Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Fiscal Drag – An Automatic Stabiliser? Herwig IMMERVOLL* * Microsimulation Unit, Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge Sidgwick Avenue, Cambridge CB3 9DE, UK. Tel. +44 1223 335269 e-mail: [email protected] Abstract Inflation can alter the structure of tax systems and lead to higher real tax burdens. The ‘automatic stabiliser’ argument assumes that increasing tax burdens reduce consumption and thereby aggregate demand, acting as an automatic stabiliser which helps to ‘cool down’ the economy in times of inflation. This argument, however, only looks at the demand side, ignoring any effects that higher tax burdens may have on the cost of production. If employees bear less then the full burden of higher taxes then real labour costs will go up as well, generating a cost-push upwards pressure on prices and opening up the possibility of a wage-price spiral. This paper build on analyses of the differential effect of marginal and average tax rates on the wage setting process in an imperfect labour market. A preliminary version of EUROMOD, a European benefit-tax model is used to derive distributions of inflation induced changes of effective tax rates for representative samples of the population of four European countries. The approach takes into account both the complexities of tax-benefit systems and the heterogeneity of taxpayers and benefit recipients in the population. For illustrative purposes, the simulated changes in the marginal and average tax burdens of employees are then combined with estimates from the literature on the sensitivity of wages with respect to these variables. The results suggest that inflation combined with an unindexed tax-benefit system can produce a moderate upward pressure on wages. However, it is argued that the wage equations on which these results are based are less than satisfactory since they ignore that tax rates of different individuals are generally affected to different extents. JEL Classification: E31; H24; H39; D31; C81 Keywords: Automatic Stabiliser; Inflation; Income Tax; Wage Setting; European Union; Microsimulation. Fiscal Drag – An Automatic Stabiliser? Herwig Immervoll1 Draft version (19.9.2000). Please do not quote without the author’s permission. Comments welcome! 1. Introduction Inflation can alter the structure of tax systems and, thus, the incidence and overall levels of taxes collected. There are several channels through which such distortions can operate. The most evident and most thoroughly researched source is the influence of inflation on the tax schedule commonly known as ‘bracket creep’ (Immervoll, 2000; OECD, 1986; Aaron, 1976). In the absence of offsetting adjustments, a progressive tax schedule will cause real tax burdens to increase as nominal incomes rise (‘fiscal drag’). The dependence of the tax system on an a priory unknown variable is undesirable in many respects. For example, inflation induced changes by-pass the democratic process, which is otherwise obligatory for enacting tax changes. On a more pragmatic level, they may undermine the social or economic purposes of the tax system. There have, therefore, been numerous proposals to adjust the tax system for inflation in order to prevent inflation induced distortions and many countries have, in fact, adopted one or another form of automatic inflation adjustment (Immervoll, 2000; Messere, 1998; Tanzi, 1980; OECD, 1976). Apart from several assumed practical difficulties in neutralising the effects of inflation, there has been one economic argument, which has been used to justify inflation induced increases in real tax revenues. Increasing real tax burdens are assumed to reduce consumption and thereby aggregate demand, acting as an automatic stabiliser which helps to ‘cool down’ the economy in times of inflation.2 This argument, however, only looks at the demand side, ignoring any effects that higher tax burdens may have on the cost of production. If employees bear less then the full burden of higher taxes then real labour costs will go up as well, generating a cost-push upwards pressure on prices and opening up the possibility of a wage-price spiral (Jackson et al., 1972; Dernburg, 1974; Malcomson and Sartor, 1987). 1 Microsimulation Unit, Department of Applied Economics at the University of Cambridge. This paper was written as part of the EUROMOD project, financed by Targeted Socio-Economic Research programme of the European Commission (CT97-3060). I am grateful for access to microdata from the Finnish Income Distribution Survey (IDS) 1996 made available from Statistics Finland; the Living in Ireland Survey, 1994 (Wave 1) made available by the Economic and Social Research Institute (ESRI), Dublin; the Socio-Economic Panel Survey (SEP) made available by Statistics Netherlands through the mediation of the Netherlands Organisation for Scientific Research Scientific Statistical Agency; and the UK Family Expenditure Survey (FES), which have been made available by the Office for National Statistics (ONS) through the Data Archive. Material from the FES is Crown Copyright and is used by permission. Neither the ONS nor the Data Archive bear any responsibility for the analysis or interpretation of the data reported here. An equivalent disclaimer applies to the other data sources and their respective providers. I am grateful for helpful comments received from Cathal O’Donoghue, Frank Wilkinson, Klaas de Vos and participants of the 56th Congress of the International Institute of Public Finance, held on August 28-31, 2000, in Seville, Spain. The views expressed in this paper as well as any errors are the author’s responsibility. 2 see, for instance, the model presented in Zilberfarb (1981). Nowotny (1980) reviews the macroeconomic issues. 2 While, during most of the 1990s, inflation has not been a major problem in the industrialised countries, it has been argued that recent developments in Europe and, especially, EMU, are likely to lead to increasing inter-country variability of inflation. As long as there remain important structural differences between different EMU countries, one would expect a unified monetary policy to lead to differing price developments across countries. Indeed, the process of ‘convergence’ can itself contribute to such differences, at least temporarily (European Commission, 1999). For EMU countries, the loss of control over monetary policy means that there is less scope for national policy makers to control inflation. Small countries, such as Ireland, may be particularly affected since their economic situation will frequently receive less attention in the determination of monetary policy than that of larger ones. Given this scenario, it seems important to discuss the stabilising properties of the fiscal system. The present paper examines possible effects of inflation induced tax and benefit distortions on the wage level. It builds on a recent literature explaining the consequences of changes in the level and progressivity of (effective) tax rates for the wage-setting process. In particular, I draw on results showing that changes in marginal and average tax rates influence wages in opposite directions. Using a European tax-benefit microsimulation model, I decompose the effects of bracket creep into changes in effective marginal and average tax rates. The contribution of the paper is threefold. Firstly, it aims to demonstrate how an integrated European tax-benefit model can be used to compute inter- and intra country distributions of effective average and marginal effective tax rates in one consistent conceptual framework. Similar distributions are computed for a ‘before’ and ‘after’ inflation scenario in order to determine the effects of inflation on average and marginal tax rates in a nominally defined tax system. Lastly, the paper discusses how the resulting changes in marginal and average tax rates can be used to quantify likely cost-push effects of bracket creep. The approach improves on previous studies in that it is able to capture the full range of effects caused by tax changes in different parts of the population. I proceed as follows. Section 2 reviews the channels through which taxes can influence the price level and thus provides the theoretical framework for the following analysis. Section 3 describes the microsimulation approach used in the empirical part of the paper. Both the model and the data are discussed here. The results are presented in section 4. The next section discusses how they can be used to estimate likely impacts on wages. Some caveats are highlighted. Section 6 concludes. 