aspects discussed in this section. The riots and demonstrations in Greece the last year is a clear evidence of this. Many economists express their concern for the recent development of extremist political views and resentment throughout Europe. ”Anger and frustration, in many different forms, have generated tensions among countries with different fortunes within the euro zone, and have also empowered extremist politics of a kind that Europe expected to leave behind” (Sen, 2012). A more bold statement was expressed by Wolf who writes that ”Europe is under way of the ideas of Heinrich Brünig, German chancellor between 1930 and 1932, whose disastrous policy of austerity prepared the way for Adolf Hitler” (Wolf, 2014, p. 291). Thus, arguing that ”it’s simply the implementation, stupid” is as misleading as it is dangerous. 3.6 The Way Ahead Chapter 2 concluded that a debt relief would certainly help in avoiding a vicious spiral in the market for sovereign debt. However, even such a drastic measure would be of limited help in an economic environment without growth. In similar vein, this chapter suggests that an expansionary fiscal policy with the aim of boosting growth is limited as long as banks are undercapitalized, the sovereign debt is unsustainable, and general prospects regarding Greece’s economic and political future continue to be pessimistic, as all this translate into a distress premium. Austerity then? Unless the confidence fairy proves to be real, this could as well end in a total collapse of the economy. To conclude: the Greek crisis consists of many interlinked vulnerabilities, hence a solution calls for bold and co54 ordinated measures. Just calling for austerity imply too many and too great risks. Even Sinn, though arguing that Greece needs austerity in order to regain growth and a stronger competitive position, realizes that the task is dangerous and even impossible when he says that ”to achieve such cuts in relative prices, one can try extreme austerity programmes to depress wages, but the result in all likelihood will be mass unemployment that tears at the very fabric of society” (Sinn, 2014, p. 8). Moreover, building future EMU-policies on the argument that the eurozone needs to rebalance through differential inflation will generate major challenges for the ECB with a clear mandate of achieving price stability. Creditors must accept a debt restructuring. The ECB must continue with its monetary expansion without having to be bumping against the austeritarian wall. Greece needs financial aid which should be targeted at the most vulnerable societal groups. Yes, Greece needs to improve its competitiveness, but this analysis has shown that the timing of austerity matters. The vicious spirals are in part consequences of ill-timed austerity which creates the worse conditions possible for implementation of structural reforms. Greece could certainly benefit from institutional reforms. By fighting tax evasion, creating a more fair and understandable pension system, and by developing a more effective administrative structure overall would do nothing but good. However, based on the theory and model implications of this chapter one could argue whether there is any reason at all to mix such reforms with fiscal austerity during a recession. While the ECB is developing instruments with expansionary effects that improve the supply of credit, further reducing the distress in the banking sector, the European policy shift towards austerity depresses aggregate demand. While the Greek government is fighting tax evasion in order to increase its revenues, the austerity increases unemployment and reduces the tax base. Reforming the pension system by, for example, increasing the retirement ages, is done in tandem with pension cuts. Bank-recapitalization in order to support the environment for investment is done in tandem with increased corporate tax rates, increased VAT rates, and subsidy cuts. The list of contradictions goes on - creating difficult conditions for reforms to be successfully implemented in the first place. Sen provides an elegant analogy in order to emphasize this important point: [...] it is as if a person had asked for an antibiotic for his fever, and been given a mixed tablet with antibiotic and rat poison. You cannot have the antibiotic without also having the rat poison. We were in fact being told that if you want economic reform then you must also have, along with it, economic austerity, although there is absolutely no reason whatsoever why the two must be put together as a chemical compound. (Sen, 2015). As section 3.3 showed, one of the key arguments in support of economic austerity is 55 the