Download FT.com print article

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Economics of fascism wikipedia , lookup

Business cycle wikipedia , lookup

Fiscal multiplier wikipedia , lookup

Nouriel Roubini wikipedia , lookup

Global financial system wikipedia , lookup

Steady-state economy wikipedia , lookup

Economic calculation problem wikipedia , lookup

Post–World War II economic expansion wikipedia , lookup

Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup

Keynesian Revolution wikipedia , lookup

Keynesian economics wikipedia , lookup

International monetary systems wikipedia , lookup

Post-war displacement of Keynesianism wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
FT.com print article
1 of 2
http://www.ft.com/cms/s/be2dbf2c-d113-11dd-8cc3-000077b07658,d...
COLUMNISTS
MARTIN WOLF
Close
Keynes offers us the best way to think about the financial
crisis
By Martin Wolf
Published: December 23 2008 18:06 | Last updated: December 23 2008 18:06
We are all Keynesians now. When Barack Obama takes office he will propose a gigantic fiscal
stimulus package. Such packages are being offered by many other governments. Even Germany is
being dragged, kicking and screaming, into this race.
The ghost of John Maynard Keynes, the father of macroeconomics, has returned to haunt us. With it has
come that of his most interesting disciple, Hyman Minsky. We all now know of the “Minsky moment” –
the point at which a financial mania turns into panic.
Like all prophets, Keynes offered ambiguous lessons to his followers. Few still believe in the fiscal
fine-tuning that his disciples propounded in the decades after the second world war. But nobody
believes in the monetary targeting proposed by his celebrated intellectual adversary, Milton Friedman,
either. Now, 62 years after Keynes’ death, in another era of financial crisis and threatened economic
slump, it is easier for us to understand what remains relevant in his teaching.
I see three broad lessons.
The first, which was taken forward by Minsky, is that we should not take the pretensions of financiers
seriously. “A sound banker, alas, is not one who foresees danger and avoids it, but one who, when he is
ruined, is ruined in a conventional way along with his fellows, so that no one can really blame him.” Not
for him, then, was the notion of “efficient markets”.
The second lesson is that the economy cannot be analysed in the same way as an individual business.
For an individual company, it makes sense to cut costs. If the world tries to do so, it will merely shrink
demand. An individual may not spend all his income. But the world must do so.
The third and most important lesson is that one should not treat the economy as a morality tale. In the
1930s, two opposing ideological visions were on offer: the Austrian; and the socialist. The Austrians –
Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich von Hayek – argued that a purging of the excesses of the 1920s was
required. Socialists argued that socialism needed to replace failed capitalism, outright. These views
were grounded in alternative secular religions: the former in the view that individual self-seeking
behaviour guaranteed a stable economic order; the latter in the idea that the identical motivation could
lead only to exploitation, instability and crisis.
Keynes’s genius – a very English one – was to insist we should approach an economic system not as a
morality play but as a technical challenge. He wished to preserve as much liberty as possible, while
recognising that the minimum state was unacceptable to a democratic society with an urbanised
economy. He wished to preserve a market economy, without believing that laisser faire makes
everything for the best in the best of all possible worlds.
This same moralistic debate is with us, once again. Contemporary “liquidationists” insist that a collapse
would lead to rebirth of a purified economy. Their leftwing opponents argue that the era of markets is
over. And even I wish to see the punishment of financial alchemists who claimed that ever more debt
turns economic lead into gold.
Yet Keynes would have insisted that such approaches are foolish. Markets are neither infallible nor
dispensable. They are indeed the underpinnings of a productive economy and individual freedom. But
they can also go seriously awry and so must be managed with care. The election of Mr Obama surely
reflects a desire for just such pragmatism. Neither Ron Paul, the libertarian, nor Ralph Nader, on the left,
got anywhere. So the task for this new administration is to lead the US and the world towards a
pragmatic resolution of the global economic crisis we all now confront.
The urgent task is to return the world economy to health.
The shorter-term challenge is to sustain aggregate demand, as Keynes would have recommended. Also
important will be direct central-bank finance of borrowers. It is evident that much of the load will fall on
the US, largely because the Europeans, Japanese and even the Chinese are too inert, too complacent,
05/01/2009 17:33
FT.com print article
2 of 2
http://www.ft.com/cms/s/be2dbf2c-d113-11dd-8cc3-000077b07658,d...
or too weak. Given the correction of household spending under way in the deficit countries, this period
of high government spending is, alas, likely to last for years. At the same time, a big effort must be made
to purge the balance sheets of households and the financial system. A debt-for-equity swap is surely
going to be necessary.
The longer-term challenge is to force a rebalancing of global demand. Deficit countries cannot be
expected to spend their way into bankruptcy, while surplus countries condemn as profligacy the
spending from which their exporters benefit so much. In the necessary attempt to reconstruct the global
economic order, on which the new administration must focus, this will be a central issue. It is one
Keynes himself had in mind when he put forward his ideas for the postwar monetary system at the
Bretton Woods conference in 1944.
No less pragmatic must be the attempt to construct a new system of global financial regulation and an
approach to monetary policy that curbs credit booms and asset bubbles. As Minsky made clear, no
permanent answer exists. But recognition of the systemic frailty of a complex financial system would be a
good start.
As was the case in the 1930s, we also have a choice: it is to deal with these challenges co-operatively
and pragmatically or let ideological blinkers and selfishness obstruct us. The objective is also clear: to
preserve an open and at least reasonably stable world economy that offers opportunity to as much of
humanity as possible. We have done a disturbingly poor job of this in recent years. We must do better.
We can do so, provided we approach the task in a spirit of humility and pragmatism, shorn of ideological
blinkers
As Oscar Wilde might have said, in economics, the truth is rarely pure and never simple. That is, for me,
the biggest lesson of this crisis. It is also the one Keynes himself still teaches.
[email protected]
Copyright The Financial Times Limited 2008
"FT" and "Financial Times" are trademarks of the Financial Times. Privacy policy | Terms
© Copyright The Financial Times Ltd 2008.
05/01/2009 17:33