* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Price StabiUty, Market Controi and Imports in the Steel Industry
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Price StabiUty, Market Controi and Imports in the Steel Industry ROBERT R. MILLER Some observers have a+tribufed price stability in the steel industry to the vertically integrated structure of the steel industry. This article suggests that the industry's pricing strategy is based not only on the industry structure, but also on its somewhat unique market characteristics. Imports have been limited to relatively few market segments, and there appears to be little likelihood that other market areas will be materially affected by imports in the foreseeable future. Journal of Marketing. Vol. 32 (April. 1968). pp. lG-20. MERICAN steel producers in the last decade have been faced with increasing amounts of low-priced imports of basic steel products. This intensified international competition stems from the capacity expansion and return to world trade of Japan and Western European nations following World War II reconstruction. Prior to 1958, steel imports at no time supplied more than 2% or 3% of total domestic consumption. Today, in contrast, imported steel products account for over 11% of the total quantity used, and in some items now supply the predominant amount sold in the open market. In some coastal areas, U. S. steel firms have nearly been displaced in supplying such common products as nails and reinforcing bars. If this competition had come from a domestic firm, or group of firms, steel industry leaders undoubtedly would have reacted by lowering prices for the affected products to match or even maintained or even raised above domestic prices existing before undercut the competitive level. In the present import situation, however, such price cuts have not been forthcoming, except in a few special cases. Instead, steel product prices generally have been substantial imports were a factor. A Industry Structure and Steel Pricing One reason for the resistance of the steel industry to meeting lower import prices has been suggested by Walter Adams and Joel Dirlam.^ In their view, the refusal to lower prices was based on the industry's history of price leadership and its vertically integrated structure. According to the Adams-Dirlam argument, the decision to maintain price levels maximized industry profits, assuming: (a) effective price leadership, (b) production by the fully integrated firms at each fabrication stage, (c) the belief by price makers that inelastic industry demand existed for all products, and (d) dependence for materials by intermediate fabricators on the integrated firms. Under these conditions, lowering a price for an intermediate product, such as wire rod or wire, would cause deterioration of prices at successive levels. Resulting profitability losses, assuming small amounts of imports, would exceed the loss incurred by refusing to meet the lower price level. Similarly, maintenance of pre-import prices for final products, such as nails and barbed wire, was intended to reduce the possibility Walter Adams and Joel Dirlam, "Steel Imports and Vertical Oligopoly Power," American Economic Review, Vol. 54 (September, 1964), pp. 626-655. 16 Price Stability, Market Control, ami Imports in the Steel Industry of severe and widespread price cutting, which again would lower industry profits. Exceptions to the price maintenance decision occurred only when small domestic competitors, producing relatively few items, were forced by imports to lower prices or when other materials, such as aluminum, were introduced as substitutes for steel. In these cases, downward price adjustments were made reluctantly by the major integrated firms. In other cases, industry leaders vociferously maintained their desire to protect smaller "independent" producers from margin-reducing price cuts and on several occasions have surrendered large segments of individual product markets rather than meeting- a lower import price. Other possible reasons for the industry's reluctance to cut prices have been suggested.-' However, all explanations so far put forth, including the Adams-Dirlam argument, depend on one assumption: for the price maintenance policy to be successful, steel industry executives must have had a strong a priori notion that market losses to imports would be relatively limited. Clearly, if foreign shipments were anticipated ultimately to absorb a large proportion of the total market at all levels in the vertical structure, a policy which ignored this eventuality would have been untenable. The observed decisions of industry price setters, therefore, implied the belief that the long-run price elasticity of demand for steel imports was low, even with relatively higher domestic mill prices. In other words, the steel industry's pricing actions were premised on the assumption that non-price factors would encourage American steel users to retain domestic sources of supply regardless of price differentials often substantially favoring foreign suppliers. Certainly the extent of market gain by importers which took place in a limited number of products could not have been thought likely in all product lines. Importance of Market Structure The purpose of this article is to demonstrate that this expectation was not unwarranted. By considering the market and distribution structure of the steel industry, it can be shown that many steelusing industries have been essentially closed to substantial import competition. Moreover, barring the possibility of a widening of price differentials between domestic and imported steel in the future, which appears unlikely, the percentage of foreignproduced steel to total domestic consumption should stabilize at approximately the current level. In the long-run, of course, the changing structure of comparative advantage in the world could result in 2 See especially, G. A. Hone and D. S. Schoenbrod, "Steel Imports and Vertical Oligopoly Power: Comment," American Economic Review, Vol. 56 (March, 1966), pp. 156-159. 