signal it shows. Austerity signals discipline which supposedly should have a positive effect on aggregate demand and investment. Further, the desire of creditors to minimize bailouts and get their loans repaid as fast as possible implies a tragic hunt for primary surpluses through austerity in the debtor country in order to get the debt level down at a sustainable level. Those plans failed in the case of Greece due to the adverse effects thoroughly discussed in this thesis. The fact that the creditors continuously repeat in their reviews and reports that, if the programme where to be implemented as agreed, no further debt relief would have been needed and Greece would have achieved sustainability in the long-run (see e.g. IMF, 2015), is thus both too simplified and too unfair (in addition, such statements are not productive in restoring investor confidence). Of course, a country that has spent beyond its means for too long must ultimately face a period of austerity. However, the austerity imposed on Greece in order to complete the necessary reforms may have been counterproductive and yielded too much unnecessary pain for the citizens. And most importantly; the timing could not have been worse. This thesis suggests that the IMF and the European policymakers should return to the classical Keynesian way of thinking about economics and support structural reforms through policies which boost aggregate demand in order to safe-guard the level of growth necessary to avoid the vicious spirals and minimize all disturbances associated with the economic adjustments. Rather than attacking basic social rights and forcing Greece into a recession which is likely to last for years, the creditors should focus on assisting Greece in achieving proper job creation and full employment. By ring-fencing health and social budgets while relaxing the fiscal targets, Greece could reform the productive base by fighting tax evasion and corruption, stimulate the economy for investments, modernize the State and public administration while not generating too much unnecessary pain to its citizens. If Greece is allowed to implement such reforms and regain its administrative credibility without too much pressure on every other aspect of the economy during the process, the country would be in better shape to develop a competitive export sector in the future. And it makes little sense to require that Greece must become more competitive if the surplus countries refuse to sacrifice some of their advantage in trade. Finally, the Greeks do not live out of fiscal targets or interest rates - they live out of work and wages. As the Greek Prime Minister Alexis Tsipras told the Economic Forum in Davos this year: ”We must all understand that, next to balanced budgets, we must also have growth[...]We need to be more realistic, and show more solidarity too” (Elliott et al., 2016). There is nothing rational about a ”recession in the short-run”. The damage done to Greek workers after periods of high interest rates, such as bankruptcies and increased unemployment and social insecurity, are not necessarily reversed for those individuals when the interest rates are lowered. This thesis has shown that, bailouts after austerity and recession, only contribute to the problem. Though Greece has an enormous debt level, the main problem is 56 the one of bad administrative arrangements. ”The distinction between reforms of bad administrative arrangements and austerity have been lost in crude financial thinking” (Sen, 2012). A debt restructuring, expansionary fiscal- and monetary policy, and structural reforms may save Greece. However, if the chosen policy is austerity, Greece is much likely to remain in a bad equilibrium for years. According to Stiglitz: Founded on the belief that there is a need for international pressures on countries to have more expansionary economic policies - such as increasing expenditures, reducing taxes, or lowering interest rates to stimulate the economy today the IMF typically provides funds only if countries engage in policies like cutting deficits, raising taxes, or raising interest rates that lead to a contraction of the economy. Keynes would be rolling over in his grave were he to see what has happened to his child. (Stiglitz, 2002, pp. 12-13) In a time where Greece’s creditors even debate between themselves whether the austerity measures are too strict, Greece’s hardship continues. 