Download Annamaria Simonazzi (Provisional) 1. Introduction: secular

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Economics of fascism wikipedia , lookup

Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup

Recession wikipedia , lookup

Nouriel Roubini wikipedia , lookup

Economic bubble wikipedia , lookup

Fiscal multiplier wikipedia , lookup

Economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Business cycle wikipedia , lookup

Chinese economic reform wikipedia , lookup

Rostow's stages of growth wikipedia , lookup

Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup

Transformation in economics wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Secular stagnation, the wage share, and asset bubbles
Annamaria Simonazzi1
(Provisional)
1. Introduction: secular stagnation?
Slow growth has been usually attributed to supply factors: a decline in productivity which is
explained in turn by disincentive effects of welfare systems no longer attuned to the changed
environment (globalization, technical change), excessive protection and regulation resulting in a too
slow adjustment of labour and wages and a rate of innovation out of step with the rate of technical
progress. By calling the supply-side story into question, Summer’s suggestion that “our economy is
constrained by lack of demand rather than lack of supply” (Summers, 2014a) stunned the economic
profession. In such a situation, increasing capacity to produce will not translate into increased
output unless there is more demand for goods and services, and “training programs, reform of
social insurance, [greater flexibility] may affect which workers get jobs, but they will not affect
how many get jobs. Indeed measures that raised supply could have the perverse effect of
magnifying deflationary pressures”. Summers advocates more government spending and
employment, to take advantage of the current period of economic slack to renew and build out our
infrastructure. Thus, the crisis has returned legitimacy to old discredited explanations based on
demand, or lack thereof.
Summer’s argument is based on the idea that the short-term real interest rate that is consistent with
full employment has fallen to negative values. With the failure of monetary policy to enforce
equality between investment and full employment savings in a “liquidity trap”, we may be stuck in
a long-run equilibrium with underemployment and we are doomed to economic stagnation. The
reasons of the fall of the “natural” or “Wicksellian” real interest rate lie in its standard determinants:
(i) the savings-supply schedule, (ii) the investment-demand schedule, with the shift in the curves
being explained mostly by demography and IT respectively. Low interest rates, in turn, may foster
financial instability: “It may be impossible for an economy to achieve full employment, satisfactory
growth and financial stability simultaneously simply through the operation of conventional
monetary policy”. Bubbles are an alternative way for society to deal with excess saving when fiscal
policy does not take up the challenge: the recent growth is thus “fragranced with hints of new
financial bubbles” (Teulings and Baldwin 2014).
Among the reasons affecting the propensity to spend and leading to the lack of demand, changes in
income distribution, though mentioned, are not given by Summers their full weight. Indeed, the
huge increase in inequality over the last three decades has refocused attention on income
distribution as a factor affecting demand and growth. Measures to reduce income concentration at
the top, so as to sustain effective demand in the rest of the population have been advocated by many
unorthodox economists in the past and are now coming from the most unexpected quarters: the IMF
(Ostry et al. 2014) now maintains that “lower net inequality is robustly correlated with faster and
more durable growth”, and the Central bankers of the richest countries reunited in Jackson Hole
have rushed in support of employment and wages2. “From her position as the world’s single most
powerful economic voice, the chair of the US Federal Reserve, Janet Yellen, is forcing the financial
11
Dipartimento di Economia e Diritto, Sapienza University of Rome.
Appelbaum B. Central bankers' new gospel: Spur jobs, wages and inflation.
http://www.nytimes.com/2014/08/25/business/central-bankers-new-gospel-spur-jobs-wages-andinflation.html?wpisrc=nl-wonkbk&wpmm=1&_r=0; Apparently, even the austere President of the Deutsche
Bundesbank, Jens Weidmann, has welcomed higher German wages, though strictly limited to some sectors
th
(Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung July 30 , 2014). http://uk.reuters.com/article/2014/07/30/uk-germany-wagesweidmann-idUKKBN0FZ03U20140730
2
1
markets to rethink assumptions that have dominated economic thinking for nearly 40 years.
Essentially, Yellen is arguing that fast-rising wages, viewed for decades as an inflationary red flag
and a reason to hike rates, should instead be welcomed, at least for now”. Yellen’s new stance, that
echoes that by another former Fed Chairman (1932-48), Marriner Eccles3, has forced Wall Street to
re-focus as well. Judging from the articles in the financial press4, finance has become obsessed with
a simple, easy-to-understand measure of American household health: wages.
The paper argues that, with increasingly unequal distribution in income and wealth and fiscal policy
proscribed, advanced economies are bound to stagnate. Monetary policy, conducted within a
