Download Nationalism and Globalisation

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Business history wikipedia , lookup

Foreign market entry modes wikipedia , lookup

Capitalism wikipedia , lookup

Regional integration wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Nationalism and Globalisation: The Politics of
Losers?
John Etherington
Department of Political Science and Public Law,
Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona
Abstract
Globalisation is usually understood, however implicitly, to operate according to a
deterritorialising logic that undermines the specific spatial configuration of power and identity
proposed by nationalism. While at an abstract level, this position is probably correct, this paper
argues that we must go beyond a crude opposition between globalisation, the nation-state and
nationalism if we are to develop an approach capable of fully understanding the complex
interrelationship between these phenomena.
In this respect, we should not obviate the historically important role of states in the development
of world capitalism, nor should we overstate the power of globalising forces. By stressing the
twin dynamic of deterritorialisation and reterritorialisation, the paper stresses that these
interrelated processes come together in specific spatial and historical contexts, and thus it is
more useful to talk of nationalisms in the plural as a means of capturing this diversity.
Introduction
Since the decade of the 1980s 'globalisation' has become an increasingly ubiquitous term to
describe what are perceived to be fundamental changes to social life across the planet. The
vast volume of literature on the subject reflects often diverging understandings of globalisation,
although most accounts revolve around the idea that the world is becoming smaller and more
1
interconnected. This phenomenon, it is generally claimed, is relatively recent, dating from the
1970s, and would be impossible without the introduction and development of new information
technology, such as satellites and the internet. Geopolitical considerations, particularly the end
of the Cold War, have also contributed to the process of constructing a truly global space.
With regards to the consequences of globalisation for nations and nationalism, opinions differ. In
many accounts, it is argued that globalisation undermines nationalism in two basic ways: on the
one hand, the ultimate goal of nationalists, state sovereignty, is increasingly worthless as global
flows of goods, services, finance, people and so forth overcome nation-state boundaries and
thus nation-states’ capacity to regulate daily life; on the other, it is argued that place-based
identities, such as national identity, are increasingly difficult to sustain in the context of the
emergence of transnational and even ‘post-national’ identities (see, for example, Appadurai
1996; Bauman 1998; Harvey 1989; Kaldour 1996). This is not to say that levels of nationalist
political mobilisation are necessarily declining, but rather that it becomes a defensive strategy
against global cosmopolitanism, the ‘politics of losers’ (Hirst and Thompson 1996:180).
Yet contemporary nationalism is a more complex phenomenon than such accounts would have
us believe: it is alive and well both in the developed West - as the current debates in Scotland,
the Basque Country and Catalonia demonstrate - and also in regions with long histories of
ethnic territorial conflict such as the Caucasus. Authors such as Anthony Smith (see also
Tomlinson 1999; and Friedman 1994) accept that
there is, after all, plenty of evidence of growing cultural and economic uniformity in all
sorts of spheres and products. The advance of American mass culture, of the English
language, of pop culture, of the visual mass media and computerised information
technology clearly represent significant global cultural trends. These are, in all likelihood,
here to stay, at least for some decades. (Smith 1995:22)
However, he immediately begs the question ‘[b]ut what do they add up to? Can large numbers
of men and women live by them as well as with them?’ (Smith 1995:22). The answer is a
2
resounding ‘no’, since the emerging globalised culture is historically shallow, it has no memory,
it is value-neutral and traditionless. People need ‘irreplaceable culture values, and the particular
symbols rituals, ideals and traditions of those who forged and participated in them - which is
what many particular cultures of the past and present sought always to preserve (Smith
1995:23).
Rather than denying the transformative power of globalisation with regards nations and
nationalism, in the 1990s a series of authors began to stress the opportunities that globalisation
offered sub-state, regional political units, including historic nations without states. Based on the
proposition that ‘contemporary nation-states are now too small for the big problems of
contemporary social life and too big for the small problems’ (Lash and Urry 1994:279), 'new
regionalist' theories highlighted several overlapping factors behind this development: state
restructuring or 'hollowing out' (Jessop 1992); a move away from the Fordist mode of
accumulation to one based on 'flexible specialisation or accumulation' (Harvey 1989; Piore and
Sabel 1983; 1984; Scott and Storper 1987); accelerated European integration including a new
'multilevel' policy-making style with greater input from the regions (Marks 1993; 1997; Marks et
al. 1996). In this new scenario traditional conceptions of nation-state sovereignty became
redundant as goals for territorial political movements, which led some scholars to consider substate nationalism as a subcategory of regionalism (Keating 1996). This is not to say that a
distinct cultural identity is not considered important; rather it became a means of developing the
kind of social solidarity that helped in the production and reproduction of social goods, while
helping such regions to market themselves as special places to live, work, invest and visit.
So does globalisation reduce nations and nationalism to expressions of impotency? Or on the
contrary, does it favour the rise of historic, sub-state nations? Or are expressions of national
belonging left unchanged by the historical shallowness of the kind of alternatives that
globalisation offers in terms of identity? In order to address such questions, this paper focuses
on the political economy of globalisation, since changes in economic organisation would appear
to be the main dynamic behind the phenomenon in general, having a direct impact on the
3
nation-state and thus on nationalism as a form of political mobilisation around the nation-state.