57 Chapter 4 Conclusion After the financial crisis there has been a European policy shift towards fiscal austerity. The financial crisis triggered an European sovereign debt crisis where Greece was hit especially hard. Hence, Greece had to agree on undertaking hard austerity policies in order to receive the necessary bailout packages. Thus, the Greek crisis and recovery represent an interesting case of how fiscal austerity works as a stabilization policy. The fact that Greece has been undertaking austerity measures since the first bailout package in 2010 without any significant changes in economic performance during the subsequent six years has raised the question about whether austerity, rather than Keynesian expansions, is indeed an optimal policy. This thesis has analysed this question by looking at historical data and discussing the possible effects of austerity and fiscal stimuli by applying two formal models. The findings are as follows: Was the Greek crisis a result of excessive spending over income? Between 2003-2007, Greece experienced a significant accumulation of macroeconomic an financial vulnerabilities as the country took advantage of the highly liquid banking system and the economic benefits which followed after the creation of the euro. Greece, together with Ireland, Spain and Portugal, enjoyed the credit boom up until 2007 which resulted in increased inflation above the eurozone average, increased prices and wages. Thus, those countries became current-account deficit countries where businesses oriented to the domestic economy with lower potential for productivity growth. The deficit countries then had to rely more on foreign capital inflows from surplus countries such as Germany, Netherlands and Belgium. The surplus countries, on the other hand, focused on reducing labour costs and improving productivity and competitiveness. Those imbalances in competitiveness made the current-account deficit countries especially prone to a financial crisis. The sudden stop of foreign capital inflow triggered by the financial crisis of 2008 forced Greece to reduce its deficits through internal devaluation which had adverse effects on growth and employment. The subsequent worsening of primary deficits was therefore in part a consequence of the crisis - not the reason. The recession and worsening of public finances caused by the 58 highly unbalanced eurozone shifted European policymaking toward austerity in order to restore the credibility of public finances in the crisis-stricken countries, and to re-balance the relative competitive positions which was an underlying reason for the sovereign debt crisis to happen in the first place. Did the austerity measures prove to be successful in restoring growth and improve the competitive position? By looking at historical data, section 2.3.2 discussed to what extent fiscal austerity has worked in improving Greek public finances, competitiveness and growth during the last six years. Since 2010, Greece has indeed managed to turn a negative primary balance into a positive one and the general government budget balance is expected to finally be in accordance with the Maastricht criterium. But the costs have been significant. A vicious spiral between sustainability, risk premiums and growth got Greece shut out of the bond market and the country has not yet fully returned. And even though the stock of public debt has somewhat decreased, the debt-to-GDP ratio is larger now than in 2010 because of the significant adverse effects austerity has on economic growth. The unemployment rate has stabilized around a tragic 25 percent level. The competitive position of Greece has not changed much as the improvement in the currentaccount deficit is mainly a result of reduced import and recession - not lower relative prices on Greek tradables. The price deflator for exported goods and services shows little improvement relative to the 2010 base-year. For Greece, it has been six years of trying to do the impossible. Alas, the data shows few signs of improvement. How does fiscal austerity affect public finances? Section 2.4.3 presented a debtequilibrium model based on the standard IMF definition of sustainable debt with a riskpremium extension as found in Mehlum (2012). The data showed that years with austerity measures have resulted in lower growth. Therefore, I further extended the model to include a negative relationship between austerity and economic growth and showed that a bad and unstable debt-equilibrium is more likely in such an environment. Thus, an economy trapped in such an equilibrium could benefit greatly from a debt relief. However, even though a debt relief could shift the economy from a bad equilibrium to a good one, the bad equilibrium is still present in the economy so that any large adverse shock to any of the variables in the model could force the economy back into difficulties. Such a spiral did happen in Greece which got the country shut out of the bond market in 2010. According to the model, this could have been prevented if Greece’s creditors had backed Greek recovery from the outset rather than forcing on more austerity which adversely affected interest rates and growth - generating a vicious spiral. If a debt relief is not an option because of the fear of future moral hazard, the alternative is the risk of getting into a vicious spiral and ultimately default as a result of the tragic hunt for sustainable debt under worse and worse conditions. 