financially de-regulated setting, is more likely to produce bubbles rather than steady growth.
Bubbles thus become the only way in which economies can grow. It is generally maintained that
they can produce only short-run, temporary effects on demand, and negative, long-lasting effects on
growth through speculative investment ending in waste, deleveraging and balance sheet recession.
The paper investigates whether, and in which conditions, booms might activate a process of
transformation and growth, and which policies may prevent or mitigate the disruptive effects of
deleveraging. In order not to be misunderstood, it is not argued that bubbles are the best way to
growth; the aim is simply to compare the disruption following the bursting of a bubble with the
wasteland produced by austerity and secular stagnation. Section 2 reviews the literature on the
relation between income distribution, demand and growth. It argues that financial deregulation has
given rise two ways to exorcise the negative effects of a declining labour share on growth: exports
and debt, which are creating cumulative disequilibria, possibly culminating in bubbles. Sections 3
and 4 analyse the need for bubbles and their impact on demand, in the short and in the long-term.
The last section briefly compares the experience of three Eurozone countries – Germany, Italy and
Spain – which have followed different patterns of growth.
2. Income distribution, demand and growth
2.1 The dual nature of wages.
Demand-led growth theory has a long tradition5. In this approach, the dynamic of demand affects
the level of output in the short and in the long run, through its influence on the creation of
productive capacity (Vianello, 1985). A lower creation of productive capacity prevents insufficient
demand from resulting in a sizeble and persistent under-utilisation of capacity, thus covering up the
tracks of the lost production (Garegnani 1992). In Summer’s (partial) rediscovery of this tradition:
“Perhaps Say’s dubious law has a more legitimate corollary – “Lack of Demand creates Lack of
Supply” (Summers 2014b, p. 37) (figure 1). In the European context of the Stability Pact, by
reducing the rate of growth of potential output, insufficient demand can impact on fiscal
sustainability, as far as the reduction in potential output reduces the output gap, and hence the
structural deficit (Boitani and Landi, 2014).
3
“As mass production has to be accompanied by mass consumption, mass consumption, in turn, implies a distribution
of wealth – not of existing wealth, but of wealth as it is currently produced – to provide men with buying power equal
to the amount of goods and services offered by the nation’s economic machinery. Instead of achieving that kind of
distribution, a giant suction pump had by 1929-30 drawn into a few hands an increasing portion of currently produced
wealth. This served them as capital accumulations. But by taking purchasing power out of the hands of mass
consumers, the savers denied to themselves the kind of effective demand for their products that would justify a
reinvestment of their capital accumulations in new plants. In consequence, as in a poker game where the chips were
concentrated in fewer and fewer hands, the other fellows could stay in the game only by borrowing. When their credit
ran out, the game stopped.” (Eccles 1951).
4
M. Phillips, Janet Yellen’s Fed is more revolutionary than Ben Bernanke’s ever was. http://qz.com/247113/janetyellen-is-a-more-revolutionary-fed-leader-than-bernanke-ever-was/
5
Keynes (1936) is obviously the leading figure here.
2
Income distribution is regarded as a fundamental determinant of final demand, and, through final
demand, of the inducement to invest. Given the Kaleckian assumption that the marginal propensity
to save is higher for capital income than for wage income, consumption is expected to increase
when the wage share rises6. However, wages have a dual function: they are a cost of production as
well as a source of demand. A higher real wage increases consumption but may also reduce
investment, in so far as a lower profit share weakens the incentive to invest7. Thus, any exogenous
variation in the real wage has contradictory effects on the level of aggregate demand. Bhaduri and
Marglin (1990) distinguished between a wage-led demand regime, when an increase in the wage
share leads to an increase in aggregate demand in the short run, and a profit led demand regime in
the opposite case8. Most empirical studies find that domestic demand regimes tend to be wage-led,
i.e. the effect of a pro-capital redistribution of income on demand is negative because consumption
is much more sensitive to an increase in the profit share than is investment (Stockhammer 2011).
However, in an open economy, external demand can provide a vent for surplus, absorbing the
excess savings that would arise when the purchasing power of wages is faltering. Indebtedness can
provide yet another support to consumption when the wage share falls.
Figure 1 Actual and potential GDP in the Eurozone.
Source: Summers (2014b).
6
In the models of Kalecki (1971) and Steindl (1952) an increase in the wage share unambiguously leads to an increase
in effective demand.
7
By depressing profits, high wages may discourage investment and accumulation, or may force capitalists to
rationalize, speed up technological progress and labour saving technologies, in turn affecting the level of employment,