Hence, the starting point of this paper consists of understanding the driving force behind
globalisation to be the deterritorialising logic of capitalist accumulation. From the basic premise
that capitalism is inherently prone to crisis of overaccumulation, Harvey suggests that, as a
means of overcoming or postponing such crises, the history of capitalism has been marked by
‘successive waves of time-space compression generated out of the pressures of capital
accumulation with its perpetual search to annihilate space through time and reduce turn over
time’ (Harvey 1989:306-7). He forcefully argues that the last two decades have been witness to
a particularly savage bout of time-space compression, which has led to the emergence of
networks of production, distribution, marketing and consumption of goods and services on an
increasingly global scale.
Nations and nationalism, on the other hand, can also be understood spatially, although unlike
globalisation, they are very much linked to the fixity of territory: the most significant claim made
by nationalists on behalf of the nation - in political terms at least – concerns the exercise of
political power over a given space. In order to justify such claims, the nation is conceived as
being intimately bound up with ‘its’ territory.
Overall it can be argued that as increasingly global networks of capitalist accumulation emerge
that transcend contemporary territorial configurations of power and identity, such as the nationstate, so they accrue structural power, the power of movement, over territorial fixity, thus
undermining the bases for nationalist territorial mobilisation. However, if we are to fully
understand the complex interrelationship between globalization and nationalism, then we must
avoid establishing a crude opposition between the respective logics of state territoriality and
capitalist accumulation. From an empirical point of view, states themselves have played an
important historical role in the global expansion of capitalism, while in the contemporary world
nation-states continue to be relevant actors and the focus of political mobilisation, suggesting
that we should not overstate the scope and scale of current globalisation. From a theoretical
perspective, although deterritorialisation is key to understanding globalisation, there are sound
4
reasons for arguing that territory can never be completely overcome, and that deterritorialisation
must necessarily be accompanied by the process of reterritorialisation, whereby different spatial
scales may retain or even increase their importance as the context in which social relations take
place. Finally, the paper argues that rather than reifying globalisation and nationalism as ‘out
there’ phenomena that operate independently of each other, a dialectical approach that involves
detailed analysis of specific spatial and historical contexts is more useful as a means of
understanding the interrelatedness of globalisation and the different forms of nationalist political
mobilisation taking place in such contexts.
The State and Globalisation in Historical Perspective
Overstating the novelty of contemporary globalisation, and the extent to which it is destined to
transcend the nation-state, rather obviates the contributions of distinguished scholars (Arrighi
1994; Braudel 1982; Mann 1986; 1993; Tilly 1990; Wallerstein 1974) to the question of the
related rise of capitalism as a world system of accumulation on the one hand, and the modern
state and the world system of states, on the other. Historically, there is a clear temporal
coincidence between these two phenomena, suggesting that even though they might function
according to different spatial logics at an abstract level, there actually exists a more dialectical
relationship of mutual influence. Indeed, Wallerstein argues that ‘capitalism has been able to
flourish precisely because the world economy has had within its bounds not one but a
multiplicity of political systems’ (Wallerstein 1974:348). In turn, this is explained by the view that
states, on the one hand, have competed for mobile capital, while, on the other, capitalist groups
have sought to mobilise their respective states in order to gain competitive advantages in the
world economy. A relatively recent addition to this literature is the acclaimed account by
Giovanni Arrighi (1994), Long Twentieth Century: Money, Power and the Origin of Our Times,
which offers a slightly more nuanced approach to the question. In the Preface the author
comments that his original aim was to understand current developments of the capitalist world
system within the context of the development of capitalism dating back to the end of the
5
nineteenth century. His thesis is that just as a the late nineteenth century saw the decline of a
British-dominated cycle of capitalist development in favour of a new cycle dominated by the
United States, so the 1980's had begun to witness the decline of the latter and the potential rise
of Japanese and East Asian hegemony. However, following Braudel,
the long twentieth century now appeared as the latest of four similarly structured long
centuries, each constituting a particular stage of development of the world capitalist
system. It became clear to me that a comparative analysis of these successive long
centuries could reveal more about the dynamic and likely future outcome of the present
crisis than an in-depth analysis of the long twentieth century as such (Arrighi 1994:x).
Subsequently, he identifies the Venetian, the Dutch (United Provinces), the British and the US
'long centuries', during each of which the scale and scope of the global capitalist system
increased. However, beyond the differences and similarities between these cycles, Arrighi
makes a very clear statement with regards the relationship between capitalism and the state,
namely that the expansion of capitalism and state power are two very closely related processes
that require explanation.
Arrighi’s point of departure is that capitalism is not synonymous with the market economy and
nor is state power antithetical to capitalism. Rather, historically capitalism is ‘absolutely
dependent for its emergence and expansion on state power and constitut[es] the antithesis of
the market economy’ (Arrighi 1994:10). More specifically, capitalism is presented as a threetiered structure: on the bottom is the tier of subsistence, the elementary and self-sufficient
economy in which capitalism ultimately takes root. Above this tier,
comes the favoured terrain of the market economy, with its many horizontal
communications between the different markets […] Then alongside, or rather above this
layer, comes the zone of the anti-market, where the great predators roam and the law of
the jungle operates. This – today as in the past, before and after the industrial revolution
6
– is the real home of capitalism. (Braudel 1982:229-230, quoted in Arrighi 1994:10)
This second tier of the market economy, Arrighi argues, had been in existence since at least the
thirteenth century, and connected Europe, Asia and Africa on well-worn trade routes. Thus, from
this perspective, the important historical transition is not from feudalism to capitalism, but rather
what he calls from ‘scattered to concentrated capitalist power. And the most important aspect of
this much neglected transition is the unique fusion of state and capital, which was realized
nowhere more favourably for capitalism than in Europe’ (Arrighi 1994:10).