59 How does a fiscal expansion affect the Greek real economy in a recession? Section 3.1 used a demand-driven Keynesian model and discussed the mechanisms of how a fiscal expansion could result in increased demand and investment, increased GDP, lower unemployment and reduced deflationary pressure. But according to the model, a positive shock to government expenses also affects prices and exports in the opposite direction of what is necessary in order to improve the competitive position. I further introduced a distress premium and showed how the positive effects of a fiscal expansion could be offset by a higher distress premium in the banking sector. Thus, even though classical Keynesian theory suggests that a fiscal expansion could be highly beneficial during a recession, the extraordinary circumstances of the Greek recession could prove otherwise. The adverse effect on competitiveness, more pressure on public finances, increased distress premiums, a larger number of non-performing loans, and the worrisome prospects associated with a possible future Grexit are all important factors which could give support to the argument that a fiscal expansion alone is not an optimal policy. Hoe does fiscal austerity affect the Greek real economy in a recession? By presenting an endogenous recession premium as suggested by Mehlum (2014), the Keynesian model showed in section 3.3.2 how there could exist a bad equilibrium if the RP-curve is steep enough. An economy in a recession which is trapped in this equilibrium could be forced into a vicious spiral between higher recession premiums, a larger number of non-performing loans and lower growth if austerity is used as a stabilization policy. Thus, austerity alone and pushed too far - in similar vein to the debt-equilibrium model - could result in a total collapse of the economy. The chapter lastly discussed some other aspects of austerity. On one hand, austerity during a recession could be expansionary if the public interprets the austerity as a signal of future discipline and stability. On the other hand, the social and political costs of austerity could be severe, as it has been in Greece since 2010. Thus, the analysis has shown that there are gains and distortions associated with both policies. Neither fiscal expansions nor austerity in isolation could lead to an effective recovery in Greece. The Greek crisis consists of many interlinked vulnerabilities, hence a proper stabilization policy needs to be characterized by bold and coordinated measures beyond austerity and bailout loans. Yes, Greece needs austerity in order to achieve a better competitive position and restore credibility in its public finances. But the discussions and models of this analysis have suggested that the timing could not have been worse. As discussed in section 3.6, there is a mismatch between policies, and as long the ECB develops expansionary monetary instruments, Greece could have benefited greatly from a debt relief in order to ease the pressure on the debt-part of the crisis. Shifting resources 60 from debt-repayment towards job creation and welfare policies could complement the expansionary monetary policy and create a solid growth foundation in order to develop a stronger competitive position later on. 61 Bibliography [1] Abbas, S. A., Arnold, N., Dacheva, P., De Broeck, M., Forni, L., Guerguil, M., and ———-Versailles, B. (2014) The Other Crisis: Sovereign Distress in the Euro Area. ———–In: Cottarelli, C., Gerson, P., and Senhadji, A. (eds.) Post-crisis Fiscal ——— Policy. The MIT Press, 193-226. [2] Alesina, A. and Tabellini, G. (1990) A Positive Theory of Fiscal Deficits and ———–Government Debt. The Review of Economic Studies, 57 (3), 403-414. [3] Alesina, A. and Drazen, A. (1991) Why are Stabilizations Delayed? The American ———-Economic Review, 81 (5), 1170-1188. [4] Alesina, A., and Ardagna, S. (2010) Large Changes in Fiscal Policy: Taxes versus ———–Spending. In: Brown, J. R. (ed.) Tax Policy and the Economy, 24. Chicago: ———–University of Chicago Press, 35-69. [5] Alpha Bank (2016) Covered Bond Programme Prospectus - Direct Issue [Online]. ———-Available at: http://www.alpha.gr/files/investorrelations/Alpha CB 2015 ———-Update Prospectus.pdf [Retrieved: 01.03.2016]. [6] Arslanap, S. and Tsuda, T. (2012) Tracking Global Demand for Advanced Economy ———-Sovereign Debt. IMF Working Paper no 12/284. [7] Auerbach, A. and Gorodnichenko, Y. (2012) Fiscal Multiplers in Recession and ———-Expansion. In: Alesina, A. and Giavazzi, F. (eds.) Fiscal Policy after the ———-Financial Crisis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 63-98. [8] Barro, R. J. (1979) On the Determination of the Public Debt. Journal of Political ———-Economy, 87 (5), 940-971. [9] Barro, R. J. and Gordon, D. B. (1983) Rules, discretion and reputation in a model ———-of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 101-121. [10] Barro, R. J. (1989) The Ricardian Approach to Budget Deficits. Journal of Economic ———-Perspectives, 3 (2), 37-54. 62 [11] Blanchard, O. and Leigh, D. (2013) Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal Multipliers. ———-IMF Working Paper no 13/1. [12] Calvo, G. A. (1988) Servicing the Public Debt: The Role of Expectations. The ———-American Economic Review, 78 (4), 647-661. [13] Carroll, C.D., Slacalek, J., and Tokuoka, K. (2014a) The Distribution of Wealth ———-and the MPC: implications of new European data. European Central Bank ———-Working Paper Series no 1648, 1-22. [14] Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., and Rebelo , S. (2011) When Is the Government ———-Spending Multiplier Large?. Journal of Political Economy, 119 (1), 78-121. [15] Cole, H. L. and Kehoe, T. J. (2000) Self-Fulfilling Debt Crises. Review of Economic ———-Studies, 67, 91-116. [16] Cæuré, B./The European Central Bank (2013) Outright Monetary Transactions, ———-one year on [Online]. Available at: https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/key/ ———-date/2013/html/sp130902.en.html [Retrieved: 22.02.2016]. [17] De Grauwe, P. (2007) Some Thoughts on the Reforming the Stability and Growth ———-Pact. In: Breuss, F. (ed.) The Stability and Growth Pact: Experiences and ———-Future Aspects. SpringerWienNewYork, 183-187. [18] De Grauwe, P. (2011) Managing a fragile Eurozone [Online]. Available at: ———-http://www.voxeu.org/article/managing-fragile-eurozone ———-[Retrieved: 01.03.2016]. [19] DeLong, J. B. and Summers, L. H. (2012) Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy, ———-Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 233-297. [20] Dornbusch, R. (1997) Fiscal Aspects of Monetary Integration, The American ———-Economic Review, 87 (2), 221-223. [21] Elliott, L., Wearden, G., and Treanor, J. (2016) IMF demands EU ———-debt relief for Greece before new bailout. The Guardian [Online], ———-21 January. Available at: http://www.theguardian.com/business/2016/jan/21/ ———-imf-demands-debt-relief-from-europe-for-greece-before-new-bailout ———-[Retrieved: 21.01.2016]. [22] Esping-Andersen, G. (2002) Why We Need a New Welfare State. USA: Oxford ———-University Press. 63 [23] European Central Bank/ECB (2012) Introductory statement to the press conference ———-(with Q and A) [Online]. Available at: ———-http://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pressconf/2012/html/is120906.en.html ———-[Retrieved: 22.02.2016]. [24] European Central Bank/ECB (2016) Introductory statement to the press ———-conference (with Q and A) [Online]. Available at: ———-https://www.ecb.europa.eu/press/pressconf/2016/html/is160310.en.html ———-[Retrieved 10.03.2016]. [25] European Commission/EC (2015a) Memorandum of Understanding [Online]. ———-Available at: http://ec.europa.eu/economy finance/assistance eu ms/greek ———- loan facility/pdf/01 mou 20150811 en.pdf [Retrieved: 01.04.2016]. [26] European Commission/EC (2015b) Assessment of the Social Impact of ———-the New Stability Support Programme for Greece [Online]. Available at: ———-http://ec.europa.eu/economy finance/assistance eu ms/greek loan facility ———-/pdf/assessment social impact en.pdf [Retrieved: 22.03.2016]. [27] Fels, G., Froehlich, H. P., Blanchard, O., and Miller, M. (1987) Germany and the ———-World Economy: A Round Table Discussion. Economic Policy, 2 (4), 177-206. [28] Galı́, J., López-Salido, D., and Vallés, J. (2007) Understanding the Effects of ———-Government Spending on Consumption. Journal of the European Economic ———-Association, 5 (1), 227-270. [29] Giavazzi, F. and Pagano, M. (1990) Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be ———-Expansionary? Tales of Two Small European Countries. NBER ———-Macroeconomics Annual, 5, 75-122. [30] Hellewig, M., Neumann, M. J. M., Vaubel, R., and Miller, M. (1887) Economic ———-Policy in Germany: Was There a Turnaround? Economic Policy, 2 (5), ———-103-145. [31] Holden, S. (2012) Gjeldskrisen i Europa - bakgrunn og lærdommer (In Norwegian. ———-The European Debt Crisis - the origins and lessons learned) [Online]. ———-Available at: http://folk.uio.no/sholden/publikasjoner/Laardommer fra ———- finanskrisen.pdf [Retrieved: 01.02.2016]. [32] Holden, S. (2015) Økonomisk aktivitet i en åpen økonomi (In Norwegian. Economic ———-activity in an open economy) [Online]. Available at: ———-http://folk.uio.no/sholden/makrobok/open-IS-RR-PK-X.pdf ———-[Retrieved: 20.12.2015]. 