2. Theory The extent to which tax increases (whether discretionary or caused by inflation) have a damping effect on price increases will depend on numerous factors. The most obvious is the elasticity of demand with respect to disposable income.3 But even if demand is responsive to tax changes, the efficacy of tax increases will be limited in cases where inflation is not primarily caused by excess domestic demand. In situations where inflation has been 'imported' or where price increases are a consequence of supply disturbances, reducing domestic demand will not be the optimum counter measure. Rather than inducing price adjustments, tax increases in such a situation are likely to raise the level of unemployed resources in the economy (Dernburg, 1974). Another reason why tax increases may not have the desired stabilising effects is that while higher taxes tend to reduce 3 If there is a certain extent of 'fiscal illusion', i.e., individuals do not (immediately) realise increased tax burdens, then demand will not be as responsive to tax increases as the elasticity of demand would suggest. 3 household demand, aggregate demand is the relevant policy variable. As is well known, tax financed public expenditure actually increases aggregate demand so long as the marginal propensity to consume is less than unity. As a result, higher taxes only translate into lower aggregate demand if lower private consumption is not overcompensated by increased public expenditure made possible by additional tax revenues. To prevent expansionary multiplier effects, intentional tax increases aimed at reducing inflation have sometimes been accompanied by measures to ensure that additional revenues cannot be used to increase public spending.4 For automatic tax increases caused by inflation, however, such attempts have not become known. It is tempting to interpret the lack of such measures as suggesting that stability considerations are not the primary reason for allowing inflation to increase the tax burden. So far, the discussion has been limited to the demand side. On the supply side, it will be critical how wages respond to higher tax burdens. In the absence of 'fiscal illusion' wage earners will want to compensate higher taxes by demanding higher gross wages from their employers. There is, thus, a possibility that tax increases lead to higher production costs and that inflation induced tax increases in the past “may well have contributed to higher inflation rates.”5 Consider an individual subject to an average tax rate τa and a marginal tax rate τm. To keep real after tax earnings unaffected by inflation (π) induced 'bracket creep', the nominal gross wage w would have to increase by ∆w: ∆w 1− τa = π⋅ w 1− τm , (1) (1-τa)/(1-τm) being the inverse of the Musgrave measure of progressivity (Musgrave and Musgrave, 1976). Thus, the required wage increase does not depend on the magnitudes of τa and τm but on the difference between them. The more progressive the tax schedule, the larger the wage increase necessary to compensate for higher real taxes burdens. To the extent that wage increases exceed inflation (even if they fall short of keeping the employees' real after-tax income unchanged), they will, other things being equal, lead to higher real labour costs and to an upwards pressure on prices which will tend to shift the aggregate supply schedule upwards.6 Combined with a lower aggregate demand due to higher taxes (i.e., assuming that the decline in private demand is not exceeded by an increase in public spending) an upwards shift in the aggregate supply curve will unambiguously result in lower output. The effect on the price level is less clear. It depends on the slope of the relevant sections of the supply and demand curves.7 If, on the other hand, aggregate demand remains unchanged (because of increased public spending), we will see both lower output and higher prices.8 But to what extent do wages actually respond to changing tax burdens? Obviously, employees must be aware of them in order to achieve any compensation for them in the labour market. 4 The German 'Stability Law' dating from 1973 has, for instance, introduced a temporary increase in the corporate income tax for the years 1973 and 1974. The law specified that resulting additional tax receipts could not be spent but had to be kept on reserve with the Bundesbank. See Pilz (1977), pp. 175-. 5 Hersoug (1984), p. 50. 6Whether and to what extent higher wages are, in fact, passed on to consumers in the form of price increases will depend on the relative degrees of market power of producers and consumers. See Tarling and Wilkinson (1985) for a discussion of the mechanisms of mark-up pricing. 7 See Blinder (1973). 8 Smyth (1983) formalises these relationships in a simple model. 4 Given this awareness, the impact on wages depends on the market structure. In a perfectly competitive labour market, there is no involuntary unemployment and the only way taxes on wages can alter the equilibrium wage level is through changes in individual working hours. This is illustrated in figure 1. Given an hourly wage w, B0 is the individual’s initial budget constraint. In a progressive tax system, the increase in after-tax income gained from working an additional hour decreases with increasing hours (the budget constraint becomes flatter). Initially, the individual chooses the optimum number of working hours h0. At the associated level of gross income, a+b, the average tax rate is a/(a+b) and the marginal tax rate, illustrated by the tangency line, is mtr0. Increasing the marginal tax rate (while keeping the average tax rate unchanged), by changing the budget constraint to Bm, will lead to a reduction of working hours to hm (pure substitution effect). An increase in the average tax rate (keeping the marginal rate unchanged) shifts the budget constraint downwards (Ba).9 The effect on working hours will depend on the relative size of the income and substitution effects. As long as the substitution effect dominates (positively sloped labour supply curve) working hours will decrease (ha). For most segments of existing labour markets in Europe, however, the standard competitive model seems inappropriate. Where involuntary unemployment does exist, modern theories of imperfect labour markets offer alternative and more differentiated analyses of the effects of tax changes. Starting in the mid-1980s, there have been several influential theoretical papers on how taxes impact on the wage setting process in an imperfect labour market.10 Results from more recent empirical studies for several European countries tend to be consistent with these theories – indicating that the imperfect labour market model is in fact appropriate in the European context (e.g., Aronsson et al., 1997; Graafland and Huizinga, 1996). These theories focus on the respective incentives of employees and employers in the wage-setting process, i.e., agents now have some market power and are no longer seen as mere price-takers. In order to capture these incentives, it is not sufficient to characterise tax changes in terms of their impact on the size of the tax burden. Instead one has to consider the marginal and average tax rates separately. In addition, it becomes important how the opportunity cost of participation in the labour market, usually represented by the unemployment benefit, is affected by a tax change. For example, union bargaining models assume a trade-off between unions' desire for lower unemployment among the workers they represent and higher real after tax wages (Hersoug, 1984; Malcomson and Sartor, 1987; Lockwood and Manning, 1993; Holmlund and Kolm, 1995). In other words, by trading wages for unemployment unions can influence the wage rate and, thus, the slope of the budget constraint in figure 1.11 Assuming constant real net unemployment benefits and unchanged progressivity at the relevant point of the tax schedule, increased average tax rates reduce the relative value of labour income vis-à-vis unemployment benefits (i.e., the replacement ratio increases).12 Unemployment will thus appear less painful to union members and 9 Note that it is impossible to change the average tax rate while keeping the marginal rate constant for all income levels. In figure 1, marginal tax rates are left unchanged for all upper income levels, while for lower incomes, they are increased (right hand part of Ba is flatter than B0). 