17 wider price differences. In the foreseeable future, however, the continuing installation of modern plants in the United States should at least preserve the nation's present competitive position. Price discrimination, or "dumping," by foreign producers also could lead to lower import prices. For the purposes of this article, extensive dumping is assumed to be effectively prevented by existing anti-dumping legislation.^ Steel products in this country are primarily distributed in two ways: (1) customers can mill-order; that is, place orders with the steel producer and receive shipments directly without any market intermediary; (2) for smaller quantities, usually less-than-carload lots, orders are directed to a wholesaler or jobber. Of the two means of distribution, mill-ordering is by far the more important, accounting for about four-fifths of the total quantity of steel products shipped. Both methods of distribution, however, reach a wide variety of customers exhibiting a range of purchasing characteristics. These buying characteristics have in large measure determined the susceptibility of various market segments to import competition. Large Steel-using Industries Automobile manufacturers provide an example of one type of direct purchaser. These companies in a typical year purchase approximately one-fifth of the total amount of steel produced. Sales normally are made on the basis of negotiated prices; list prices serve only as a starting point in negotiation. The automotive firms estimate annual requirements for various steel products and enter into purchase contracts to cover these needs. The steel producer generally agrees to deliver steel in relatively small lots throughout the year to conform closely with the customer's anticipated production For recent relative price movements in steel products, see Irving B. Kravis, Robert E. Lipsey, and Philip J. Bourque, Measuring hiier)iational Price Competitiveness: A Preliminary Report, Occasional Paper 94, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1965. • ABOUT THE AUTHOR. Professor Miller teaches courses in International business and managerial economics at the University of Iowa. During the period [954-1961. he was employed by the General Electric Company in various marketing positions. More recently, he has been affiliated with the Stanford Research Institute as an economic consultant. Prior to going to Iowa, he taught briefly at San Jose State College in California. Professor Miller undertook his early academic training at the University of Michigan, where he received degrees in industrial-mechanical engineering in 1952 and business in 1954. He Is a recent recipient of a Ph.D. degree from Stanford University. 18 schedule. Comparatively little steel, under normal operating conditions, is inventoried by the automotive firm. Anticipated delivery delays, as might be caused by a steel strike, are countered by shortterm inventory accumulation. It should be emphasized also that these observations refer to large tonnage products, which comprise over 80% of total steel purchases by the industry. Because steel is not stocked, automobile manufacturers are heavily dependent on the steel producer's ability to consistently deliver according to the prearranged schedule. Any unforeseen interruption in shipments can lead to an extremely costly production stoppage in the automotive plant. Deviations from the planned delivery schedule, however, become necessary from time to time aa automobile sales forecasts are revised. Such adjustments normally can be accomplished expeditiously, because steel mills supplying the automotive industry usually are located in close proximity to customer plants, thereby minimizing the amount of steel in transit at any given time. Similarly, customer production difficulties that are caused periodically by steel quality variations can be quickly remedied as they arise. These market characteristics are approximated in such other large steel-using industries as major appliances and containers. In each, prices are negotiated, and the purchaser bargains from a position of considerable market power. Both the final delivered price and services to be provided by the steel producer are negotiable, and both can be varied with prevailing economic conditions and, perhaps, to meet foreign competition. Tightly maintained delivery schedules and consistently high product quality are of major importance. As an estimate, markets with these approximate characteristics absorb 40% of the total amount of steel consumed in the United States. Movements in list prices in these markets, as reflected in wholesale price indices, are not necessarily meaningful as an indication of actual market prices. In periods of excess capacity in the steel industry, large purchasers can exert powerful pressure on steel producers for additional services and rebates, neither of which is reflected in publishing price schedules or by other methods of estimating delivered price.