Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Outline of Presentation 1. Definition of monopoly. 2. Barriers to entry. 3. Theory of a single price monopoly. 4. Comparative statics: The effect of increasing costs. 5. Monopoly and Welfare. 6. Monopoly and Quality. 7. Price discrimination. 8. Why do natural monopolies exist? Chapter 14: Monopoly Teemu Nyholm S ystems S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 1 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 1 Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology 1. Definition of monopoly Dictionary: Exclusive control by one group of the means of producing or selling a commodity or service. Session 2 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 2 2. Barriers to Entry Definition: Barriers to entry protect a firm from the competition. The existence of monopolies is always based on some kind of barriers to entry. Legal barriers to entry: law, license, patent. => Legal Monopoly. Economics: The amount of output a monopoly is selling responds continuously as a function of the price it charges. • In a competitive markets a firm is a price-taker. Natural barriers to entry: unique source of supply, economies of scale, economies of scope. => Natural Monopoly. • In monopolistic market a firm is a price-maker. S ystems S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 3 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 3 Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology First order condition can be written using elasticity of demand 3. Theory of single price monopoly 1 dc( y ) = 1 + p( y ) dy ε ( y) Monopoly’s maximization problem: Monopoly is choosing optimal output in order to maximize profit. max p ( y ) y − c( y ) y I Monopolist is producing such amount, that marginal cost equals to marginal revenue. II Monopolist is able to sell at a price level, that exceeds its marginal costs. Thus monopoly price exceeds competitive-market-price and the amount produced is less. III The difference between monopoly price and competitive-market-price depends on the commodity’s elasticity of demand. First and second order conditions: p ( y ) + p ' ( y ) y − c' ( y ) = 0 2 p ' ( y ) + p' ' ( y ) y − c ' ' ( y ) ≤ 0 S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 4 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 4 S ystems Session 5 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 5 Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 6 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 6 Linear example: 4. Comparative statics p The effect of a cost change on price: MC p* dp dp dy 1 = = >0 dc dy dc 2 + yp' ' ( y ) p' ( y ) D Part of a monopoly’s cost increase is passed a long in the form of increased prices. MR y* y S ystems S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 7 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 7 Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology 5. Monopoly and Welfare Social objective function: 6. Monopoly and Quality Let q be product quality and let’s suppose that costs and utility depend on quality. Social objective function: W ( x ) = max u( x ) − c( x ) x Let x* be the level of monopoly output. Then W ( x , q ) = u ( x , q ) − c ( x, q ) Let (x*, q*) be monopolist’s profit maximizing points. Then W ' ( x*) = − u ' ' ( x*) x* > 0 => x* does not maximize welfare. IV ∂W ( x*, q*) ∂p ( x*, q*) * 0 x > =− ∂x ∂x ∂W ( x*, q*) ∂ u ( x*, q*) ∂p ( x*, q*) * = − x ∂q ∂q ∂q x * Monopolist produces too little output relative to the social optimum. S ystems S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology V Session 8 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 8 Session 9 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 9 Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology If the derivative of average willingness to pay exceeds the derivative of marginal willingness to pay for the quality change, so monopolist’s quality choice will not be optimal from the social viewpoint. Session 10 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 10 7. Price discrimination Definition: Price discrimination is the practice of charging some customers a higher price than others for an identical good or of charging an individual customer higher price on a small purchase than on a large one. S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology S ystems Session 11 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 11 Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 12 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 12 7.1 First-degree price discrimination VI In the perfect price discrimination the price charged for each unit is equal to the maximum willingness to pay for that unit. If a firm is perfectly price discriminating, it will choose to produce a Pareto efficient level of output, that is the same level as a firm in the competitive markets would produce. A perfectly price discriminating firm gains all the surplus from the trade. Monopolist’s maximizing problem, when perfectly price discriminating: max r − cx such that u ( x) ≥ r. r,x Let (r*,x*) be the optimal price and amount combination. Then from f.o.c: u ' ( x*) = c r* = u ( x*) S ystems S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 13 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 13 7.2 Second-degree price discrimination Second-degree price discrimination occurs when prices differ only depending on the number of commodities bought. It is known as nonlinear pricing. Let’s suppose two consumers with utility functions u1(x) and u2(x) for product x such that u1 ( x ) > u2 ( x) and u '1 ( x ) > u '2 ( x) S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Self-selection constraints: Consumers choose ( x1, r1=p(x1) x1 ) and ( x2, r2=p(x2) x2 ). Because they want to consume amount xi and are willing to pay r1 u1 ( x1 ) − r1 ≥ 0 and u2 ( x2 ) − r2 ≥ 0 And because they prefer their own consumption choice u1 ( x1 ) − r1 ≥ u1 ( x2 ) − r2 u2 ( x2 ) − r2 ≥ u2 ( x1 ) − r1. Now monopolist’s optimization problem takes the form S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 15 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 15 Session 14 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 14 max r1 + r2 − cx1-cx2 such, that self - selection constraint s hold. Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 16 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 16 From the first order conditions VII u1 ' ( x1 ) = c + u2 ' ( x1 ) − u1 ' ( x1 ) > c u2 ' ( x2 ) = c If a firm is using nonlinear pricing, then the consumer with the highest demand pays marginal cost and others pays more. Thus only the consumer with the highest demand consumes socially efficient amount. 7.3 Third degree price discrimination Third-degree price discrimination occurs when consumers are charged different prices, but each consumer faces a constant price for all units of output purchased. Let’s suppose that a firm is price discriminating among two groups with different demand curves p1(x1) and p2(x2). Now the profit maximization problem takes the form max p1 ( x1 ) x1 + p2 ( x2 ) x2 − cx1 − cx2 S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology S ystems Session 17 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 17 Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 18 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 18 The first order conditions: 1 p1 ( x1 ) + p1 ' ( x1 ) x1 = p1 ( x1 ) 1 − =c ε1 ( x1 ) 1 p 2 ( x2 ) + p2 ' ( x2 ) x2 = p2 ( x2 ) 1 − =c ε 2 ( x2 ) which implies that p1( x1 ) > p2 ( x2 ) ⇔ ε1 < ε 2 VIII If a firm is price discriminating among consumers, then the consumers with the more elastic demand are charged a lower price. S ystems 8. Why do natural monopolies exist? A natural monopoly exists when a single firm can supply an entire market with lower costs than can any number of competitive firms. Definition: Strict economies of scale in the production of outputs in N are present if for any initial input -output vector (x1,…,xm;y1,…,yn) and for any w > 1, there is a feasible input output-vector (wx1,…,wxm;v1y1,…vnyn) where all vi>w. S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 19 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 19 Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 20 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 20 In the case of a single product firm, the existence of scale economies is sufficient but not necessary condition for natural monopoly. In the case of a multi-product firm, economies of scale are neither sufficient condition for natural monopoly. Definition: Strict and global subadditivity of costs. C(y) is strictly and globally subadditive in the set of N=1…n commodities, if for any m output vectors y1, … , ym we have C(y1 +…+ ym) < C(y1)+…+C(ym). IX Strict and global subadditivity is necessary and sufficient condition for natural monopoly of any output combination in the industry producing commodities in N. S ystems Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology S ystems Session 21 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 21 Analysis Laboratory Helsinki University of Technology Session 22 - Student presentation Seminar on Microeconomics - Fall 1998 / 22