10 References are provided in Hansen et al. (2000), Pissarides (1998) and Sorensen (1997). 11 Most earlier models take individual working hours as exogenously given. However, more recent studies have modelled a bargaining process where unions and firms negotiate wages and working hours simultaneously. See Fuest and Huber (2000), Hansen et al. (2000) and Hansen (1999). 12 For countries where unemployment benefits are non-taxable, a sufficient condition for the replacement ratio to increase is that the benefit level changes by the same proportion as pre-tax wages (which is the case if the former is a fixed percentage of the latter). If benefits are taxable then the replacement rate will still go up (even if the real after-tax benefit decreases) as long as the real after-tax wage decreases by more (in relative terms). Whether this is the case will depend on the specific structure of the (effective) tax schedule. It should also be stressed that, as 5 the unions' preferences will tend to shift away from avoiding unemployment towards securing higher wage increases. On the other hand, an increase in the marginal tax rate will cause unions to moderate their wage demands since changes in the before tax wage now have a smaller effect on union members' after tax income. The actual outcome of the bargaining process will depend on the respective target wages of employers and unions as well as their relative bargaining powers. Since taxes on employment income do not change the target wage of the employer “it is not unreasonable to assume that, as long as the union has some bargaining power, the effect of such changes on the actual wage will be in the same direction as the effect on the union’s target wage.”13 The two other popular imperfect labour market models, the search model and the efficiency wage model, also predict that "increased tax progressivity (a rise in the marginal tax rate for a given average tax rate) will moderate wages and promote employment, whereas a rise in the average tax rate will tend to drive up the wage level."14 In the remainder of the paper, however, I concentrate on the union bargaining model. Given that tax changes in these models are predicted to have very different consequences depending on how they affect average taxes and progressivity, it is essential to carefully separate these two effects in any related analysis. This, however, is quite difficult for several reasons. First, tax rules are often very complicated. Apparently minor details of the tax code often cause very substantial ups and downs in marginal tax rates. Ignoring these details can therefore seriously bias any incentive effects modelled on the relationship between average and marginal tax rates. Secondly, it is the effective tax rates that determine the relative preferences in the above models. It is therefore important to consider both income taxes and social insurance contributions.15 In addition, effective tax rates are influenced by transfer payments as well so one has to also include state benefits in the analysis. The rules of these benefit payments are, however, frequently even more complicated than tax rules. Finally, different types of taxpayers will face very different effective tax rates and will therefore favour different target wages. Previous studies have simply computed the relevant tax rates for a ‘typical’ household type with average earnings (e.g., married couple with a single breadwinner and two ‘children’). Such an approach ignores the obvious influence of the household type on effective tax rates. Equally important, it ignores the fact that different earnings levels will be affected differently by any real-world change of the tax system. The union, however, must decide on one relevant change in effective tax rates in order to decide on its target wage. Once the union aggregates all the different changes in effective tax rates among its membership, the resulting target wage may be very different from one that would be optimal for someone with average earnings. The reason, as Lockwood and Manning (1993) Graafland and Huizinga (1996) and others have argued, the actual impact of the replacement rate on the wage outcome is likely to depend on the unemployment rate. 13 Malcomson and Sartor (1987), p. 1583. As far as the bracket creep phenomenon is concerned, however, this statement should be extended in one respect. The effective burdens resulting from employer social insurance contribution are, in fact, potentially distorted by inflation. But since contribution schedules are usually regressive, inflation reduces the employer’s effective contribution burden. So in this case, there is even more reason to expect the union’s target wage and the actual wage to move in the same direction. 14 Sorensen (1997), p. 229. 15 There are two (related) complications here. One is that compulsory social insurance contributions could be seen as not reducing take-home pay if there is a perceived relationship between the amount paid and any (potential) social insurance benefits received. If this is the case then any contributions paid by the employer would also need to be included in the ‘take-home pay’ income concept. In the remaining part of the paper, I disregard these considerations for reasons of simplicity. In most countries, not distinguishing between income taxes and contribution payments can probably be justified on the grounds that there exist substantial tax-financed subsidies for social insurance funds. 6 note, is that “the average marginal and the average average tax rates will in general not be equal to the marginal and average tax rates evaluated at the average earnings.”16 3. Methodology I use a tax-benefit microsimulation model to compute taxes and benefits for each household in a representative micro data set. The model contains very detailed tax- and benefit rules including the interaction between different instruments. Using micro data sets which are representative of the respective country’s population it captures the actual variation of household types and earnings levels. The approach therefore addresses all three difficulties described above. On the basis of the computed taxes and benefits, I calculate average effective tax rates (AETRs) and marginal effective tax rates (METRs). The calculations result in a detailed picture of the distribution of AETRs and METRs. Rather than averaging across very different earnings levels and household situations, the approach produces results which reflect the diversity of the underlying population. To determine the effect of inflation, the calculations are performed for a “before inflation” and “after inflation” scenario. AETRs and METRs for the "after inflation" scenario are computed under the assumption of (1) unadjusted tax rules but adjusted benefit rules (7%_IT) and (2) unadjusted tax and benefit rules (7%_IT&BEN). An important advantage of the simulation approach is that it is able to isolate the effects of inflation on AETRs and METRs while keeping everything else constant. Using results from the literature on the elasticity of wages with respect to average and marginal tax rates as a starting point, I then discuss how the change in effective tax rates can be used as a basis for an estimate of