Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
169 Suomi, Reima (2006) Evaluating Network Externalities. In Remenyi, Dan –Brown, Ann (editors) Proceedings of the 13th European Conference on Information Technology Evaluation (ECITE), Genova, Italy 27-29.9.2006, 437-442. ISBN 978-1-905305-32-2 (print), 978-1-905305-34-6 (cd). EVALUATING NETWORK EXTERNALITIES Reima Suomi Turku School of Economics Abstract Networks externalties, both positive and negative, are known to be part of every network. Positive network externalities are the main reason for building networks, and a primary source of wealth for the modern society, often actually called the networked society. Network externalities stemming from telecommunication networks are a primary source of wealth in the information society. This article discusses what kind of networks we have in the society, what network externalities are, and in which varieties they exist. Further the article draws some initial ideas on how network externalities could be measured. The article identifies four major problems in network externality measurement: the stakeholder problem, the identification problem, the arbitrator problem and the measure problem. Introduction Network externality has been defined as a change in the benefit, or surplus, that an agent derives from a good when the number of other agents consuming the same kind of good changes (Liebowitz & Margolis). According to a recent research, network externalities are on of the 10 key forces that drive information technology to the society (Andal-Ancion, 2003). For economists, the theory of network externalities, or network externalities, or standardization, has wide applicability. Indeed, it has fundamental importance for competition policy, regulation, business strategy, intellectual property, and technical change in a wide range of industries; developments in these industries cannot be fully understood without an understanding of network externalities (Besen). Network effect are a popular and important theoretical concept, yet very much neglected by the information systems research community. Because of this, there remains a risk that their operationalization of network externalities in the field of information networks is not conducted properly. This article discusses what different methods there could be to operationalize, measure and evaluate network externalities. This article comes up with four fundamental problems that are met with when network externalities are studied: the stakeholder problem, the identification problem, the arbitrator problem and the measure problem. Networks externalties, both positive and negative, are known to be part of every network. Positive network externalities are the main reason for building networks, and a primary source of wealth for the modern society, often actually called the networked society (Castells, 1996; Stalder, 1998). Network externalities stemming from telecommunication networks are a primary source of wealth in the information society. Taking this seriously, it is astonishing how little effort information system researchers have devoted to understanding network externalities. One reason might be that network externalities have traditionally been a playfield of economists, and information system researchers have felt unease at the field. This, however, needs not to be the case. Aside the rather theoretical discussion on network externalities the economists run, a more practical and operative approach to the issue is needed. This is aimed at in this article, actually just presenting some preliminary and initial thoughts on a research agenda to be run over the coming years. According to a recent research, network externalities are on of the 10 key forces that drive information technology to the society (Andal-Ancion, 2003). For economists, the theory of network externalities, or network externalities, or standardization, has wide applicability. Indeed, it has fundamental importance for competition policy, regulation, business strategy, intellectual property, and technical change in a wide range of industries; developments in these industries cannot be fully understood without an understanding of network externalities (Besen). Network effect are a popular and important theoretical concept. However, there remains a risk that their operationalization is too difficult to perform. This article discusses what different methods there could be to operationalize, measure and evaluate network externalities. What are networks? Networks exist in many varieties and forms. The microstructure of the underlying network of connections (physical or virtual) can influence the strength of network externalities (Sundararajan, 2003). Common for all networks is the existence of two or more network nodes, and some kind of relationship between them. Networks can be physical or abstract, and actually all networks exhibit some kind of abstract characteristics, and a network having physical components can be seen as a special case. More specifically, the abstract/physical characteristics can materialize both in the nodes and in the relationship/connections between the nodes. Figure 1 Types of networks Typical physical networks are those of telecommunications, including the Internet, mobile phone networks, local area networks, Plain Old Telephone (POTS) networks, etc. Many of networks have to do with the society infrastructure, such as railway, electricity, water, sewer or road networks. The relationship between the network nodes need not to be physical. We so speak of airport networks, bank