Download Monopoly

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Marginalism wikipedia , lookup

Externality wikipedia , lookup

Economic equilibrium wikipedia , lookup

Supply and demand wikipedia , lookup

Perfect competition wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
CHAPTER
15
Monopoly
Goals
Learn why some markets have only one seller
in this chapter you will
Analyze how a monopoly determines the quantity to produce and
the price to charge
See how the monopoly’s decisions affect economic well-being
See why monopolies try to charge different prices to different
customers
Consider the various public policies aimed at solving the problem
of monopoly
Outcomes
after accomplishing
these goals, you
should be able to
List three reasons why a monopoly can remain the sole seller of a
product in a market
Use a monopolist’s cost curves and the demand curve it faces to
show the profit earned by a monopolist
Show the deadweight loss from a monopolist’s production
decision
Demonstrate the surprising result that price discrimination by a
monopolist can raise economic welfare above that generated by
standard monopoly pricing
Show why forcing a natural monopoly to charge its marginal cost
of production creates losses for the monopolist
147
148
Chapter 15 Monopoly
Strive for a Five
The material covered in Chapter 15 has been tested quite heavily in recent years on the
free response portion of the AP microeconomics exam.You should be prepared to create a
cost curve model for a monopoly. Specific issues to understand include:
■■ Monopoly market power
■■ Monopoly profit maximization
■■ Inefficiency of monopolies
■■ Price discrimination
■■ Natural monopolies
Key Terms
■■
■■
■■
■■
■■
Monopoly—A firm that is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes
Natural monopoly—A monopoly that arises because a single firm can supply a good or
service to an entire market at a smaller cost than could two or more firms
Price discrimination—The business practice of selling the same good at different prices
to different customers
Arbitrage—The process of buying a good in one market at a low price and selling it in
another market at a higher price
Perfect price discrimination—A situation in which the monopolist is able to charge each
customer precisely his or her willingness to pay
Chapter Overview
Context and Purpose
Chapter 15 is the third chapter in a five-chapter sequence dealing with firm behavior and
the organization of industry. Chapter 13 developed the cost curves on which firm behavior
is based. These cost curves were employed in Chapter 14 to show how a competitive
firm responds to changes in market conditions. In Chapter 15, these cost curves are
again employed, this time to show how a monopolistic firm chooses the quantity to
produce and the price to charge. Chapters 16 and 17 will address the decisions made by
monopolistically competitive and oligopolistic firms.
A monopolist is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes. As such, it has
market power because it can influence the price of its output. That is, a monopolist is a
price maker as opposed to a price taker. The purpose of Chapter 15 is to examine the
production and pricing decisions of monopolists, the social implications of their market
power, and the ways in which governments might respond to the problems caused by
monopolists.
Chapter Review
Introduction Monopolists have market power because they can influence the price of their
output. That is, monopolists are price makers as opposed to price takers. While competitive
firms choose to produce a quantity of output such that the given market price equals the
marginal cost of production, monopolists charge prices that exceed marginal costs. In
this chapter, we examine the production and pricing decisions of monopolists, the social
implications of their market power, and the ways in which governments might respond to
the problems caused by monopolists.
Why Monopolies Arise
A monopoly is a firm that is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes. A
monopoly is able to remain the only seller in a market only if there are barriers to entry. That
Chapter 15 Monopoly
is, other firms are unable to enter the market and compete with it. There are three sources
of barriers to entry:
■■ Monopoly resources: A key resource required for production is owned by a single firm.
For example, if a firm owns the only well in town, it has a monopoly for the sale of
water. DeBeers essentially has a monopoly in the market for diamonds because it
controls 80 percent of the world’s production of diamonds. This source of monopoly
is somewhat rare.
■■ Government regulation: The government gives a single firm the exclusive right to
produce some good. When the government grants patents (which last for twenty
years) to inventors and copyrights to authors, it is giving some­one the right to be
the sole producer of that good. The benefit is that it increases incentives for creative
activity. The costs will be discussed later in this chapter.