potential wage pressures caused by inflation induced distortions of taxes and benefits. It is important to note that the scenarios explored here are hypothetical. This approach is necessary because the aim is to determine possible cost-push effects of fiscal drag in un-indexed tax-benefit systems.17 However, in three of the countries examined here, ‘automatic’ inflation adjustments of the tax-benefit system are in force (the exception is Ireland).18 In addition, the rate of inflation used in the simulations is 7%. For many countries, this may seem rather high. However, as pointed out in the introduction, fiscal stabilisers are especially important for countries such as Ireland whose economy has not yet ‘converged’ and who therefore experience larger price level movements than other countries. The model used is a preliminary version of EUROMOD, an integrated European tax-benefit model, which, at the time of writing, is under construction. EUROMOD provides us with a Europe-wide perspective on social and fiscal policies that are implemented at European, national or regional level. It is also designed to examine, within a consistent comparative framework, the impact of national policies on national populations or the differential impact of co-ordinated European policy on individual Member States. Within the context of the present paper, the most relevant feature of EUROMOD is that it can provide conceptually consistent and, thus, comparable output for different countries. See Immervoll et al. (1999) for more details. 16 p. 11. Emphases are in the original. 17 While it would be interesting to also explore the effects of fiscal drag given existing uprating regimes, it is not possible to examine the ‘automatic stabiliser’ argument in a tax-benefit system where the fiscal drag has been neutralised by adjusting tax-benefit rules for inflation. The interested reader is referred to Immervoll (2000) where I analyse the extent to which inflation distorts tax burdens given existing uprating regimes. 18 The scope and extent of indexing does, however, vary considerably between countries. See Immervoll (2000) for a description of indexing schemes (of income taxes and social insurance contributions) in the Netherlands and the UK. 7 Simulations are run for four countries: Finland, Ireland, the Netherlands and the UK. The micro data sets underlying the simulations are derived from the 1996 Finnish Income Distribution Survey (IDS), the Living in Ireland Survey, 1994 (Wave 1), the 1996 wave of the Dutch Socio-Economic Panel (SEP) and the UK 1995/6 Family Expenditure Survey. For detailed information regarding sample sizes, coverage, non-response, etc. the reader is referred to Sutherland (1999). In each case, the samples are weighted to adjust for non-response bias and to bring the results up to population levels. The simulations are based on the systems of tax and benefit rules current in June 1998 and all monetary variables in the micro-data are updated to this year using the most appropriate uprating index available for each type of income. Given the limitations of the underlying data, not all the relevant components of the respective taxbenefit systems lend themselves to simulation. I simulate income taxes, social insurance contributions, child benefits and other family benefits, and income-tested benefits.19 In computing income, components that are not simulated in the model are taken directly from the data. In particular, this is the case for contribution based payments, such as contributory pensions. For each country, there are three scenarios. The “base-line” scenarios use 1998 rules and data.20 In the “7%_IT” scenarios, all income variables in the data are increased by 7% to simulate an inflationary shock. In simulating tax and benefit instruments, income tax and social contribution rules remain unchanged, i.e., all amounts such as tax band limits, thresholds, deductions, etc. remain at their nominal 1998 values. In order to capture the pure ‘bracket creep’ effect caused by unadjusted income tax and social insurance contribution rules, all benefit rules are indexed for inflation (i.e., all amounts in the relevant benefit rules are also increased by 7%).21 To explore the consequences of different scopes of “indexing”, I also simulate a scenario where benefit rules are subject to inflation-induced distortions. In these scenarios, called “7%_IT&BEN”, the unadjusted 1998 benefit, income tax and contribution rules are used.22 For each scenario, AETRs and METRs are then computed for all employees in the data set of the respective country.23 The model allows these rates to be computed at any level of analysis that is supported by the data. It is, for example, possible to compute average tax rates at the level of the individual, the couple, the family (however defined), or the entire household. For marginal tax rates, there are even more alternative measurement approaches. For instance, decisions need to be taken regarding the sign and appropriate size of the margin, the income variable(s) to be altered, the relevant unit of analysis, and how the marginal income change is to be shared among members of this unit. For the purpose of this paper, AETRs and METRs are computed at the 19 Housing benefits are only simulated in Ireland, the Netherlands and the UK. For Finland the simulation routines for housing benefits have not been implemented yet and the housing benefit values recorded in the data are taken instead. However, at a later stage, EUROMOD will be able to simulate housing benefits for all countries where they exist. 20 As explained above, the original period to which the data refer to is not 1998. However, data are uprated from the original year to 1998 to construct a quasi-1998 population. 21 The rules are only adjusted for simulated benefits. Benefits that are not simulated, such as insurance-based transfers, are simply increased in line with inflation. 22 Note that leaving benefit rules unadjusted is not the same as leaving the nominal benefit amounts unchanged. Due to non-linearities in the benefit rules, not adjusting the rules may lead to larger changes in benefit amounts than the simple erosion caused by inflation. For example, income tested benefits may stop being paid altogether as a consequence of the (nominal) means exceeding some unadjusted threshold. 23 I define employees as persons working more than 10 hours per week and whose employment income represents their main source of earnings (i.e., it is higher than any self-employment income). 8 individual level. This means that one needs to decide sharing rules for instruments, which operate at a level other than the individual. For example, social assistance benefits influence effective tax rates since they affect disposable income. However, social assistance is normally paid at the family or household level. The actual impact on individuals’ effective tax rates therefore depends on how these benefits are shared among individuals. In the simulations I make the assumption that all benefits that do not clearly accrue to one specific person (such as pensions) are shared equally among all adults in the unit which is relevant for computing the benefit. Any taxes that are paid jointly are assumed to be split in proportion to the tax base of each individual of the tax unit (this is, for example, important in Ireland, where there is joint income taxation for married couples). The income variable to be varied for computing marginal taxes is, obviously, employment income. The size of the margin is taken to be plus 3%.24 One of the advantages of an integrated European tax-benefit model is that consistent income concepts can be used across countries. For the current exercise I use the following definition of disposable income (Y): wage and salary income (including sick pay paid by government and any lump-sum components of employment income), plus self-employment income, plus property income (rent, dividends, interest), plus other cash market income and occupational pension income plus regular private transfers, alimony and child maintenance, plus contributory (insurance-) benefits (state pensions, unemployment benefits, sickness benefits, etc.) plus non-contributory benefit payments (universal and social assistance benefits), minus direct taxes and (employee) social insurance contributions. This income concept is used for computing AETRs, effτa, and METRs, effτm, as follows.25 τ = d(T-B) / d(Y+T-B) (2) τ = (T-B) / (Y+T-B) (3) eff m eff a where T is the sum of income taxes and employee contributions, and B is the sum of all benefit payments. 