This is not to say that state power is indistinguishable from capitalism, nor that the two operate
according to necessarily complimentary logics: the power of the state ultimately depends on its
ability to achieve exclusive control over a delimited space known as territory, which may or may
not coincide in its spatial extent with networks of capitalist accumulation. Thus, according to
Arrighi, ‘in our account, the division of the world-economy into competing jurisdictions does not
necessarily benefit the capitalist accumulation of capital’. (Arrighi 1994:32). In this context, the
role of the hegemonic power in any one age is to reconcile the ‘recurrent contradiction between
an 'endless' accumulation of capital and a comparatively stable organization of political space’
(Arrighi 1994:33).
From this perspective, how can we understand contemporary globalisation and its effects on the
nation-state? The first thing to mention here is that contemporary globalisation has been marked
by the rising importance of speculative financial capitalism vis-à-vis capitalist investment in fixed
assets, which historically has tended to reflect the end of a 'long century' of hegemony, in this
case of the US. If we are witnessing the passing of an era, what will replace the US in its role as
hegemonic power within the world system? Historically, previous hegemonic powers
appear to have been great powers of a different and increasing order […] the
metropolitan domains of each state in this sequence encompass a larger territory and a
greater variety of resources than their predecessor. More importantly, the networks of
7
power and accumulation that enabled the states in question to reorganize and control the
world system within which they operated grew in scale and scope as the sequence
progresses. (Arrighi 1994:14)
Thus, if historical trends, as identified by Arrighi, continue, two potential scenarios emerge. The
first is that a new hegemonic power will emerge, more powerful than its predecessors, to fulfil
the role of reconciling global capitalist accumulation with the existence of territorially fixed
political jurisdictions in the shape of nation states. At the time of writing, Arrighi focussed on the
rise of Japan as the potential new hegemonic power, although hindsight tells us that this
potential has been unfulfilled. China would be the current candidate to fill this role, especially if
we take into account its enormous population and the growth potential that this would seem to
imply. However, like Japan in the 1980s and unlike previous transitions, US financial capital is
not flowing into China to take advantage of its increasing importance as a manufacturing centre.
Rather the reverse is true: the Chinese authorities have been generating huge current-account
surpluses that have been invested in the US, principally in Treasury bonds, which means that
US consumers have been effectively financed by the Chinese authorities.
This apparent break with history opens the door for a second scenario in which US hegemony
represents the last attempt by a particular state at governing the world system. Such has been
the global expansion of capitalist accumulation in recent years, it could be argued, that no single
state has the capacity to be hegemonic and perform the role of reconciling such accumulation
with the continued existence of a political order of nation-states. In such a scenario, a world
government, in one form or another, would be the only solution. Indeed, Arrighi himself talks of
the increasingly important role of the IMF, World Bank and other multilateral organisations of
governance such as the G8.
If we view both scenarios as extremes on a continuum, the space between can be seen as
being occupied by more complex scenarios in which state sovereignty becomes more diffuse,
but not to the point where it ceases to exist, and in this respect the current financial crisis is
8
instructive. On the one hand, the crisis has revealed the size of global, or at least transnational,
markets for financial products such as credit derivatives. These markets, whose turnover
represents trillions of dollars, have largely grown parallel to more traditional financial markets for
stocks, currencies and so forth, and as such are unregulated by nation-states. However, on the
other, states have rarely been more active in economic terms over the last three decades,
whether setting up banks for 'toxic' assets, nationalising individual banks, propping up the
financial system, or stimulating consumption as a means of overcoming the crisis. More
generally, states have become key actors and spaces of conflict as the struggle begins to 'share
out' the huge losses accruing from collapsing asset prices.
Whatever the outcome of the current financial and economic crisis, we should not forget that the
modern state and capitalism have been intertwined for almost five centuries, and as such, the
existence of increasingly global networks of capitalist accumulation does not necessarily mean
that there is no need for state institutions, acting on the ground, to guarantee the conditions for
that accumulation.
The Modern State and Contemporary Globalisation: an
empirical analysis
Towards Economic Integration: some data
One of the assumptions that informed the preceding discussion was that economic activity is
now increasingly organised in transnational networks of capital accumulation, and that such
networks enjoy structural power over nation-state attempts to regulate them. Turning to the first
claim, by almost any measure, the extent to which economic activity is increasingly organised
transnationally is difficult to ignore. As Table 1 demonstrates, cross-border trade in goods and
services has in increased notably in recent years as a proportion of world GDP, affecting all
categories of nation-state economies, from low-income ones to high-income ones. The increase
in merchandise trade is particularly marked in the case of middle-income economies, such as
9
China and Brazil.
Table 1: Global Economic Integration
Merchandise
Trade in
services
trade
% GDP
% GDP
1995
23.6
Low income
34.5
Middle income
32.3
High income
32.3
World
Source: World Bank (2006)
2005
41.1
62.1
43.9
47.3
1995
6.2
7.1
7.9
7.8
2005
9.8
10.5
11.1
11.0
Gross
private
capital flows
% GDP
1995 2005
2.4
6.7
6.6
13.3
11.0
37.2
10.3
32.4
Foreign direct investment
% GDP
net inflows
net outflows
1995
0.4
0.9
1.0
1.0
2005
1.5
3.1
2.1
2.2
1995
0.0
0.1
1.4
1.2
2005
0.2
0.5
2.4
2.1
Furthermore, foreign direct investment – both inflows and outflows – have doubled in the same
period, and again the rise is significant for middle-income countries, although as Figure 1 and 2
show, such flows continue to be concentrated in developed economies.