wage earners’ bargaining power, and distribution (Barba and Pivetti 2012). However, high wages and labor market
institutions may also have positive effects on economic growth if good labor relations improve the propensity of
workers to contribute to the production process. Productivity is defined wage-led if an increase in wages encourages
productivity enhancing capital investment resulting in an acceleration of the growth of productivity (Lavoie and
Stockhammer 2012, p. 15).
8
A wage-led investment regime defines a more long-run concept: it implies that an increase in the wage share will
lead in addition to a wage-led demand also an increase in investment expenditures. Over the long run it implies an
increase in the rate of accumulation of the capital stock.
3
2.2 Exorcisms
Export-led growth. In an open economy, the effect of distribution on demand must take account of
net exports. Looking at wages only as cost, and assuming away the possibility of an equilibrium at
less than full employment, mainstream models recognize only the positive effects that follow a
decrease in wages: the improved competitiveness will increase net exports while the higher profit
share will sustain investment. When considering also the role played by wages on consumption,
however, the result is no longer obvious. The total effect of a pro-capital redistribution of income
depends on the effects on consumption, the sensitivity of investment to profits and the sensitivity of
net exports to unit labor costs. If the total effect of the increase in the profit share on aggregate
demand is negative, the demand regime is called wage-led. Conversely, if the effect of distribution
on net exports is high enough to offset the effects on domestic demand the demand regime is called
profit-led. A number of studies have attempted to estimate the effects of a redistribution of income
on all three components of private demand. They conclude that, in most of the large economies such
as the US, Japan, the Euro area in aggregate as well as individual large European countries Germany, France, Italy, the effects due to net exports are not large enough to change the nature of
the demand regime from wage to profit-led, since foreign trade forms only a small part of aggregate
demand (Onaran and Galanis 2012).
Different, systemic effects result if all countries follow the same distributional strategy. A
simultaneous wage cut is likely to leave all countries with only the negative domestic demand
effects, with their combined GDP contracting. While beggar thy neighbor policies cancel out the
competitiveness advantages in each country, and are therefore counter-productive9, an across the
board increase in money wages, though leaving competitiveness unaffected, can sustain a wage-led
growth (provided that firms still feel sufficient competitive pressures to compel them to cut their
mark-ups in response to the wage increases).
Debt-led growth. Finance and credit can play a double role: they can affect income distribution
directly, while neutralizing their effects on demand by granting credit. During the last 3 decades
finance staged an astonishing expansion of profits in a rapidly expanding financial services
industry, simultaneously supplementing the reduced incomes with debt. Changes in consumers’
access to credit and in consumers’ borrowing behaviour, especially regarding what consumers
think is appropriate to borrow, fuelled the type of herd behavior and irrational exuberance that is
usually attributed to stock markets. The different impact that the change in distribution exerted on
final demand and accumulation in the Anglo-Saxon world compared with most of continental
Europe – at least until the inception of the euro – is largely explained by the debt and wealth effects
created by the financially-driven high-tech and construction bubbles. According to Barba and
Pivetti (2012), “the overall effect on investment of the financial sector enlargement, in size and
scope, was negative: it contributed to bring about a change in income distribution unfavourable to
the expansion of demand, while providing only a temporary disconnection of demand from the
distributive change”.
Eurozone: two symbiotic growth models. Stock and property markets bubbles are initiated and
sustained by bubbles in the supply of credit, reinforced by the liberalization of capital flows. In
debtor countries booming sectors attract capital inflows thereby financing their current account
deficits. Export-led countries run current account surpluses and net capital outflows. Thus,
international financial deregulation has given rise to two symbiotic growth models: a debt-led
growth model (with foreign capital inflows) and an export-led model (with capital outflows)
(Lavoie and Stockhammer 2012).
9
Onaran and Galanis (2012) find that a 1% simultaneous decline in the wage share in G20 leads to a decline in the
global GDP by 0.36%.
4
Since the adoption of the euro, the member states have followed different growth strategies: most
countries in the periphery have adopted a debt-led growth, the core an export-led growth. If the
export-led country is characterized by a wage-led demand regime, as it is maintained to be in the
case of Germany (Stockhammer et al. 2011), wage moderation requires ever stronger export
stimulus to support growth. This entails increasing deficits in those countries which are on a debtled growth. This precarious “equilibrium” can continue only until the core countries are willing to