4. Simulation Results The resulting distributions of AETRs and METRs for employees are presented in figures 2 and 3. The distribution of marginal rates is more concentrated in the UK than in the other three countries. Ireland shows the widest dispersion of rates. On average, METRs are lowest in the UK (about 32%) followed by Ireland and the Netherlands while in Finland, the average marginal burden (47%) is only slightly below the 50% mark. Turning to average rates (figure 2), the rate intervals where the largest shares of employees are located differs between the Ireland, the Netherlands and the UK on one hand and Finland on the other. In Finland, the largest number of 24 For some analyses it may make sense to compute the marginal tax rate for both a positive and a negative margin and use, say, their mean. However, in the majority of cases, inflation will cause tax burdens to increase (Immervoll, 2000). So the appropriate margin is one that is relevant for the union in deciding by how much the wage should be increased to compensate for higher taxes. The relevant question is therefore what proportion of a wage increase goes to union members (as increased take-home pay) in return for a higher risk of unemployment. Clearly, to answer this question a positive margin is needed. 25 Contributory benefits are not simulated because the necessary contribution records are not in the data. In the simulations, it is assumed that these benefits increase in line with inflation. Indirect taxes, and therefore any inflation induced erosion of the real value of excise taxes, are disregarded in the simulations presented here. However, a later version of EUROMOD will allow indirect taxes to be simulated. 9 employees is faced with effective tax rates of between 30-35%. More than 19% of Finnish employees pay more than 35% whereas in the other countries, this is only true for 2% (IR), 8% NL and 1.6% (UK) of employees. It is also worth noting that due to generous social benefits, a very large number of Finnish employees benefits from highly negative average tax burdens (less than -50%). Although it would clearly be interesting to explore these results further, the main interest of this paper is how, as a result of inflation, rates would change in an unadjusted tax-benefit system. Theories of imperfect labour markets stress the opposite effects of marginal and average tax rates in the wage setting process. Clearly, in an un-indexed progressive tax schedule inflation will increase the average tax rate for all taxpayers. On the other hand, in a large number of cases, taxpayers will remain in the same tax bracket. They will, thus, be confronted with higher average tax rates while the marginal tax rates will remain unchanged. In these cases, the theoretical and empirical results discussed above would point towards increasing real labour costs. Whether and to what extent inflation raises the marginal tax rates for a significant number of tax payers will be determined by the rate of inflation and the proximity of taxpayers' nominal incomes to the next higher tax band limit. An increase in the marginal tax rate will obviously be more likely if tax 26 bands are narrow or inflation is high. The tax schedules of the countries considered here are rather wide. In most cases, one would therefore expect the number of taxpayers with unchanged marginal tax rates to dominate in cases of low to moderate inflation. Figures 4 to 7 show that this is indeed the case. The graphs show how, in an unadjusted taxbenefit system, employees’ METRs and AETRs change following a uniform 7% increase in all their primary incomes. The METRs of between 64% (IR) and 85% (UK) of employees are exactly the same after inflation as they were before. Even though most employees whose METRs do change are confronted with a larger marginal burden, some actually experience decreasing METRs. This is because, as their nominal incomes rise, individuals may no longer be eligible for tax credits or benefit payments that are subject to an income taper. They are thus no longer affected by the high withdrawal rates (and therefore effective marginal rates) caused by theses instruments. As means tested social assistance benefits are the main contributor to high withdrawal rates, the numbers of employees facing decreasing METRs are higher for the scenario where benefit rules are not adjusted for inflation (7%_IT&BEN). AETRs, on the other hand, go up for almost everybody. Looking first at the ‘7%_IT’ scenarios, employees face higher income tax burdens as inflation erodes the real value of tax free allowances, deductions, tax credits, and tax rate bands. In most cases, any decrease in AETRs caused by regressive social insurance contribution systems less than compensates for the rise in average income tax rates. However, despite a very progressive income tax schedule, more employees in the Netherlands (fig. 6) benefit from decreasing AETRs (and METRs) than in other countries.27 In Finland (fig. 4) the federal income tax is quite 26 For tax schedules where the marginal tax rate rises continuously rather than in steps, every tax payer will face higher marginal tax rates as a result of rising nominal incomes. The case of Germany, where marginal rates do rise continually rather than in steps, would therefore be an interesting one to examine. It is planned to include Germany in a later version of this paper. 27 This is because in the Netherlands the regressive social insurance contributions are, in terms of total receipts, considerably more important than income taxes. They are also more regressive than in other countries. Employee and employer health insurance contributions are no longer payable once employment income exceeds a certain upper limit. On one hand, this reduces employee health insurance contributions to zero. On the other hand, employer contributions are part of taxable income. The regressive effect of employee contributions is therefore amplified by decreasing income taxes. See Immervoll (2000) for a more detailed description of the Dutch and 10 progressive with the largest number of tax bands (six plus a zero-tax band) of the countries considered here. There are also no upper contribution limits and one part of the contribution system (health insurance) actually exhibits a progressive rate structure. As a result, a large number of employees are confronted with METR increases exceeding 5%. However, a large part of the tax revenue is generated by the local income tax system, the tariff of which is proportional. This dampens the effect on AETRs. Turning to Ireland (fig. 5), a larger number of taxpayers are, compared to the other three countries, at the upper end of the income tax schedule (which consists of only two tax bands). More persons are therefore affected by the erosion of deductions and tax-free allowances. In addition, many employees have income below but close to the lower limit of the upper income tax band. Consequently, bracket creep from the lower (24%) to the upper (46%) marginal tax rate band has a larger effect than in other countries. Taken together, these effects account for the large number of employees facing an increase in their average tax rate of more than 5%. The large bracket creep effect also causes very substantial METRs increases (>40%) for a substantial number of taxpayers. In the UK (fig. 7), the number of employees whose METRs are unaffected by inflation is considerably higher than in other countries. This is due to the wide income tax bands in this country. There are, however, a relatively large number of employees