Figure 1. FDI inflows by economy, 2002-2007 (billions of
US$)
2000
1800
1600
1400
1200
Developed Economies
1000
Developing economies
800
600
400
200
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
year
10
2007
Figure 2. FDI outflows by economy, 2002-2007 (billions
US$)
2500
2000
1500
Developed Economies
Developing economies
1000
500
0
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
A further measure of increased economic integration concerns the ownership of shares. Share
ownership has also become increasingly transnational over the last decade or so: in 1995
eleven per cent of French stock market shares were in the hands of foreign investors, eight per
cent in the cases of the US and Japan, while just four per cent of British shares were under
foreign ownership (The Economist 1997). By 2003 the figure had risen to 34.8 per cent for the
case of France, ten per cent for US, 23.7 per cent for Japan, 32.3 per cent for the UK (Edwards
2006). Indeed, perhaps one of the most important dimensions of contemporary economic
globalisation has been the rising importance of transnational financial markets and actors.
Figure 3 shows the six-fold increase in the turnover of currency markets over the last two
decades, most of which is due to speculative finance, rather than to cover increases in world
trade.
11
Figure 3. Global foreign exchange market turnover1 (daily
averages in April) 1989-2007
3500
3000
2500
2000
Billions US$
1500
1000
500
0
1989
1992
1995
1998
2001
2004
2007
1
Includes spot transactions, forwards and swaps of up to seven days.
Source: BIS (2002; 2007)
Persistent nation-state divergence
Overall, as noted, it is difficult to ignore what appear to be very clear trends towards economic
activity being increasingly organised as a transnational level, but does this necessarily mean
that nation-states have lost the power to regulate? A common argument, used by academics,
politicians and journalists alike, is that nation-states have indeed lost economic sovereignty and
as a result are obliged to embark on a neo-liberal race to the bottom (NLRTB), that is, to
converge macro- and micro-economic policy around low wages, low taxes, low public spending
(particularly on social policies) and low deficits in order to attract 'footloose' capital flows and
investment. Garret (1998) has produced a most interesting empirical and theoretical critique of
such predictions by examining the empirical evidence from OECD countries. Official data
suggests that between 1960 and the mid-1990’s, government spending basically doubled as a
percentage of GDP in OECD countries, with significant differences persisting and even
12
emerging between countries. Public spending deficits also rose over the period studied, as did
tax rates on capital: 'the overall trend in effective rates of capital taxation has been upward,
quite strongly so' (Garret 1998:818). Again comparing trends across countries, there is little to
suggest convergence on deficit stances or on capital taxation rates. By the beginning of the
present decade, more evidence was found among advanced capitalist economies for 'a trend
toward lower inflation rates and smaller budget deficits', particularly among EU countries
seeking to comply with the Maastricht criteria for access to the Euro, although ‘substantial
cross-national diversity remains in areas such government consumption spending, government
transfer payments, public employment, and public taxation’ (Mosely 2007:112).
Thus, the analysis presented here would appear to belie the proposition that globalisation
inevitably forces states to adopt similar low-tax, low-spending economic policies, with all that
that implies. Of course, it could be argued that the lack of economic policy convergence in the
terms described here is due to a lack of market integration, thus it could be argued that when
this process of integration is complete, as it inevitably will be, predictions about the neo-liberal
race to the bottom will be fulfilled. However, once more empirical evidence casts doubt on such
an hypothesis: in the case of the United States, where there exists no effective barriers to the
movement of capital across state lines, tax rates were in fact more divergent between the fifty
states of the USA than between the countries of the OECD.
This suggests a rather more complex rationale for the location of FDI than simply criteria based
on lowest costs. One the one hand, Krugman (1998) highlights the importance of productivity in
TNC calculations, as opposed to raw costs, while on the other, FDI decisions are increasingly
aimed at gaining access to markets, especially in developed capitalist states, and as such
location decisions go beyond criteria of costs of production. Even where TNCs decide to locate
production facilities in lower-wage countries, Garret argues that this does not necessarily mean
that business activity at ‘home’ is reduced, as there might be an increasing specialisation in key
functions, such as R&D, in the country of origin. Overall, Garret concludes that decisions
concerning the location of production sights will be the fruit of cost benefit analyses, in which
13
economies with high levels of government spending may benefit, if such spending is
accompanied by high productivity rates, high human and capital stocks and political stability. He
finds very little correlation between FDI outflows and government spending levels, budget deficit
positions and capital taxation levels, suggesting that nation-state governments have more
autonomy in this respect than is predicted by many.
In terms of the possible effects of more integrated financial markets on nation-state political and
economic autonomy, Garret concludes that ‘there is no evidence that the financial markets
attach interest premiums to the expansion of the public economy per se’ (Garret 1998:823), as
long as such expansion is financed by taxes and not by running a deficit, which would seem to
increase the interest rates charged by the markets on loans to government, while provoking
currency devaluations in the market. However, this must be qualified by evidence from two
European countries: Belgium has financed public spending through debt to the extent that, in
terms of GDP, it has the highest ratio of public indebtedness to GDP among OECD countries.