64 [33] Ilzetzki, E., Mendoza, E. G., and Végh, C. A. (2013) How big (small?) are fiscal ———-multipliers? Journal of Monetary Economics, 60, 239-254. [34] International Monetary Fund/IMF (2015). Greece: preliminary draft debt ———-sustainability analysis [Online]. IMF country report no. 15/165. Washington ———-D.C.: IMF. Available at: https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2015 ———-/cr15165.pdf [Retrieved: 05.01.2016]. [35] Kentikelenis, A., Karanikolos, M., Reeves, A., Mckee, M., and Stuckler , D. (2014) ———-Greece’s Health Crisis: From Austerity to Denialism. The Lancet, 384 (9918), ———-748-753. [36] Keynes, J. M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. ———-Paperback edition, London: Palgrave Macmillan. [37] Krugman, P. (2013) The Confidence Fairy, The Expectations Imp, and the Rate-Hike ———-Obsession [Online]. Available at: http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/06 ———-/09/the-confidence-fairy-the-expectations-imp-and-the-rate-hike-obsession/ ———-[Retrieved: 01.04.2016]. [38] Kumar, M. S. and Woo, J. (2014) The Relationship between Debt Levels and ———-Growth. In: Cottarelli, C., Gerson, P., and Senhadji, A. (eds.) Post-crisis ———-Fiscal Policy. The MIT Press, 97-125. [39] Kuttner, R. (2013) Debtors’ Prison: the politics of austerity versus possibility. ———-New York: Alfred A. Knopf. [40] Lane, P. R. (2012) The European Sovereign Debt Crisis. Journal of Economic ———-Perspectives, 26 (3), 49-68. [41] Laubach, T. (2009) New Evidence on the Interest Rate Effects of Budget Deficits ———-and Debt. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7 (4), 858-885. [42] Mehlum, H. (2012) Sustainable debt and oil fund [Online]. Available at: ———-http://folk.uio.no/hmehlum/2310h2015/sustdebt.pdf ———-[Retrieved: 20.12.2015]. [43] Mehlum, H. (2014) Stabiliseringspolitikk i krisetider (In Norwegian. Stabilization ———-policy in times of crisis). Samfunnsøkonomen, 7, 16-23. [44] Mehlum, H. (2015) IMF’s manipulering i Hellas (In Norwegian. IMF’s ———-manipulation in Greece) [Online]. Available at: http://www.sv.uio.no/esop/ ———-forskning/aktuelt/i-media/2015/150815mehlum.pdf [Retrieved: 01.04.2016]. 65 [45] Panizza, U., and Presbitero, A. F. (2014) Public debt and economic growth: Is there ———-a causal effect? Journal of Macroeconomics, 41, 21-41. [46] Pappas, T. S., (2013) Why Greece Failed, Journal of Democracy, 24 (2), 31-45. [47] Ramey, V. A. (2011) Can Government Purchases Stimulate the Economy? Journal ———-of Economic Literature, 49 (3), 673-685. [48] Reinhart, C. and Rogoff, K. S. (2010) Growth in a Time of Debt. The American ———-Economic Review, 100 (2), 573-578. [49] Romer, D. (2012) Advanced Macroeconomics. 4th edition, New York: McGraw-Hill. [50] Sapir, A. (2007) Re-orientation of the Stability and Growth Pact. In: Breuss, F. ———-(ed.) The Stability and Growth Pact: Experiences and Future Aspects. ———-SpringerWienNewYork, 87-91. [51] Schäuble, W. (2011) Why austerity is the only cure for the eurozone. ———-Financial Times [Online], 5 September. Available at: ———-http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/97b826e2-d7ab———--a06b-00144feabdc0.html#axzz45VSaxXbA [Retrieved: 02.04.2016]. [52] Sen, A. (2012) What Happened to Europe? [Online]. ———-New Republic. Available at: https://newrepublic.com/article/105657/ ———-sen-europe-democracykeynes-social-justice [Retrieved: 01.03.2016]. [53] Sen, A. (2015) The economic consequences of austerity [Online]. ———-New Statesman. Available at: http://www.newstatesman.com/politics/2015 ———-/06/amartya-sen-economic-consequences-austerity [Retrieved: 01.03.2016]. [54] Shambaugh, J. C (2012) The Euro’s Three Crises. Brookings Papers on Economic ———-Activity, 157-231. [55] Sinn, H-W. (2014) Austerity, Growth and Inflation: Remarks on the Eurozone’s ———-Unresolved Competitiveness Problem. The World Economy, 37 (1), pp 01-13. [56] Stiglitz, J. (2002) Globalization and its discontents, paperback edition, ———-London: Penguin Books Ltd. [57] van den Noord, P. (2007) Fiscal policies in EMU at the crossroads. In: Breuss, F. ———-(ed.) The Stability and Growth Pact: Experiences and Future Aspects. ———-SpringerWienNewYork, 35-59. [58] von Hagen, J., Schuknecht, L., and Wolswijk, G. (2011) Government bond risk ———-premiums in the EU revisited: The Impact of the financial crisis. ———-European Journal of Political Economy, 27, 36-43. 