with decreasing marginal rates. This can be explained by the relative importance of income dependent benefits (see below). In the ‘IT&BEN’ scenarios, AETRs show a further increase as the real value of benefits decreases since, in these scenarios, benefit rules are no longer indexed to the price level. Child benefits have the largest impact in this respect: 34% and 40% of all employees receive child benefit in the UK and the Netherlands respectively; in Finland and Ireland, the fractions of employees receiving the benefit are 42% and 40%. However, as discussed above, the effect of unadjusted benefit rules on METRs often goes in the opposite direction. It is well known that, because benefits are withdrawn as incomes increase, income tested benefits can cause very high METRs. Once incomes exceed the level where the benefit is tapered to zero, the METR will therefore drop significantly (often all the way to zero since for these low income levels, the tax system may not ‘bite’ yet). If the benefit rules are not adjusted for inflation, a certain number of benefit recipients are no longer eligible for income tested benefits after inflation causes their nominal incomes to increase. These persons are therefore no longer affected by high withdrawal rates and their METRs fall. This effect is documented by the difference in METRs between the ‘IT’ and ‘IT&BEN’ scenarios. Clearly, in this paper the impact of income tested benefits in this respect depend on how many employees actually receive them in the baseline scenario. In 1998, around 6.5% of UK employees working more than 10 hours received means tested benefits (Income Support, Housing Benefit, Council Tax Benefit). A further 2.9% benefited from the income and working hours related in-work benefit (Family Credit), causing a noticeable reduction of METRs between the ‘IT’and the ‘IT&BEN’scenario. In the Netherlands, the METR reducing effect of income dependent benefits is also considerable since about 1.4% and 4.0% of employees are, respectively, in receipt of social assistance and rent subsidy.28 With 0.2%, a much smaller fraction of Irish unionised employees receive social British income tax and contribution rules. The 1998 tax and benefit rules and details about their simulation in the model are described in the EUROMOD country reports, which are currently being produced. They will be available from the author on request. 28 However, it is possible that the effect of rent subsidy is overestimated here. The reason is that there may be a take-up issue, which is currently not taken into account in the simulations. The simulated 4% in receipt of housing benefits contrast with a mere 1.3% who have claimed to receive this benefit in the 1996 microdata. A validation exercise, which is currently underway for all 15 countries, is designed to clarify the sources of such deviations. 11 assistance (Family Income Supplement).29 As a result, not adjusting benefit rules for inflation has only a minor effect on the number of employees with decreasing METRs: the bars in figure 5 are almost identical for the 7%_IT and the 7%_IT&BEN scenarios. The same is true for Finland (fig. 4) where only 0.4% of employees receive social assistance. However, the changes in METRs shown in the table should be interpreted with some caution. The Finnish microdata show that housing benefit is received by a considerable number of unionised employees (7%). However, the version of EUROMOD used here does not yet simulate Finnish housing benefits. The decrease in METRs is therefore likely to be larger than indicated by the results presented here. 5. Discussion and Interpretation In a recent study Auerbach and Feenberg (2000) look at the labour market effects of inflation induced tax distortions in the context of a competitive labour market. They focus on how bracket creep leads to rising marginal rates as taxpayers move across tax band schedules. In cases where the average and marginal rates move in the same direction30, the focus on marginal rates is justified because, as shown in figure 1, as long as the substitution effect is greater than the income effect, changes in marginal and average tax rates will influence labour supply, and thus wages, in the same direction. As argued above, however, models of imperfect labour markets predict that marginal and average tax rates influence the outcome of the wage setting process in different directions. Table 1 presents results, for three of the countries covered in this paper31, of empirical studies of the impact of marginal and average tax rates on the real wage level. All three results confirm the theoretical predictions. How can these results be combined with the detailed information, discussed in the previous section, on tax rate changes following inflationary distortions of the tax-benefit system? Unfortunately, there is no straightforward way to do this. It is evident from the simulation results, that inflation induced changes in METRs and AETRs vary considerably among employees. Focusing again on the union wage setting model, this makes it likely that the tax rates of employees of different unions will be affected differently. But the elasticities shown in table 1 are not available at a disaggregated level. Furthermore, in estimating them, the variation in tax rates necessary for eliciting elasticities has only been measured in relation to one employee who is deemed to be representative: Studies estimating wage equations typically take an approach as follows (e.g. Lockwood and Manning, 1993). First, it is assumed that the distribution of tax rates is the same in all unions. As a result, it is not necessary to identify who belongs to which union. Secondly, the union is supposed to base its target wage on the tax rates faced by an employee with average earnings living in a household which is considered to be ‘typical’. It follows that it is sufficient to know the tax rates faced by the employee with average earnings - calculating the tax rates of a large number of different employees can thus be avoided.32 29 Housing benefits are not important in this group either. 30As demonstrated above, this is not the case for all individuals. 31I am not aware of any empirical studies for Ireland. 32Resorting to this latter assumption also means that it is not necessary to specify an aggregation rule for the different preferences faced by the members. By only considering the tax variables of the 'typical' employee, one implicitly assumes that the union's preferred wage is identical with the 'typical' employee's. See Booth (1985), Oswald (1982) and Oswald (1985) for different approaches to aggregating preferences across the membership of a union. 12 The currently available elasticities of wages with respect to marginal and average tax rates do, in other words, not support the level of disaggregation at which changes in AETRs and METRs have been computed here. Yet, since benefits and taxes are strongly dependent on earnings, the family situation and other characteristics, ignoring the influence of the distribution of these characteristics on employee's tax rates and, thus, the union's target wage can clearly produce misleading results. In order to still be able to speculate on possible influences of 'bracket creep' on the wage level I have, nevertheless, used the elasticities from table 1 for illustrative purposes. Despite the fact that elasticities have been generated by using the tax rate changes of the average union member (rather than the average tax rate changes of all union members) as explanatory variables, I have used them to compute the effect on real wages of the mean change in AETRs and METRs. The results are reported in table 2. They indicate that inflation induced distortions of the tax-benefit system do cause cost-push effects through real wage increases. However, for reasons stated above, these results leave much to be desired and the numbers can therefore not be regarded as reliable estimates.33 It is useful in this context to highlight the desirability of enriching the specification of microeconometric models through the