However, until its absorption into the Euro the Belgium franc had ‘long been stably pegged
against the deutsche mark, with very small interest-rate differentials between the two countries’
(Garret 1998:804). Similar conclusions can be reached in the case of Italy.
Overall, if globalisation implies a significant increase in economic activity on a transnational
scale, then empirical evidence leaves little doubt that this is an important feature of the
contemporary world. However, this does not necessarily mean that globalisation necessarily
forces nation-states to merely serve the interests of transnational networks of capitalist
accumulation; among developed economies at least, persistent macro-economic policy
divergence suggests that internal socio-economic and political considerations are important
components in shaping nation-state macro-economic policies, which in turn leads us to question
the extent to which the socio-economic dimension of state sovereignty is really a thing of the
past.
14
Deterritorialisation and Reterritorialisation
As we have seen, to the extent that capitalist accumulation is increasingly said to take place on
a global scale, it signifies deterritorialisation. ‘Deterritorialization’, Ó Tauthail proposes, ‘is the
name given to the problematic of territory losing its significance and power in everyday life.
Territory, the concept suggests, is no longer the stable and unquestioned actuality it once was.
Rather than an assumed given, its position and status is now in question’ (Ó Tuathail 1999:139).
It has come about, it is argued, ‘as a consequence of the technological, material and
geopolitical transformations of the late twentieth century’ (ibid.) which threatens to overcome the
exercise of territorial political power and territorially-based identities.
However, deterritorialisation must not be seen as an absolute process for there are sound
theoretical reasons for arguing that territory can never be completely done away with, and that
deterritorialisation must necessarily be accompanied by the process of reterritorialisation. In this
respect, Robins, for example, talks about globalisation as the ‘achievement of a new global-local
nexus, about new and intricate relations between global space and local space’ (Robins
1991:34-35), and from this point of departure, several factors have been identified that, taken
together, would appear to add up to an increased degree of salience for sub-state regions as
spaces of governance with respect to nation states.
The first factor concerns changing modes of territorial management in advanced capitalist
democracies since the 1980s, which came about through wider changes in the way in which
states regulate capitalism, and is generally referred to a state restructuring. This process of
state restructuring took place after a period in which for some the nation-state reached its
golden era in the form of the policy instruments of the Welfare State, ‘under which collective
bargaining and monopoly pricing were institutionalized, policy instruments were deployed to
maintain and manage aggregate demand, and norms of mass consumption ... were generalized’
(Peck and Tickell 1994:289). In this respect, it is argued that the importance of the state rested
15
on its role as a means of correcting market dysfunction and, above all, of maintaining stable,
increasing levels of internal demand, a vital consideration for a regime of accumulation,
Fordism, which was based on mass production, consumption and productivity gains derived
from economies of scale (see, for example, Aglietta 1979; Boyer 1986). As part of this system of
social regulation, central governments began to turn their attention to regional development
policies in the form of grants, subsidies and transfer payments to encourage the formation of
satellite economies in the ‘periphery’. The ‘purpose was simply to make central planning more
efficient and was thus an extension of the central state’s power and had no necessary
connection with decentralization or popular participation’ (Sharpe 1993:13).
The crisis of the Fordist-Keynesian mode of regulation of the 1970’s and 1980’s led central
governments to abandon their commitment to social and territorial wealth redistribution. In the
context of the emerging global economic order, Western nation-states increasingly turned away
from demand-management policies in favour of supply-side policies that sought to promote
overall levels of competitiveness independently of the consequences for the territorial
distribution of wealth (Jessop 1992). In terms of territorial management, the strategy of the
carrot and stick was applied, whereby
the stick was a reduction of subsidies to distressed firms and social welfare and
vocational benefits for displaced workers. The carrot was partial devolution of authority
over vocational training, economic development, and social welfare programmes to local
or regional authorities. (Sabel 1994:127).
Within this context, Keating talks of how ‘policies and institutions for governing regions became
increasingly contested’ (Keating 1996:24), as the impact of economic globalisation began to be
felt. With the retreat of the state from territorial management, in many cases it was left to the
individual regions to develop their own economic strategies in the face of the demands made by
a globalising economy, and regionalist movements no longer framed their demands solely within
the context of the nation-state: ‘the context for the new regionalism is not merely, as in the past,
16
the nation state; it is the continental, and even global economy’ (Keating 1996:25).
State restructuring fed into what can be considered as a paradigm shift in economic
organisation, from a Fordist regime of accumulation, which as we have seen was based on
economies of scale and mass production, to ‘flexible specialisation’ or ‘flexible accumulation’. As
turn-over times were reduced, so greater emphasis was placed on the ability to respond to everchanging market demands – flexibility – a characteristic of small- to medium-sized forms.
Studies began to emerge from central and north-eastern Italy highlighting the setting up of an
economy based on hi-tech, flexible workshops and small firms 1 . However, such firms on their
own are unlikely to be able to meet the costs involved of constant innovation and training, nor
the size required to achieve minimal economies of scale. Consequently,
Firms had a low degree of vertical integration and depended on each other for a wide
range of specialised activities. A dense system of subcontracting lay at the heart of the
local economy. The ‘extraordinarily rich and complex relationship’ (Brusco 1989: 261)
between clients [...] and subcontractors [...] kindled innovation and enhanced adaptability.
[...] Collaboration went further. Firms passed on orders to each other and shared in the
costs of expensive equipment. They pooled their resources to set up local associations of
specialists for the collective provision of marketing, accounting and technical services
(Kumar 1995:39).