networks, retail outlet networks, hotel networks etc. These networks exist and are valuable as such, even though they are usually connected by several physical networks such as telecommunications or roads. Sometimes the relationships between the nodes are more important than the nodes. Actually, the network nodes can sometimes be hard to see. Take the example of a road network. Actually it is hard to see any specific nodes that would act as junctions of the connections. The roads are the connections itself, and they connect cities etc. However, we do not speak of a city network but of a road network. One way to look at the issue is to understand each road (usually with an assigned number in the national road system) as a node in the network. In that case, the junctions come in as connections. This example shows how difficult the terminology is. Abstract networks are many. A good example is the art of formulating astrons. No real connection of any kind exists between the stars in the astron, but an abstract network is formulated. In this case, the nodes themselves are still physical. A mother of all network with abstract nodes and abstract connections between them is that of the holy trinity. Networks can have well-defined or vague boundaries. An example of a well-defined network should at lest in theory be an intranet or local area network of a company, that is separated from the rest of the telecommunication network by a firewall. The network administrator should be able to exactly say what are the nodes of the network. A vague network is for example that of an academic community, say information system researchers. Both the potential network nodes as external evaluators can have different ideas on who or what is a part of the network and who or what not. All networks are dynamic at the end, also change their nodes and relationships between them. For some limited period, a network can however be seen as static. A summary of our network definition is in Table 1. Table 1 Characteristics of network • Consist of nodes and relationships/connections between them • All networks exhibit abstract characteristics, some have even physical nodes and/or connections between them • Network boundaries can be vague or well-defined • All networks are dynamic at the end, but can look like static for a certain period ________________________________________________________________________ Individuals or organizations (units) can have different roles as it comes to networks. The most clear role is that of being a member, node, of a network. Other typical roles are those of owner of a network, administrator of a network, or customer of a network. Depending on the situation, might be that a network has no customers, owners or administrators. A unit can be simultaneously in several roles in a network, even simultaneously a network node, owner, administrator and a customer. Needless to say, each unit is a member of several networks, sometimes even unconsciously, and each unit has several roles to several networks. What are network externalities? Network externality has been defined as a change in the benefit, or surplus, that an agent derives from a good when the number of other agents consuming the same kind of good changes. (Liebowitz & Margolis). The roots of the network effect research are in the marketing discipline, where it was understood that the success of a product or service is a phenomenon strengthening itself. The phenomenon was called the bandwagon effect by which was meant “the extent to which the demand for a commodity is increased due to the fact that others are also consuming the same commodity. It represents the desire of people to purchase a commodity in order to get into ‘the swim of things’; in order to conform with the people they wish to be associated with; in order to be fashionable or stylish; or, in order to appear to be ‘one of the boys.”(Leibenstein, 1950) Still today, the network effect is often connected the act of buying and selling, and not the the act of consuming, as above: “A positive consumption externality (or network externality) signifies the fact that the value of a unit of the good increases with the number of units sold” (Economides, 1996). Another definition stressing buying is that of: “Network externalities arise when a consumer values compatibility–often stemming from ability to take advantage of the same complements–with other consumers, creating economies of scope between different consumers’purchases”(Farrell & Klemperer, 2006). One should make a difference between network effect and network externality. Network externalities should not properly be called network externalities unless the participants in the market fail to internalize these externalities (Liebowitz & Margolis). An externality is the effect of a transaction between two parties on a third party who is not involved in the carrying out of that transaction. Internalizing an effect means that it is no more directed towards a third party. Network externalities can be direct or indirect, and positive or negative, we arrive at Figure 2. Figure 2 Types of network externalities Direct network externalities exist when an increase in the size of a network increases the number of others with whom one can “communicate” directly. Indirect network externalities exist when an increase in the size of a network expands the range of complementary products available to the members of the network (Besen). Network externalities can be positive or negative. A typical negative network effect is a traffic jam. All too often network externalities are