incorporation of tax-benefit microsimulation.34 As is evident from the difficulties discussed here, this seems necessary because in practice, “trade union members have different labour and non-labour incomes, different family characteristics, etc. and face different marginal and average tax rates [… ] The empirical studies of tax effects on wage formation normally use aggregate time-series and do not allow for the microeconomic diversity that microeconometritians would like to emphasize.”35 6. Conclusion This paper has described an approach to the detailed measurement of changes in marginal and average effective tax rates following inflation induced distortions of the tax-benefit system. A preliminary version of EUROMOD was used to compute inflation induced changes of effective tax rates for representative samples of the population of four European countries. The approach therefore takes into account both the complexities of tax-benefit systems and the heterogeneity of taxpayers and benefit recipients in the population and produces results for both the levels and the distribution of marginal and average effective tax rates. Furthermore, the simulation method is 33A few other limitations should be noted here. The most important is probably that the range of results obtained from different studies of the wage effects of taxes in imperfect labour markets is considerable. Recently there have been some studies extending the wage setting model used in earlier studies (Anderson et al., 1999; Hansen et al., 2000; Hansen, 1999; Fuest and Huber, 2000). Even though these recent results do not necessarily overturn the qualitative results obtained in earlier papers, they do illustrate the need for a more refined understanding of the wage setting process. It seems particularly important to establish how trade unions elicit and aggregate union members’ preferences. Unless the target wage is voted on (in which case preferences are elicited automatically), it is not clear to what extent unions take into account the complexities of the tax-benefit systems, which affect their members’ tax rates (however, in voting models, a similar problem arises in that union members may themselves not perceive the tax-benefit system ‘correctly’. See, e.g., Arrazola et al. (2000)). In some sense, therefore, there is a possibility that detailed tax-benefit modelling may be ‘too detailed’. For a detailed discussion on more general issues relating to the reliability of microsimulation results for population sub-groups see Pudney and Sutherland (1994). 34Numerous studies examining the role of tax-benefit systems in labour supply decisions have successfully done this. See for example Blundell et al (2000), Callan (2000), Duncan and Weeks (1997), Callan and van Soest (1993). 35 Christiansen, V. (1997), ‘Discussion’, in: P.B. Sorensen (1997), op cit., p. 252. 13 able to isolate the effect of distortions of unadjusted tax and benefit rules, while holding ‘everything else’constant. It has been argued that the extent to which inflation induced tax increases (and benefit reductions) potentially contribute to a cost-push effect through higher real wages will crucially depend on the actual structure of the labour market. In addition, however, it has become apparent that however the wage setting process is being modelled, the effect on the wage outcome will be a function of (1) the detailed structure of the tax-benefit system; (2) the extent and scope of adjustments of the tax-benefit system to price-level changes; and (3) the structure of the population. Using taxbenefit microsimulation it is possible to capture these three dimensions. The main contribution of the present study is to give a detailed picture of the joint effects of inflation and an unadjusted tax-benefit system on marginal and average effective tax rates. The most important result is that the impact varies considerably between employees. Estimates from existing studies on the role of marginal and average tax rates in the wage setting process have then been applied to the simulated tax rate changes. The results indicate that in an unadjusted taxbenefit system, inflation does tend to exercise a moderate upward pressure on labour costs. However, it has been argued that the methodology underlying available elasticities of wages with respect to marginal and average tax rates are too simplistic since models used to estimate them only focus on the 'representative' tax payer. They ignore the fact that tax rates will be subject to quite different changes depending on taxpayers’ earnings, family situation, etc. Tax-benefit microsimulation can provide a remedy in this context. It can be used to enrich econometric models used for estimating elasticities of wages by providing detailed tax and benefit estimates separately for each observation. 14 References Aaron, H.J. (ed) (1976), Inflation and the Income Tax, Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C. Andersen, T.M. and B.S. Rasmussen (1999), ‘Effort, taxation and unemployment’, Economics Letters, 62, pp. 97-103. Aronsson, T., M. Wikström, and R. Brännlund (1997), ‘Wage determination under non-linear taxes: Esimation and an application to panel data’, Oxford Economic Papers, 49, pp. 404-18. Arrazola, M., J. de Hevia, and J.F. Sanz (2000), ‘More on tax perception and labour supply: the Spanish case’, Economics Letters, 67, pp. 15-21. Auerbach, A.J. and D. Feenberg (2000), ‘The significance of federal taxes as automatic stabilisers’, NBER working paper, no. 7662, Cambridge, MA. Blinder, A.S. (1973), ‘Can Income Tax Increases be Inflationary? An Expository Note’, National Tax Journal, pp. 295-301. Blundell, R., A. Duncan, J. McCrae and C. Meghir (2000), ‘The Labour Market Impact of the Working Families' Tax Credit’, Fiscal Studies, 21. pp.75-100. Booth, A.L. (1985), ‘The free rider problem and a social custom model of trade union membership’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, pp. 253-61. Callan, T. (ed) (2000), Taxes, Transfers and Labour Market Responces: What Can Microsimulation Tell Us? Dublin: ESRI. Callan, T. and A. van Soest (1993), ‘Female labour supply in farm households’, The Economic and Social Review, 24, pp. 313-34. Calmfors, L. (1982), ‘Employment policies, wage formation and trade union behaviour in a small open economy’, Scandinavian Journal of Economics. Christiansen, V. (1997), ‘Discussion’, in: Sorensen (1997), p. 252. Dernburg, T.F. (1974), ‘The Macroeconomic Implications of Wage Retaliation Against Higher Taxation’, IMF Staff Papers, Nov. Duncan, A. and M. Weeks (1997), ‘Behavioural Tax Microsimulation with Finite Hours Choices’, European Economic Review, 41, pp. 619-26. European Commission (1999), ‘Study 4: Market Integration and Differences in Price Levels Between EU Member States’, in: European Commission, EU Economy: 1999 Review, Brussels. Fuest, C. and B. Huber (2000), ‘Is tax progression really good for employment? A model with endogenous hours of work’, Labour Economics, 7, pp. 79-93. Graafland, J.J. and F.H. Huizinga (1996), ‘Taxes and benefits in a non-linear wage equation’, Research Memorandum, no 126, CPB Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis, The Hague. Hansen, C.T. (1999), ‘Lower tax progression, longer hours and higher wages’, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 101, pp. 49-65. Hansen, C.T., L.H. Pedersen, and T. Slok (2000), ‘Ambiguous effects of tax progressivity – theory and Danish evidence’, Labour Economics, 7, pp. 335-47. Hersoug, T. (1984), ‘Union wage responses to tax changes’, Oxford Economic Papers, 36, pp. 37-51. Holmlund, B. and A.S. Kolm (1995), ‘Progressive taxation, wage setting and unemployment – theory and Swedish evidence’, Tax Reform Evaluation Report, no. 15, National Institute of Economic Research and Economic Council, Sweden. Immervoll, H. (2000), ‘The impact of inflation on income tax and social insurance contributions in Europe’, EUROMOD Working Paper, no. 2/00, Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge. Available through http://www.econ.cam.ac.uk/dae/mu/emwp4aa.pdf. Immervoll, H., C. O’Donoghue and H. Sutherland (1999), ‘An Introduction to EUROMOD’, EUROMOD Working Paper, no. 0/99, Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge. Available through http://www.econ.cam.ac.uk/dae/mu/emwp0.pdf. Jackson, D., F. Wilkinson and H.A. Turner (1972), Do trade unions cause inflation?, Department of Applied Economics Occasional Paper, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge. Lockwood, B. and A. Manning (1993), ‘Wage setting and the tax system. Theory and evidence for the United Kingdom’, Journal of Public Economics, 52, pp. 1-29. 