■■ The production process: The costs of production make a single producer more efficient
than a large number of producers. A natural monopoly arises when a single firm can
supply a good to an entire market at a smaller cost than could two or more firms. This
happens when there are economies of scale over the relevant range of output. That is,
the average-total-cost curve for an individual firm continually declines at least to the
quantity that could supply the entire market. This cost advantage is a natural barrier
to entry because firms with higher costs find it undesirable to enter the market.
Common examples are utilities such as water and electricity distribution.
How Monopolies Make Production and Pricing Decisions
A competitive firm is small relative to the market, so it takes the price of the good it
produces as given. Because it can sell as much as it chooses at the given market price,
the competitive firm faces a demand curve that is perfectly elastic at the market price.
A monopoly is the sole producer in its mar­ket, so it faces the entire downward-sloping
market demand curve. The monopolist can choose any price/quantity combination on
the demand curve by choosing the quantity and seeing what price buyers will pay. As with
competitive firms, monopolies choose a quantity of output that maximizes profit (total
revenue minus total cost).
Because the monopolist faces a downward-sloping demand curve, it must lower the
price of the good if it wishes to sell a greater quantity. Therefore, when it sells an additional
unit, the sale of the additional unit has two effects on total revenue (P × Q):
■■ The output effect: Q is higher.
■■ The price effect: P is lower (on the marginal unit and on the units it was already
selling).
Because the monopolist must reduce the price on every unit it sells when it expands
output by one unit, marginal revenue (∆TR/∆Q) for the monopolist declines as Q
increases and marginal revenue is always less than the price of the good.
As with a competitive firm, the monopolist maximizes profit at the level of output
where marginal revenue (MR) equals marginal cost (MC). As Q increases, MR decreases
and MC increases. Therefore, at low levels of output, MR > MC and an increase in Q
increases profit. At high levels of output, MC > MR and a decrease in output increases
profit. The monopolist, therefore, should produce up to the point where MR = MC. That
is, the profit-maximizing level of output is determined by the intersec­tion of the marginalrevenue and marginal-cost curves. Because the MR curve lies below the demand curve, the
price the monopolist charges is found by reading up to the demand curve from the MR =
MC intersection. That is, it charges the highest price consistent with that quantity.
Recall that for the competitive firm, because the demand curve facing the firm is
perfectly elastic so that P = MR, the profit-maximizing equilibrium requires that P = MR
= MC. However, for the mo­nopoly firm, MR < P, so the profit-maximizing equilibrium
requires that P > MR = MC. As a result, in competitive markets, price equals marginal cost while
in monopolized markets, price exceeds marginal cost.
Evidence from the pharmaceutical drug market is consistent with our theory. While the
patent is enforced, the price of a drug is high. When the patent expires and generic drugs
become available, the price falls substantially.
149
150
Chapter 15 Monopoly
As with the competitive firm, profit = (P − ATC) × Q, or profit equals the average
profit per unit times the number of units sold.
The Welfare Cost of Monopolies
Does a monopoly market maximize economic well-being as measured by total surplus?
Recall that total surplus is the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus. Equilibrium
of supply and de­mand in a competitive market naturally maximizes total surplus because
all units are produced where the value to buyers is greater than or equal to the cost of
production to the sellers.
For a monopolist to produce the socially efficient quantity (maximize total surplus by
produc­ing all units where the value to buyers exceeds or equals the cost of production), it
would have to produce the level of output where the marginal-cost curve intersects the
demand curve. However, the monopolist chooses to produce the level of output where the
marginal-revenue curve intersects the marginal-cost curve. Because for the monopolist the
marginal-revenue curve is always below the demand curve, the monopolist produces less than
the socially efficient quantity of output.
The small quantity produced by the monopolist allows the monopolist to charge a
price that ex­ceeds the marginal cost of production. Therefore, the monopolist generates a
deadweight loss because, at the high monopoly price, consumers fail to buy units of output
where the value to them exceeds the cost to the monopolist.
The deadweight loss from a monopoly is similar to the deadweight loss from a tax, and
the mo­nopolist’s profit is similar to tax revenue except that the revenue is received by a
private firm. Because the profit earned by a monopolist is simply a transfer of consumer
surplus to producer surplus, a monopoly’s profit is not a social cost. The social cost of a
monopoly is the deadweight loss generated when the monopolist produces a quantity of
output below that which is efficient.