understood just as posivite. The same phenomenon can be both positive and negative, depending on the role of the observer. To take an example, to a railway operator having a lot of customers is a good thing (more revenue), but for the customer the same situation can mean congestion, also an negative effect. The enchantment of network externalities is that they often come out as surprise and as a byproduct that was not calculated or foreseen in any way. How to measure networks Networks as such are already complicated objects for measurement, not to speak of their. Typical measures of networks are geographical coverage (materializing in concepts such as WAN, MAN, LAN), or the length of a network, say for example the length of a road network in a country. A basic indicator is the number of active and passive nodes in the network, even though for example in a telecommunication network it is actually difficult to say which node is a passive and which one an active one. An active telecommunication network node is expected to have some decision capacity, usually programmed to the device. A group itself are the different indicators showing the output or performance of the network. A telephone network might be evaluated through the number of calls taken in a certain period of time, or a liquid pipeline through the amount of liquid it transfers. A more complicated measure would take into account the performance. A telephone network might be evaluated based on the phone minutes in a certain period of time. More complicated, say an optic cable can be of very different capacity. A teleoperator might report the amount of shield kilometers dig to the round, not taking into account what kind of cable was actually laid. In the railway industry, train transport performance is measured in axis kilometers: a train with 100 axes running 50 kilometres would perform the same as a train with 50 axes running 100 kilometres. The age of a network is too a complicated concept. It is typical to refer to the highest documented node age of the network., take an example from the London underground: “London Underground was formed in 1985, but its history dates back to 1863 when the world's first underground railway opened in London” (London underground. History., 2006). However, counting some average age for a network can be a haunting task, especially if the relative weight (what might that be) of each node has to be taken into account. To summarize, measuring networks is difficult. Overall measures that might allow for comparing different types of networks are rare if any. The number of network nodes is the only actual comparable figure, but even it is sometimes had to define. How to measure network externalities? We finally arrive to the crucial and actual question of this paper, how to measure network externalities. Unfortunately, in this paper we are not yet ready to deliver an answer. What we can do is identifying four kinds of problems: • The stakeholder problem • The identification problem • The arbitrator problem • The measure problem By our definition, the network externalities should be materialized to an external, third party, of the transaction taking place in the network. Already identifying who are the third parties can be a hard task. If we for example pollute, it is hard to find out who exactly will suffer from that transaction. This we call the stakeholder problem. The second problem is to identify the available network externalities, analyzing the issue from the viewpoint of the different stakeholders identified first. As already discussed, network externalities often materialize themselves in an unexpected way and first after a long maturing time. Most probably the direct negative externalities are to be identified first by the customers. The network owners and operators, also those trying to gain benefit from the networks, are the first to identify positive network externalities, both direct and indirect. The indirect negative externalities might be the most difficult to identify. The problem of identifying network externalities is here called the identification problem. The third problem we take up is called “arbitrator” problem. The externalities are not always direct, but materialize themselves over complicated value chains. Understanding these value chains, especially in the case of the indirect network externalities, is a major problem. We have to measure the network externalities in some scale. Network externalities discipline has its roots in economics, and so a natural conclusion would be to measure everything in money. In reality, this can hardly be done. For example, in the case of the popular example pollution, what is the economic value of an unpolluted environment. Another possibility of measuring network externalities would be that of giving them assessed values by the stakeholders on different scales. For example, through pairwise comparisons stakeholders could provide some ordinal scale on which network externalties can be ordered. One further possibility is to measure the importance of different network externalities on a likert-like scale in the case of different stakeholders. One of the lessons is that mental evaluations of network externalties can direct network behaviour more than values presented in money – values which anyway can be arbitrary and artificial. Most obviously network externalities materialize themselves to different stakeholders in different scales, and thus different measures are needed. Mastering this mess we call the measure problem. To come to some kind of answer to the question posed