15 Malcomson, J.M. and N. Sartor (1987), ‘Tax push inflation in a unionized labour market’, European Economic Review, 31, pp. 1581-96. Messere, K. (ed) (1998), The Tax System in Industrialized Countries, Oxford University Press, Oxford. Musgrave, R. and P.B. Musgrave (1976), Public Finance in Theory and Practice, 2nd edition, McGrawHill: New York. Nowotny, E. (1980), ‘Inflation and Taxation: Reviewing the Macroeconomic Issues’, Journal of Economic Literature, 18, pp. 1025-49. OECD (1976), The Adjustment of Personal Income Tax Systems for Inflation, Paris. OECD (1986), Personal Income Tax Systems Under Changing Economic Conditions, Paris. Oswald, A.J. (1982), ‘The microeconomic theory of the trade union’, Economic Journal, 92, pp. 269-83. Oswald, A.J. (1985), ‘The economic theory of trade unions: An introductory survey’, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 87, pp. 160-193. Piltz, D.J. (1977), ‘Deutscher Landesbericht’, in: International Fiscal Association, Studies on International Fiscal Law: Inflation and Taxation, Vienna, 161-79. Pissarides, C.A. (1998), ‘The impact of employment tax cuts on unemployment and wages; The role of unemployment benefits and tax structure’, Eurpean Economic Review, 42, pp. 155-83. Pudney, S. and H. Sutherland (1994), ‘How reliable are microsimulation results? An analysis of the role of sampling error in a U.K. tax-benefit model’, Journal of Public Economics, 53, pp. 327-65. Smyth, D.J., (1983), ‘Taxes and Inflation’, in: N. Schmukler and E. Marcus, Inflation Through the Ages: Economic, Social, Psychological and Historical Aspects, Brooklyn College Press, New York, pp. 326-39. Sorensen, P.B. (1997), ‘Public finance solutions to the European unemployment problem?’, Economic Policy, 25, pp. 223-64. Sutherland, H. (1999), EUROMOD Data Robustness Assessment Exercise Questionnaire. Microsimulation Unit, Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge. Tanzi, V. (1980), Inflation and the personal income tax: An international perspective, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Tarling, R. and F. Wilkinson (1985), 'Mark-up pricing, inflation and distributional shares: a note', Cambridge Journal of Economics, 9, pp. 179-85. Tyrväinen , T. (1995), ‘Real wage resistance and unemployment: multivariate analysis of cointegrating relations in 10 OECD countries’, OECD Job Study Working Paper, no. 10, Paris. Zilberfarb, B.Z. (1981), ‘Partial Tax Indexation and Economic Stability’, in: J.M. Flanders and A. Razin (eds), Development in an Inflationary World, Proceedings of the 1979 Pinhas Sapir Conference, New York, pp. 163-71. 16 Table 1. Sensitivity of real wages with respect to marginal and average tax rates. Country Elasticity of real pre-tax wages wrt1 FI average retention ratio (1-ta) -1 marginal retention ratio (1-tm) 0.3 NL -0.61 0.18 UK [-0.64, -1.40] [0.65, 1.40] 1 The elasticities given for Finland, the Netherlands and the UK are those estimated by Tyrväinen (1995) taken from Sorensen (1997); Graafland and Huizinga (1996); Lockwood and Manning (1993), respectively. Where intervals are shown, they represent the maxima and minima found in studies using alternative estimation approaches or measurement periods. Table 2. Changes in pre-tax wages following inflation. Country FI1 average change in METRs 7%_IT 7%_IT&BEN +2.17% +2.00% average change in AETRs 7%_IT 7%_IT&BEN +16.05% +20.45% change in real pre-tax wage 7%_IT 7%_IT&BEN +0.4% +0.8% IR1 +4.53% +4.12% +5.25% +6.29% NL2 +0.75% -0.13% +3.21% +6.03% +0.4% +0.9% UK2 +1.34% +0.37% +4.19% +6.41% [-0.1%; +0.1%] [+0.6%; +1.3%] Source: EUROMOD and own calculations based on table 1. 1 Changes in METRs and AETRs are averaged across unionised employees only. 2 Changes in METRs and AETRs are averaged across all employees (no union membership information is available in the micro-data used). 17 Figure 1. The role of marginal and average tax rates in a competitive labour market. net income 1 1 (1- mtr 0) ⋅w a w B0 Bm Um Ba U0 Ua b hm leisure ha h0 18 Source: EUROMOD .7 t o .75 .7 .65 .65 to .6 t o .6 .55 .55 to .5 t o .5 .45 .45 to .4 t o .4 .35 .35 to .3 t o .3 .25 .25 to .2 t o .2 .15 .15 to .1 t o .1 .05 .05 to 0 to 0 <0 Share Figure 2. Distribution of Marginal Effective Tax Rates (Employees) 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% Source: EUROMOD .2 t o .25 .2 .15 .15 to .1 t o .1 .05 .05 to 0 to 0 -.05 -.05 to -.1 to -.1 -.15 -.15 to -.2 to -.2 -.25 -.25 to -.3 to -.3 -.35 -.35 to -.4 to -.4 -.45 30% -.45 to -.5 to <-.5 Share Figure 3. Distribution of Average Effective Tax Rates (Employees) 35% UK Finland Netherlands Ireland 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% Figure 4. FI: Distribution of Changes in Marginal Effective Tax Rates 20% 18% 7%_IT Scenario 16% 7%_IT&BEN Scenario 14% 0% Change: 65.4% (7%_IT Scenario) 65.1% (7%_IT&BEN Scenario) Share 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% >40 40 25 to 35 30 to 30 25 to 25 20 to 20 15 to 15 10 to 10 5 to 5 0 to 0 -5 t o -5 -10 to -10 -20 -15 -15 to -20 to -25 -25 to -30 to -30 -35 to -35 -40 to <-4 0 0% Change [%] FI: Distribution of Changes in Average Effective Tax Rates 85% 80% 75% 70% 65% 7%_IT Scenario 60% 7%_IT&BEN Scenario 55% Share 50% 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% >40 40 25 to 35 30 to 30 25 to 25 20 to 20 15 to 15 10 to 10 5 to 5 0 to =0 <0 0% Change [%] Source: EUROMOD 21 Figure 5. IR: Distribution of Changes in Marginal Effective Tax Rates 20% 18% Share 16% 7%_IT Scenario 14% 7%_IT&BEN Scenario 12% 0% Change: 64.3% (7%_IT Scenario) 64.1% (7%_IT&BEN Scenario) 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% >40 40 25 to 35 30 to 30 25 to 25 20 to 20 15 to 15 10 to 10 5 to 5 0 to 0 -5 t o -5 -10 to -10 -20 -15 -15 to -20 to -25 -25 to -30 to -30 -35 to -35 -40 to <-4 0 0% Change [%] IR: Distribution of Changes in Average Effective Tax Rates 85% 80% 75% 70% 65% 7%_IT Scenario 60% 7%_IT&BEN Scenario 55% Share 50% 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% >40 40 25 to 35 30 to 30 25 to 25 20 to 20 15 to 15 10 to 10 5 to 5 0 to =0 <0 0% Change [%] Source: EUROMOD 22 Figure 6. NL: Distribution of Changes in Marginal Effective Tax Rates 20% 18% 7%_IT Scenario 16% 7%_IT&BEN Scenario 14% 0% Change: 65.8% (7%_IT Scenario) 64.2% (7%_IT&BEN Scenario) Share 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% >40 40 25 to 35 30 to 30 25 to 25 20 to 20 15 to 15 10 to 10 5 to 5 0 to 0 -5 t o -5 -10 to -10 -20 -15 -15 to -20 to -25 -25 to -30 to -30 -35 to -35 -40 to <-4 0 0% Change [%] NL: Distribution of Changes in Average Effective Tax Rates 85% 80% 75% 70% 65% 7%_IT Scenario 60% 7%_IT&BEN Scenario 55% Share 50% 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% >40 40 25 to 35 30 to 30 25 to 25 20 to 20 15 to 15 10 to 10 5 to 5 0 to =0 <0 0% Change [%] Source: EUROMOD 23 Figure 7. UK: Distribution of Changes in Marginal Effective Tax Rates 20% 18% 7%_IT Scenario 16% 7%_IT&BEN Scenario 14% 0% Change: 85.2% (7%_IT Scenario) 84.4% (7%_IT&BEN Scenario) Share [%] 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% >40 35 40 25 to 25 to 30 to 30 25 20 to 20 15 to 10 15 10 to 5 to 5 0 to 0 -5 t o -5 -10 to -10 -20 -15 -15 to -20 to -25 to -25 -30 to -30 -35 to -35 -40 to <-4 0 0% Change [%] UK: Distribution of Changes in Average Effective Tax Rates 85% 80% 75% 70% 65% 7%_IT Scenario 60% 7%_IT&BEN Scenario Share [%] 55% 50% 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% >40 40 25 to 35 30 to 30 25 to 25 20 to 20 15 to 15 10 to 10 5 to 5 0 to =0 <0 0% Change [%] Source: EUROMOD 24