At the same time, a whole range of public and semi-public regional institutions were created,
such as development agencies, training and research facilities, and marketing agencies, as a
means of providing individual firms with the necessary services that, on their own, the latter
would be incapable of supplying.
Post-Fordist theories of endogenous development and the resurgence of industrial districts are
essentially based on networks of co-operation and collaboration between small firms and TNC
filières, semi-public development agencies etc., characterised, above all, by the sharing of
17
resources and in particular information. For these actors to collaborate and co-operate in this
way, trust is vital, and in order to generate multiple sources of trust, social solidarity, based upon
a series of factors, from shared professional experiences to shared ethnic and linguistic
identities, must be present. In the case of the Third Italy, a new kind of ‘social compromise’
based on the various local subcultures - Socialist and Communist in the central regions and
Catholic in the north-east has been fostered (Kumar, 1995: 39).
Post-Fordist theories of regional development bring us full circle back to theories of regionalism.
The important thing to note here is the positive role which place-based culture can have in
generating public goods such as trust. In addition, cultural distinctiveness may also be useful as
a ‘a resource, giving a region a specific niche in the international market place’ (Keating, 1996:
32), which is particularly important at a time when regions and localities must increasingly
compete for scarce resources such as inward investment, or to become important sites of tourist
consumption. Harvey (1993), for example, notes that more often than not, local consensus is
achieved between representatives of capital and labour, together with representatives of local
and regional political institutions, interested in saving or creating jobs and businesses
respectively. Thus, in many cases cross-class coalitions are established, allowing us to talk of
local/regional mobilisation that may seek to highlight the unique advantages of investing in the
particular place, that may go beyond the strictly economic factors to include other distinguishing
local features such as distinct cultural identity. Thus, in this new scenario, communities that are
relatively fixed in place seek to attract productive investments by presenting themselves as
‘business friendly’ environments, offering well-trained, well-disciplined workforces, local/regional
institutional support, good physical infrastructures, and even pleasant places for top
management to live. At the same time, places might also seek to become sites of consumption,
to attract, for example tourists to ‘historic sites’, ‘cultural centres, a pleasing urban or regional
landscape and the like’ (Harvey 1993:8).
18
The Dialectics of Globalisation and Nationalism
Beyond questions of whether the Fordist post-Fordist paradigm is a useful framework to analyse
the development of capitalism over recent decades 2 , the question arises as to the balance of
power between these emerging spaces of economic regulation and transnational economic
networks and flows. In this respect, Harvey (1993) opposes space and place, in which the
former is increasingly dominated by capital flows, while the latter are examples of fixity and
immobility; and Castells talks of the new ‘Information Age’ characterised by the struggle
between the fixity of ‘spaces of places’ against the mobility of ‘spaces of flows’, or in terms of the
‘disjunction between the local and the global’ (Castells 1997:11. See also Ruggie 1993).
In practice, and returning to the the subject of regional economic, political and social
development, while it is clear that some regions have indeed prospered, it is less apparent that
all regions can be ‘winners’ at the same time, and as such regional and local prosperity under
conditions of globalisation might be better considered as a zero-sum game in which they may
resort to ‘beggar-thy-neighbour strategies’ (Peck and Tickell 1994:281) in order to attract and
retain investment. Indeed, rather than promoting difference,
what is striking about local strategies is just how unlocal they are. Workforce training, the
erosion of social protection, the construction of science and business parks, the vigorous
marketing of place and the ritual incantation of the virtues of international competitiveness
and public-private partnership seem now to have become almost universal features of socalled ‘local’ strategies (Peck and Tickell 1994:281).
In effect it is a question of asymmetry, local versus local versus global. Thus, many see the
whole idea of regional economies based on flexible specialisation as the means by which capital
avoids the rigidities of Fordism and secondly plays region off against region (see Swyngedouw
1992; Harvey 1989; and Dunford and Kafkalas 1992). Thus, in a world in which global spaces
are dominated by the needs of capital accumulation,
19
the global-local nexus does not create a privileged new role for the locality in the world
economic arena. Of course local economies continue to matter [...] We should however,
treat claims about new capacities for local autonomy and proactivity with scepticism. If it
is, indeed, the case that localities do now increasingly bypass the national state to deal
directly with global corporations, world bodies or foreign governments, they do not do so
on equal terms. Whether it is to attract a new car factory or the Olympic Games, they go
as supplicants. And, even as supplicants, they go in competition with each other: cities
and localities are now fiercely struggling against each other to attract footloose and
predatory investors to their particular patch (Robins 1991:36).
These positions offer a timely reminder of the structural limits to place-based economic and
political developments, but does this necessarily mean that we should ignore place-based
strategies when trying to explain outcomes related to globalisation? Ash Amin thinks not:
to think of the global flows of dominance and transformation and the local as fixities of
tradition and continuity is to miss the point, because it denies the interaction between the two
as well as the evolutionary logics of both. Thus, for example, whether a city or nation is
threatened or not by globalization is likely to depend upon the terms of interaction between
evolving ‘in here’ identities and capabilities and ‘out there’ influences, rather than upon the
capacity of the city or nation to avoid global connection or ‘contamination’. Thus a place in a
world of ‘stretched and deepened’ time-space connectivity might now be more a matter of
how this connectivity is negotiated or worked to your advantage, rather than resisted or kept
out. (Amin 1997:129-130).