66 [59] Wolf, M. (2014) The shifts and the shocks: what we’ve learned - and have still to ———-learn - from the financial crisis. Paperback edition, ———-London: Penguin Books Ltd. 67 Appendices 68 Appendix A The Model Consider the IS-RR-PC framework for an open economy as found in Holden (2015)1 : Y = C + I + G + NX (A.1) C = z c + c1 (Y − T ) − c2 (i − π e ) (A.2) I = z I + b1 Y − b2 (i − π e ) (A.3) T = z T + tY (A.4) N X = z N X − a1 Y + a2 E − a3 P (A.5) In (A.1) aggregate output equals aggregate demand in equilibrium and is the accounting identity that corresponds to the calculation of a country’s GDP where Y is GDP, C is private consumption, I is private investments, G is government expenses, and N X is the net exports. (A.2) is the consumption function that shows total consumption for a given level of income Y . The parameter c1 , the marginal propensity to consume, is restricted to satisfy 0 < c1 < 1. The parameter c2 , the marginal effect after a change in the real interest rate, is restricted to satisfy c2 > 0. This equation captures that private consumption is increasing in disposable income. In addition, the real interest rate is given by r = i − π e i.e. the nominal interest rate minus expected inflation. Let z C capture other effects that affect consumption such as total household wealth, the income distribution, and expectations about future disposable income. (A.3) is the investment function where 0 < b1 < 1 and b2 > 0. The marginal propensity to invest parameter b1 shows by how much private investments increase with one unit increase in GDP. b2 captures by how much changes in the real rate of interest affect private 1 Investment-Saving - Interest Rate Rule - Phillips Curve-model. 69 investments. z I captures other factors that might affect investment such as technology, access to finance, and expectations about the future. (A.4) shows net taxation, T , as an increasing function of Y where the tax rate, t, satisfies 0 < t < 1. T increases in Y as increased GDP implies lower unemployment, a larger tax base, and fewer welfare expenses. (A.5) shows net exports, N X, as a decreasing function of Y and the price level, P . Increased Y increases imports while increased P reduced exports. N X is increasing in the exchange rate, E, as a higher exchange rate implies that domestic goods become relatively cheaper for foreigners. The parameters satisfy 0 < a1 < 1 and a2 , a3 > 0. The real equilibrium GDP can be written on reduced form by inserting equations (A.2) - (A.5) into equation (A.1): Y = z C +c1 ((1−t)Y −z T )−c2 (i−π e )+z I +b1 Y −b2 (i−π e )+G+z N X −a1 Y +a2 E −a3 P and solve for Y Y = 1 (z C − c1 z T − c2 (i − π e ) + z I − (i − π e ) + G + z N X + a2 E − a3 P ) 1 − c1 (1 − t) − b1 + a1 (A.6) Next, consider the three equations: i = iF + ∆E e E Y −Yn + zn Yn Y −Yn e P =1+π +β + zn n Y π = πe + β (A.7) (A.8) (A.9) (A.7) represents the uncovered interest rate parity approximation which shows the nominal interest rate, i, as a function of the interest rate in the country of which the cure rency is pegged, iF , plus the expected rate of devaluation, ∆E . In the case of a currency E ∆E e union, E = 0 so that i = iF holds in all member countries within the union. (A.8) is the Phillips-curve where inflation, π, is increasing in expected inflation, the output gap and exogenous supply shocks, z π . The higher expected inflation and output 70 gap the higher are the wages and hence the firm’s costs. This leads to higher mark-ups Yn and higher prices. The parameter β is defined as β = b AL where the parameter b satisfies b > 0 and A is the productivity of the labour force, L. β shows by how much inflation increases with one unit increase in the output gap. −1 . By setting P−1 = 1 (A.9) shows the price level. Define price growth as π = P −P P−1 one simply get P = (1+π). Hence, (A.9) is derived by inserting (A.8) into this expression. In order to derive the IS-curve, insert P from (A.9) into (A.6) and find Y = 1 (z C − c1 z T − c2 (i − π e ) + z I − b2 (i − π e )+ 1 − c1 (1 − t) − b1 + a1 Y −Yn N e G + z X + a2 E − a3 (1 + π + β + z n )) n Y which further gives Y = 1 (z C − c1 z T − c2 (i − π e ) + z I − b2 (i − π e )+ β 1 − c1 (1 − t) − b1 + a1 + a3 Y n G+z NX e (A.10) π + a2 E − a3 (1 + π − β + z ) which is the IS-curve where aggregate demand determines the value of aggregate supply. Slope: −(c2 + b2 ) ∂Y = <0 ∂i 1 − c1 (1 − t) − b1 + a1 + a3 Yβn which implies that there is a negative relationship between GDP and the interest rate. 71