* Moreover, periods of slack demand in the mass steelbuying industries, because of the relative importance of such industries in total steel demand, tend to be correlated with recessions in the steel industry itself. Comparatively high fixed costs characterize many purchasing firms and provide an especially strong motivation to reduce variable expenses, including outlays for materials, when plants are underutilized. On this point, see also Lawrence B. Krause, "Import Discipline: The Case of the United States Steel Industry," Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. XI (November, 1962), pp. 33-47. Journal of Marketing, April, 1968 Large buyers, therefore, have both the incentive and the bargaining strength to force price adjustments during recessions or, possibly, in response to import competition. Even if a moderate difference in actual prices favoring imports were to exist, mass purchasers, as exemplified by auto and appliance manufacturers, would be reluctant to transfer any significant portion of their purchases overseas. Day-to-day continuity of supply is of such paramount importance that price differences typically existing between imports and domestic steel producers simply would not compensate purchasing firms for the additional risks inherent in foreign supply. This factor could be reinforced by the opinion of many manufacturing executives in this country that the availability of low-priced foreign steel supplies is. at best, a cyclical phenomenon and, at worst, a manifestation of efforts by foreign cartels to injure domestic steel firms. This is not to say that very large users of steel would not purchase some imported steel from time to time, especially as a bargaining device in price negotiations with normal steel sources or when domestic supplies are constrained. But for the bulk of their requirements, imports would not have served as an adequate substitute and, as a matter of historical record, have not been utilized to a significant extent. For example, imports of cold rolled sheet, an important item in such industries, have grown in recent years but still account for less than 7% of total consumption.5 Other markets in which steel is typically millordered are more difficult to categorize. Electrical and industrial machinery manufacturing firms exhibit purchasing characteristics which are very similar to the mass production industries described above. For these firms, which account for about 10%-20% of total steel shipments, imports have been purchased infrequently. For example, the industrial machinery sector is one of the larger users of hot rolled steel bars. In 1966, less than 6% of total consumption of this product was supplied by imports.« Construction Industry The construction industry, however, presents a more complex market situation. This industry accounted for 13.2% of steel industry shipments in 1966.^ For sizable construction projects, such as large fabricated steel buildings or long bridges, bidding is limited to a few large contracting firms. Among these firms are the fabrication divisions of the steel-producing companies themselves. When the job is awarded to an independent contractor, steel normally is purchased on a sealed-bid basis by specAmerican Iron and Steel Institute, Annual Statistical Report, 1966 Edition, New York, 1967. Same reference as footnote 5. Same reference as footnote 5, p. 33. Price Stability, Market Control, and Imports in the Steel iflcation. As a consequence, importers can compete more effectively and have been somewhat more successful, especially in coastal cities. Again, however, domestic steel sources offer the large contractor more flexibility on delivery schedules, which is not an unimportant consideration on jobs of comparatively long duration. On smaller projects, more contractors can bid and pricing becomes very competitive. When the steel order on such projects is still sufficiently large to justify mill-ordering, requiring less-thancarload quantities of steel, the contractor depends for supply on the steel service center—to be discussed below. The size of the construction project, however, is not the only determinant of possible import competitiveness; t3i)e of product also is important. For example, reinforcing bars, called re-bars, are another product used extensively in construction work. Rebars are produced not only by the large integrated firms but also, unlike heavy structural members, by a variety of smaller companies throughout the United States. Virtually all re-bar is purchased directly from the mill. The product is technologically simple, and, because the grades and sizes are few, comparatively easy to stock. As a result of these characteristics, re-bar prices are highly competitive. Domestic steel producers have no special advantage, such as they have in the mass production industries, since re-bars tj^ically are purchased by smaller contractors in a complete lot to satisfy a particular job requirement. Under these circumstances, users have frequently turned to lower-priced import sources, with the result that in 1966 imports accounted for 17% of total shipments of re-bars. Other Distribution Sales through various distributors and jobbers provide the outlet for steel not ordered directly from the mill. The most important of these middlemen is the steel service center, which for the most part specializes in warehousing a wide range of steel products and selling locally in small lot orders. Many service centers are owned by integrated producing firms, although not all major companies have chosen to function at the wholesale distribution level.