Amin, I think, is right in two respects: first, in that he proposes that we see the relationship
between globalisation and place as an interaction, rather than granting causality exclusively to
the former. Second, outcomes are consequently said to depend on individual place-based
strategies, which effectively accords agency to place-based actors, such as local political and
economic elites. However, we should not underestimate the power of structural changes in the
20
scale of economic activity to construct the limits within which these actors operate. In other
words, global actors have increasingly set the rules within which local strategies must fit, as
when the latter are made to depend on the attraction of investment flows. But if we do bare in
mind thisqualification, then the points Amin makes can be used to construct a dialectical
approach, capable of understanding questions of not only of structure and agency, but also of
how politics, culture and ethnicity, for example, essentially interact with economic processes,
such as globalisation 3 . At the same time, this interaction does not take place in a vacuum, but
rather in specific temporal and spatial contexts, hence understanding these contexts is central
to any analysis of globalisation and nationalism. Thus, we might wish to analyse the nature of
local economic structures, and the role of politics, ideology and ethnicity, for example, in the
reproduction of them or resistance to them within the context of globalisation.
Concluding Remarks
This paper has sought to qualify the proposition that globalisation necessarily implies greater
power for global networks of capital accumulation over territorial strategies of power and the
political mobilisation that takes place around them. These arguments are aimed at merely
suggesting the basis of an approach to the question of the relationship between globalisation
and nationalism. Perhaps the most important conclusion to be drawn is that globalisation,
whose inherent logic is deterritorialising, and political power based on and mobilised around
territory, such as nationalism, ultimately exist in a dialectical relationship of mutual influence.
Current globalisation may in part be the result of the structural needs of capitalism to overcome
its crises of overaccumulation, but at the same time, globalisation itself has been shaped by
state policies – neoliberal deregulation, for example – and territorial political mobilisation, which
in turn must operate in the changing environment of capitalist accumulation. Globalisation is a
spatially and socially uneven process, or set of processes, and as such, in order to capture the
different ways in which transnational actors and processes interact with a particular form of
place-based political mobilisation – in this case nationalism - we might be advised to talk of
21
nationalisms in the plural as a means of recognising the fact that how different groups interact
with globalisation will depend on, for example, the political, economic and ideological resources
available to them, and on struggles for power in those places To place all nationalist movements
in the single category of ‘nationalism’ rather reduces our analysis to a necessarily general
discussion of abstract categories, a discussion which by its very nature would be incapable of
understanding the impact of each on the other, precisely because it fails to deal with specific
historical and spatial contexts within which the two come together.
22
Notes
1
For a good overview of such work, see Kumar (1995).
2
Jessop, among others, is rather sceptical about the extent to which Fordism, understood as a mode of
production, regime of accumulation, regime of regulation and even a mode of societalization, existed
outside certain sectors of the economy and outside of certain territorial limits. For example, in the paradigm
industry of Fordism, automobiles, outside certain US and French manufacturers ‘several recent studies
demonstrate how Fordist mass production has been blocked (in this sector) by such factors as skill
structure, managerial capacities, market size, labour market conditions, and union organization’ (Jessop
1992:54). See also Amin and Robins (1990) and Cooke and Morgan (1995).
3
This dialectical approach has been developed by Jim MacLaughlin (1986; 2001), although applied to the
emergence of nationalism, particularly in Ireland, in the nineteenth century.
23
References
Aglietta, M. 1979. A Theory of Capitalist Regulation: the US Experience. London: New Left
Books.
Amin, Ash. 1997. “Placing Globalization”, Theory, Culture & Society 14, 2: 123-137.
Amin, Ash and Robins, Kevin. 1990. “The re-emergence of regional economies? The mythical
geography of flexible accumulation”, Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 8: 7-34.
Appadurai, Arjun. 1996. Modernity at Large. Cultural Dimensions of Globalization. Minneapolis:
University of Minnesota Press.
Arrighi, Giovanni. 1994. The Long Twentieth Century. Money, Power, and the Origins of Our
Times. London: Verso.
BIS (Bank for International Settlements). 2002. Triennial Central Bank Survey: Foreign
Exchange derivatives market activity in 2001. Basel: BIS.
BIS (Bank for International Settlements). 2007. Triennial Central Bank Survey: Foreign
Exchange derivatives market activity in 2007. Basel: BIS.
Boyer, Robert. 1986. La Théorie de la Regulation: une analyse critique. Paris: La Découverte.
Braudel, Fernand. 1982. The Wheels of Commerce. New York: Harper and Row.
Castells, Manuel. 1997. The Power of Identity. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
24
Cooke, Philip and Morgan, Kevin. 1994. “Growth Regions under Duress: Renewal Strategies in
Baden Württemberg and Emilia-Romagna”, in Ash Amin and Nigel Thrift (eds.), Globalization,
Institutions and Regional Development in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Dunford, Mick and Kafkalas, Grigoris. 1992. “The global-local interplay, corporate geographies
and spatial development strategies in Europe”, in Dunford and Kafkalas (eds.) Cities and
Regions in the New Europe: the Global-Local Interplay and Spatial Development Strategies.
London: Belhaven.
Edwards, T. Huw. 2006. “International Share Ownership, Profit Shift and Protectionism”.
Discussion Paper Series, Dept. of Economics, Loughborough University. Available online at:
http://econpapers.repec.org/paper/lbolbowps/2006_5f15.htm
Friedman, Jonathan. 1994. Cultural Identity and Global Process. London, Thousand Oaks, New
Delhi: Sage.