Price Discrimination
Price discrimination is the business practice of selling the same good at different prices
to different customers. Price discrimination can only be practiced by a firm with market
power such as a mo­nopolist. There are three lessons to note about price discrimination:
■■ Price discrimination is a rational strategy for a profit-maximizing monopolist because
a monop­olist’s profits are increased when it charges each customer a price closer to his
individual willingness to pay.
■■ Price discrimination is only possible if the monopolist is able to separate customers
according to their willingness to pay—by age, income, location, etc. If there is
arbitrage—the process of buy­ing a good in one market at a low price and selling it in
another market at a higher price—price discrimination is not possible.
■■ Price discrimination can raise economic welfare because output increases beyond
that which would result under monopoly pricing. However, the additional surplus
(reduced deadweight loss) is received by the producer, not the consumer.
Perfect price discrimination occurs when a monopolist charges each customer her exact
will­ingness to pay. In this case, the efficient quantity is produced and consumed and there is
no dead­weight loss. However, total surplus goes to the monopolist in the form of profit. In
reality, perfect price discrimination cannot be accomplished. Imperfect price discrimination
may raise, lower, or leave unchanged total surplus in a market.
Examples of price discrimination include movie tickets, airline tickets, discount coupons,
financial aid for college tuition, quantity discounts, and tickets for Broadway shows.
Public Policy Toward Monopolies
Monopolies fail to allocate resources efficiently because they produce less than the socially
optimal quantity of output and charge prices that exceed marginal cost. Policymakers can
respond to the problem of monopoly in one of four ways:
■■ By trying to make monopolized industries more competitive. The Justice Department
can employ antitrust laws (statutes aimed at reducing monopoly power) to prevent
mergers that reduce competition, break up extremely large companies to increase
competition, and prevent companies from colluding. However, some mergers result in
Chapter 15 Monopoly
■■
■■
■■
synergies that reduce costs and raise efficien­cy. Therefore, it is difficult for government
to know which mergers to block and which ones to allow.
By regulating the behavior of the monopolies. The prices charged by natural monopolies
such as utilities are often regulated by government. If a natural monopoly is required
to set its price equal to its marginal cost, the efficient quantity will be consumed but
the monopoly will lose money because marginal cost must be below average variable
cost if average variable cost is declin­ing. Thus, the monopolist will exit the industry. In
response, regulators can subsidize a natural monopoly with tax revenue (which creates
its own deadweight loss) or allow average-total-cost pricing, which is an improvement
over monopoly pricing but it is not as efficient as marginal-cost pricing. Another
problem with regulating prices is that monopolists have no incentive to reduce costs
because their prices are reduced when their costs are reduced.
By turning some private monopolies into public enterprises. Instead of regulating the prices
charged by a natural monopoly, the government can run the monopoly itself. The Postal
Service is an example. Economists generally prefer private ownership to government
ownership because pri­vate owners have a greater incentive to minimize costs.
By doing nothing at all. Because each of the previously listed solutions has its own
shortcomings, some econo­mists urge that monopolies be left alone. They believe that
the “political failure” in the real world is more costly than the “market failure” caused
by monopoly pricing.
Conclusion: The Prevalence of Monopolies
In one sense, monopolies are common because most firms have some control over the
prices they charge. On the other hand, firms with substantial monopoly power are rare.
Monopoly power is a matter of degree.
Helpful Hints
1. A monopolist can choose the quantity and see what price buyers will pay or can
choose the price and see what quantity buyers will purchase. That is, a monopolist is
still subject to the demand curve for its product. The monopolist cannot choose both a
high price and a large quantity if that combination does not lie on the demand curve
facing the monopolist.
2. A monopolist is not guaranteed to earn profits. Any one of us can be the monopolist
in the production of gold-plated textbook covers (because there is currently no
producer of such a product), but the demand for such a product is likely to be too low
to cover the costs of production. In like manner, gaining a patent on a product does
not guarantee the holder of the patent future profits.