^ In general, even the independent service centers rely for steel supplies on the large integrated firms, including in many cases steel producers operating competitive distributorships. Very little imported steel has been distributed through steel service centers, despite the apparent long-term existence of substantial price differentials favoring imports. Only when domestic sources are closed, as during strike periods, have imports been purchased by service centers. As domestic supplies 8 For example, U. S. Steel, Jones and Laughlin, and Inland all operate ^captive" service centers; Bethlehem Steel, however, does not. Industry 19 have been renewed after the strike, imports once again have been displaced. The reason for this behavior is, of course, obvious for "captive" centers. For the independent, however, the explanation, while necessarily somewhat conjectural, probably has been related to two factors. First, the service center, must rely on domestic steel sources during periods of heavy demand overseas, and it must maintain good relations with the major flrms to assure itself of a continuous flow of materials. Furthermore, the management of a small independent center cannot risk offending its primary steel vendors, since its business livelihood depends on margins established and maintained by the majors. Price cutting by an independent would be quickly matched by competing "captive" centers. In short, steel service centers are highly vulnerable to "disciplinary" action and will not expose themselves to the possibility of such action without very strong motivation. As yet, the necessary stimulus does not seem to have been provided. The second, probably less important, reason for service centers refusing to handle imports is concerned with the various federal, state, and local "Buy-American" laws. In some states these laws absolutely prohibit the use of foreign materials in government-financed construction and manufacturing projects. Where only the federal law applies, domestic materials must be utilized unless outside sources are significantly less costly. Because of these laws, importing service centers would be forced to maintain separate inventories of imported and domestic steel. In the absence of any important price competition in their product lines from other service centers, there is little reason to confront the problem, and, again, few have done so. Specific steel product lines, however, are also distributed by a variety of non-specialist wholesalers. For example, small pipe sizes are carried by plumbing supply houses and electrical distributors; baling wire by agricultural equipment dealers; nails, wire, and staples by hardware and building supply houses. In each of these cases, the particular steel products carried represent an insignificant part of the distributor's total product offering. Moreover, in wholesale situations of this type, price competition is severe and distributors are acutely conscious of price differentials. Where these circumstances have prevailed, imports of steel products have generally become very important. In some product lines, such imports now account for half of domestic consumption. As a percentage of total shipments, for example, imports absorbed the following proportions in 1966: nails and staples 46.5%, barbed wire 31.5%, woven wire fence 29.5%. In some regions, particularly coastal areas, these percentages were even higher.^ Same reference as footnote 5. 20 Journal of Marketing, April, 1968 Conclusion In summary, the market structure of the steel industry has limited areas susceptible to import penetration. Large segments of the American steel market essentially have been closed to importers for various reasons, except in periods of domestic shortage. Import expansion has occurred largely in the few market areas where formal distribution facilities were available or where such means were not required, as in some construction materials at port cities. Because of its effective control over major distribution channels, the domestic steel industry has been able to pursue a comparatively independent price policy for most products. In some cases, negotiations with purchasers might have resulted in somewhat lower actual prices, but available studies have not shown these reductions to be significant. Importers could have surmounted this distribution barrier, in part, by forming service centers of their own; in fact, they have not done so. As a consequence, the price response of the U.S. industry to imports in predictably confined product markets has been straightforward: where the industry price could be maintained, imports have been permitted to expand virtually unopposed; where market competition among smaller, less integrated producers has resulted in lower prices, the larger firms have met the market price, while at the same time holding constant prices at lower levels of fabrication. Interestingly, this latter behavior has led independent producers to accuse their integrated suppliers of "dumping" steel in final product markets, while complaining about foreign dumping in controlled lines produced only by the large firms.i*' On this point, see: U. S. House of Representatives, Select Committee on Small Business, The Impact Upon Small Business of Dual Distribution and Related Vertical Integration, Hearings, Subcommittee #4, 88th Congress, 1st Session, Washington, D.C. (August-September, 1963), pp. 917-927. -MARKETING MEMO A Whole New Market? . . . . . . As our business system races to fill these luxury wants, I believe our market is becoming transformed again—into a market of fulfillment wants. These have little to do with the individual's acquisitiveness, but rather with his psychological and social needs—his yearning for self-fulfillment, for development of his talents, for an attractive environment, and for the removal of inequalities and suffering in the backwaters of our civilization that have been passed over by change. The customer in our market today is not an unthinking consuming apparatus. He is concemed with education, with health, with culture, with environmental conditions. He wants cleaner, safer cities more than he wants a larger house or apartment. He wants efficient transportation systems more than he wants a bigger, more powerful car. Can business, with its great experience and ability to get things done, respond to the new desires and hopes of our fellow men in an environment rapidly changing through its own creative technology? Does business have a future in this market? —J. Wilson Newman, "Does Business Have a Future," MSU Business Topics, Vol. 15 (Autumn, 1967), pp. 17, 18.