Garret, Geoffrey. 1998. “Global Markets and National Politics: Collision Course or Vicious
Circle?”, International Organization, 52, 4: 787-824.
Harvey, David. 1989. The Condition of Postmodenity: An Enquiry into the Origins of Cultural
Change. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Harvey, David. 1993. “From Space to Place and Back Again: Reflections on the condition of
postmodernity ” in John Bird et al. (eds.), Mapping the Futures: local culture, global change.
London: Routledge.
Hirst, Paul and Thompson, Graham. 1996. Globalization in Question. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Jessop, Bob. 1992. “Fordism and post-Fordism: a critical reformulation”, in Michael Storper and
25
Allen John Scott (eds.), Pathways to Industrialization and Regional Development. London:
Routledge.
Kaldor, Mary. 1996. “Cosmopolitanism Versus Nationalism: The New Divide?”, in Richard
Caplan and John Feffer (eds.), Europe’s New Nationalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Keating, Michael. 1988. The State and Regional Nationalism. Territorial Politics and the
European State. New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Keating, Michael. 1996. “The Political Economy of Regionalism”, in Michael Keating and John
Loughlin (eds.), The Political Economy of Regionalism. London: Frank Cass.
Krugman, Paul. 1998. ‘What’s New About The New Economic Geography?’ Oxford Review of
Economic Policy, 14, 2: 7-17.
Kumar, Krishan. 1995. From Post-Industrial to Post-Modern Society: New Theories of the
Contemporary World. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Lash, Scott and Urry, John. 1994. Economies of Signs and Space. London: Sage.
Mac Laughlin, Jim. 1986 “The political geography of ‘nation-building’ and nationalism in social
sciences: structural vs. dialectical accounts”, Political Geography Quarterly, 5, 4: 299-329
Mac Laughlin, Jim. 2001. Reimagining the Nation-State: the Contested Terrains of
Nationbuilding. London, Pluto Press.
Mann, Michael. 1986. The Sources of Social Power: Volume 1, A History of Power from the
Beginning to AD 1760. Cambridge University Press.
26
Mann, Michael. 1993. The Sources of Social Power: Volume 2, The Rise of Classes and Nation
States 1760-1914. Cambridge University Press.
Marks, Gary. 1993. “Structural Policy and Mulilevel Governance in the European Community”, in
Alan Cafruny and Glenda Rosenthal (eds.), The State of the European Community. Essex:
Longman.
Marks, Gary. 1997. “An Actor-Centred Approach to Multi-level Governance” in Charlie Jeffery,
(ed.) The Regional Dimension of the European Union. Towards a Third Level in Europe?
London: Frank Cass.
Marks, G.ary et al. 1996. “European Integration from the 1980s: State-Centric v. Multi-level
Governance”, Journal of Common Market Studies, 34, 3: 341-378.
Mosely, Layna. (2007) “The Political Economy of Globalisation”, in David Held and Anthony
McGrew (eds.), Globalization Theory: Approaches and Controversies. Cambridge: Polity Press.
Ó
Tuathail,
Gearoid.
2000.
Borderless
Worlds?
Problematizing
Discourses
of
Deterritorialization. Geopolitics, 4: 139-154.
Peck, Jamie and Tickell, Adam. 1994. “Searching for a New Institutional Fix: the After-Fordist
Crisis and the Global-Local Disorder”, in Ash Amin (ed.), Post-Fordism: a Reader. Oxford: Basil
Blackwell.
Piore, M. and Sabel, C. 1983. “Italian Small Business Development: Lessons for US Industrial
Policy”, in Zysman, J. and Tyson, L. (eds.) American Industry In International Competition:
Government Policies and Corporate Strategies. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Piore, Michael and Sabel, Charles. 1984. The Second Industrial Divide. New York: Basic Books.
27
Robins, Kevin. 1991. “Tradition and translation: national culture in its global context” in John
Corner and Silvia Harvey (eds.), Enterprise and Heritage: crosscurrents of national culture.
London: Routledge.
Ruggie, John. G. 1993. “Territoriality and Beyond: problematizing modernity international
relations”, International Organization, 47, 1: 139-174.
Sabel, Charles. 1994. “Flexible Specialisation and the Re-emergence of Regional Economies”,
in Ash Amin (ed.), Post-fordism: a reader. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Scott, Allen, J. and Storper, Michael. (987. “High Technology Industry and Regional
Development: a Theoretical Critique and Reconstruction”, International Social Science Journal,
112: 215-232.
Sharpe, L. Jim.1993. The Rise of Meso Government in Europe. London: Sage.
Smith, A. D. 1995. Nations and Nationalism in the Global Era. London: Polity Press.
Swyngedouw, Erik. 1992. “The Mammon quest. Glocalisation, interspatial competition and the
monetary order: the construction of new scales”, in Mick Dunford and Grigoris Kafkalas, (eds.),
Cities and Regions in the New Europe: the Global-Local Interplay and Spatial Development
Strategies. London: Belhaven.
Tilly, Charles. 1990. Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1990. Oxford: Basil
Blackwell.
Tomlinson, John. 1999. Globalization and Culture. Cambridge: Polity Press.
28
Wallerstein, Immanuel. 1974. The Modern World System I. Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins
of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century. New York: Academic Press.
World Bank. 2007. World Development Indicators 2007.Washington D.C.: World Bank
29