Self-Test
Multiple-Choice Questions
1. Which of the following statements is correct?
a. A competitive firm and a monopolist are price takers.
b. A competitive firm and a monopolist are price makers.
c. A competitive firm is a price taker, whereas a monopolist is a price maker.
d. A competitive firm is a price maker, whereas a monopolist is a price taker.
e. A competitive firm is a price maker, whereas a monopolist is a price setter.
151
Chapter 15 Monopoly
2. Which of the following statements is (are) true of a monopoly?
(i) A monopoly has the ability to set the price of its product at whatever level it
desires.
(ii) A monopoly’s total revenue will always increase when it increases the price of its
product.
(iii) A monopoly can earn unlimited profits.
a. (i) only
b. (ii) only
c. (iii) only
d. (i) and (ii) only
e. (ii) and (iii) only
3. The supply curve for the monopolist
a. is horizontal.
b. is vertical.
c. is upward sloping.
d. is downward sloping.
e. does not exist.
4. A monopolist’s average revenue is always
a. equal to marginal revenue.
b. greater than the price of its product.
c. equal to the price of its product.
d. less than the price of its product.
e. less than marginal revenue.
Figure 15-1
Price
152
P
MC
A
B
C
ATC
F
G
H
J K
L
MR
Quantity
5. Refer to Figure 15-1. What price will the monopolist charge?
a. A
b. B
c. C
d. F
e. H
6. Refer to Figure 15-1. What area measures the monopolist’s profit?
a. (B-F)*K
b. (A-H)*J
c. (B-G)*K
d. 0.5[(B-F)*(L-K)]
e. B*K
Chapter 15 Monopoly
Price
Figure 15-2
P3
Curve C
Curve D
P5
P4
P2
P1
P0
Curve B
Q1 Q3
Q2 Q4
Curve A
Quantity
7. Refer to Figure 15-2. A profit-maximizing monopoly’s total revenue is equal to
a. P4 x Q3.
b. P5 x Q1.
c. P3 x Q4.
d. (P4-P2) x Q3.
e. P2 x Q3.
8. Refer to Figure 15-2. A profit-maximizing monopoly’s total cost is equal to
a. P4 x Q3.
b. P2 x Q3.
c. P1 x Q3.
d. (P4-P1) x Q3.
e. P3 x Q4.
9. Refer to Figure 15-2. A profit-maximizing monopoly’s profit is equal to
a. P4 x Q3.
b. (P4-P2) x Q3.
c. (P4-P1) x Q3.
d. (P5-P0) x Q1.
e. P2 x Q3.
10. Refer to Figure 15-2. Profit on a typical unit sold for a profit-maximizing
monopoly would equal
a. P5-P0.
b. P4-P2.
c. P4-P1.
d. P4-P3.
e. P4-P0.
11. Refer to Figure 15-2. At the profit-maximizing level of output,
a. marginal revenue is equal to P3.
b. marginal cost is equal to P3.
c. average revenue is equal to P4.
d. average total cost is equal to P0.
e. price is equal to P3.
153
154
Chapter 15 Monopoly
12. The socially efficient level of production occurs where the marginal cost curve
intersects
a. average variable cost.
b. average total cost.
c. demand.
d. marginal revenue.
e. minimum average total cost.
13. The economic inefficiency of a monopolist can be measured by the
a. number of consumers who are unable to purchase the product because of its high
price.
b. excess profit generated by monopoly firms.
c. poor quality of service offered by monopoly firms.
d. deadweight loss.
e. difference between marginal cost and marginal revenue at the profit maximizing
level of output.
Price
Figure 15-3
9
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
10
9
8 A B
7
6 C D J
5
I H
4
F
3
2
1
MC
MR
Demand
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Quantity
14. Refer to Figure 15-3. Which area represents the deadweight loss from monopoly?
a. J
b. H
c. H + I
d. J + H
e. F
15. Price discrimination requires the firm to
a. separate customers according to their willingness to pay.
b. differentiate between various units of its product.
c. engage in arbitrage.
d. use coupons.
e. charge a higher price than break even.
16. For a typical natural monopoly, average total cost is
a. falling, and marginal cost is above average total cost.
b. falling, and marginal cost is below average total cost.
c. rising, and marginal cost is below average total cost.
d. rising, and marginal cost is above average total cost.
e. constant, and marginal cost is equal to average total cost.