in the beginning of this table, the process as depicted in Figure 3 is needed in the evaluation of network externalities. Figure 3 The process of network externalities evaluation Further research of mine, hopefully of many others too, will further elaborate this process. An example In order to give an example of the network externalities evaluation, let us discuss the case of a local area network, which by definition is a limited and small network. Stakeholder identification The stakeholders of the network are at least three: the users, the network (operative) administrator, and the owner of the network (the one paying the final bills). Value chain analysis The value chain of externalities materialization can already get complicated. A simplified value chain could be that of delivering the infrastructure, delivering resources using the infrastructure, and sharing resources through the infrastructure. Each step in the value chain adds value, and the last, third activity will produce network externalities, also added value through utilizing the network. Network externalities identification When utilizing the network, users get more resources to use when the network grows and network externalities grow. The bigger the network, the more specialized processing nodes and information resources will be in the network. For the network, the network externalities might be negative, as more work is to be conducted in the network. For the network owner, more activity in the network should mean more return on the investment. One must remember that some other network of the organization might suffer because of the powerful local area network. A clear example is that many organizations have got rid of traditional telephone networks because of modern computer networks or/and because of mobile phone networks. For stakeholder, what actually counts is the total balance when all the used networks are taken into account. Measurement of externalities How the network externalties materialize to each stakeholder depend a lot on the charging arrangements designed for the network. For example, the owner of the network might get some revenue for each new user, as well as the network operator. Most likely the revenue flow of the extra users will be bigger than the marginal cost of each new user. Through the network, final users might avoid acquiring the needed resources themselves, and would thus save money. For example, buying an own color laser printer could be avoided because of the positive network externalities provided by the fact that one laser can serve a big group of users. Conclusions Benefits and costs caused by information systems are hard to measure, even evaluate. The problem is further complicated when network externalities are taken into account. No wonder most researchers at the information systems research discipline have ignored the topic of network externalities. This means that information system researchers would ignore the mechanisms running at the very heart of the information society. Network externalities can be a complicated concept, and with wrong kind of approach they remain an untouched white area even in the future. This however needs and can not be the case. In order to really understand the inner functions of the information – network - society, network externalities must be studied. What is needed is an operative, simple, sometimes even childish approach, where a genuine will exists to see network externalities in work around us. We can see them if we want and give them names, but we can as well ignore them. A topic too needing attention is the comparison of different networks. We information system researchers might shrink the idea that there is something in common say with the GSM network and the sewer network, but most surely there is. The first step in the process of mastering the problem is identifying and acknowledging its size and severity. This article has proceeded with this in mind. The very basic concepts of networks and network externalities have been elaborated, and they already have been found as complicated. The haunting task of evaluating network externalities remains largely untouched in this article. However, a good start is that of understanding and acknowledging the basic problems: the stakeholder problem, the identification problem, the arbitrator problem and the measure problem. References Andal-Ancion, A. (2003). The digital transformation of traditional business. MIT Sloan Management Review(Summer), 35-41. Besen, S. M. Innovation, Competition, and the Theory of Network Externalities: Charles River Associates. Castells, M. (1996). The rise of the network society. Malden, Massachusetts: Blackwell Publishers Inc. Economides, N. (1996). The economics of networks. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14(2). Farrell, J., & Klemperer, P. (2006). Network Effects and Switching Costs (forthcoming). In S. N. Durlauf & L. E. Blume (Eds.), the new New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics: Palgrave Macmillan. Leibenstein, H. (1950). Bandwagon, Snob, and Veblen Effects in the Theory of Consumers’Demand. The Quarterly Journal of Economics(May). Liebowitz, J., & Margolis, S. E. Network externalities (Effects). London underground. History. (2006). Retrieved 20.6.2006, 2006, from http://www.tfl.gov.uk/tube/company/history/ Stalder, F. (1998). The rise of the network society, the information age: Economy, society and culture, vol I. Information Society, 14(4), 301-308. Sundararajan, A. (2003). Network effects. Retrieved 20.6.2006, 2006, from http://oz.stern.nyu.edu/io/