Chapter 15 Monopoly
17. If the government regulates the price that a natural monopolist can charge to be equal
to the firm’s average total cost, the firm will
a. earn zero economic profits.
b. earn positive economic profits, causing other firms to enter the industry.
c. earn negative economic profits, causing the firm to exit the industry.
d. minimize costs in order to lower the price that it charges.
e. not be able to continue to operate in the long run.
Panel C
Price
D
Panel B
Price
Panel A
Price
Price
Figure 15-4
Panel D
D
D
D
Quantity
Quantity
Quantity
Quantity
18. Refer to Figure 15-4. Which of the following statements is correct?
a. Panel C represents the typical demand curve for a perfectly competitive firm, and
Panel B represents the typical demand curve for a monopoly.
b. Panel B represents the typical demand curve for a perfectly competitive firm, and
Panel C represents the typical demand curve for a monopoly.
c. Panel A represents the typical demand curve for a perfectly competitive firm, and
Panel B represents the typical demand curve for a monopoly.
d. Panel C represents the typical demand curve for a perfectly competitive firm, and
Panel D represents the typical demand curve for a monopoly.
e. Panel A represents the typical demand curve for a monopoly, and Panel B
represents the typical demand curve for a perfectly competitive firm.
19. The profit-maximization problem for a monopolist differs from that of a competitive
firm in which of the following ways?
a. A competitive firm maximizes profit at the point where marginal revenue
equals marginal cost; a monopolist maximizes profit at the point where marginal
revenue exceeds marginal cost.
b. A competitive firm maximizes profit at the point where average revenue equals
marginal cost; a monopolist maximizes profit at the point where average revenue
exceeds marginal cost.
c. For a competitive firm, marginal revenue at the profit-maximizing level of
output is equal to marginal revenue at all other levels of output; for a monopolist,
marginal revenue at the profit-maximizing level of output is smaller than it is for
larger levels of output.
d. For a profit-maximizing competitive firm, thinking at the margin is much more
important than it is for a profit-maximizing monopolist.
e. For a competitive firm, marginal revenue at the profit-maximizing level of output
is equal to marginal cost, however for a monopolist, marginal revenue at the
profit-maximizing level of output is larger than marginal cost.
20. When a monopolist increases the amount of output that it produces and sells, average
revenue
a. increases, and marginal revenue increases.
b. increases, and marginal revenue decreases.
c. decreases, and marginal revenue increases.
d. decreases, and marginal revenue decreases.
e. decreases, and marginal revenue remains constant.
155
156
Chapter 15 Monopoly
Free Response Questions
1. Graphically depict the deadweight loss caused by a monopoly. How is this similar to
the deadweight loss from taxation?
2. Explain how a profit-maximizing monopolist chooses its level of output and the price
of its goods.
Chapter 15 Monopoly
Solutions
Multiple-Choice Questions
1. c TOC: Monopoly
2. a TOC: Monopoly
3. e TOC: Monopoly
4. c TOC: Average revenue
5. b TOC: Monopoly
6. c TOC: Profit maximization
7. a TOC: Total revenue
8. c TOC: Total cost
9. c TOC: Profit
10. c TOC: Profit
11. c TOC: Average Revenue
12. c TOC: Welfare
13. d TOC: Deadweight loss
14. d TOC: Deadweight loss
15. a TOC: Price discrimination
16. b TOC: Natural monopoly
17. a TOC: regulation/Natural monopoly
18. a TOC: Monopoly/Perfect competition
19. b TOC: Monopoly/Perfect competition
20. d TOC: Average revenue
Price
Free Response Questions
1. A profit-maximizing monopolist will choose to produce Q0 units of output and sell at price P0. However,
marginal cost is MC0. This is identical to the deadweight loss of taxation when the tax forces a wedge between
market price and marginal cost.
MC
P0
MC0
MR
Q0
Demand
Quantity
TOP: Deadweight loss
2. A profit-maximizing monopolist produces the output level where marginal revenue equals marginal cost and
charges the corresponding price from the market demand curve. Note that a monopolist charges a price that
exceeds marginal cost, unlike a competitive firm, for which price equals marginal cost.
TOP: Profit maximization
157