supply liquidity to the debtor countries. As soon as this fails debtor countries must adjust, since it is
unlikely that surplus countries will change their strategy to act as “locomotive”. In the case of
Germany, in fact, given wage moderation, domestically-originated growth is limited. Germany acts
rather as a transmitter of global trade impulses, from the United States and Asia to Europe. German
supply chains are set in motion by demand that predominantly originates outside Europe (Bornhorst
and Mody 2012). Simulations of demand-induced GDP reductions triggered by austerity policies in
the Eurozone suggest that, with the exception of Germany and Austria, the most important
determinant of the fall in income has been the domestic component of final demand. Similarly,
Garbellini et al (2014) find that peripheral Eurozone countries have generally been more sensitive to
domestic demand reductions, while core-eurozone countries have been more vulnerable to (and
inflicting more damage to) their trade partners10.
These results help to better assess the “way out” represented by internal devaluation. For those who
look at wages only as cost, an internal devaluation can succeed in converting the debt-led growth
countries into export-led performers. This, it is argued, requires the implementation of structural
reforms, in the labour market (freedom of firing for newly hired employees, downward wage
adjustment, lower unemployment duration, weakening of collective bargaining institutions,
decentralized bargaining and wage differentiation across workers and sectors) and in the product
market in order to speed up the reallocation of resources to more productive sectors. However, the
euro area is still a rather closed economy with a high intra-EU trade. Wage moderation in the Euro
area as a whole is likely to have only moderate effects on foreign trade but it will have large
detrimental effects on domestic demand11. Thus, when all Eurozone countries pursue ‘beggar thy
neighbor’ policies, the international competitiveness effects are likely to be only minor, and the
negative domestic effects dominate the outcome.
3. Are bubbles essential for growth?
“Prior to 2003, the [US] economy was in the throes of the 2001 downturn, and prior to that it was
being driven by the internet and stock market bubbles of the late 1990s. So it has been close to 20
years since the American economy grew at a healthy pace supported by sustainable finance.”
(Summers 2014b, p.31)12.
Since the early 1980s dramatic changes in income distribution have occurred, with a substantial
decline in the wage share across the world. Globalization may have contributed to weaken the
wage-led demand regimes of the relatively closed economies in the post-war era: imports and
exports have grown relative to GDP, imported inputs have increased their share in domestic demand
10
Germany, Austria and Belgium ‘exported’ more than 75% of the drop in domestic final demand while the drop in
final demand from PIIGS contributed to around 50% of their own GDP reduction, and was more than offset by the
expansion of BRIC countries (Garbellini et al. 2014) .
11
This argument is based on the (wrong) assumption that competition is mostly based on prices and unit costs.
Relaxing this assumption (see Simonazzi et al 2013) will only reinforce the argument.
12
The idea that the current system can only grow through bubbles had already been put forward in 2010 by Andrea
Ginzburg, in his abstract for a paper, “Bricks & Chips. Real and financial interactions in a global setting”, which has
unfortunately never been written.
5
and exports, investment may have become more sensitive to profitability and delocalization and
outsourcing, or the threat of it, may have affected employment and wage bargaining13.
The concentration of income and wealth at the very top greatly increased the demand for complex
financial products, putting pressure on financial institutions to supply profitable securities. The
investment banks generated huge fee and commission revenues by obliging. “Neoliberal economic
principles allowed the regulators to believe that the surging growth of complex financial
instruments must be to the social benefit” (Wade 2010). The combination of pull and push forces
has made the financial system prone to generate bubbles, followed by crashes.
Given the national and systemic changes in the advanced economies - an increasingly unequal
income distribution, the labour-saving and skill-biased features of technical change and
globalization, the de-regulation of finance – and the related market approach in economic theory
and policy, only two ‘engines’ were left: export-led and debt-led growth. In these conditions,
growth can easily degenerate into a bubble. “Boom-bust cycles driven by stock markets, property
markets or capital flows have been a key feature of neoliberalism as practiced in the real world, as
exemplified by the Latin American crises of the 1980s and of the mid 1990s (the Peso crisis), the
EMS (European Monetary System) crisis (1992/93), the South East Asia crisis (1997/98), the
dot.com bubble burst 2000/01 and the Great Recession of 2008/09” (Lavoie and Stockhammer
2012, p. 22).
Thus, mainstream and post-Keynesian analyses converge. In Summers’ words, “macroeconomic
policy as currently structured and operated may have difficulty maintaining a posture of full
employment and production at potential … and if these goals are attained there is likely to be a
price paid in terms of financial stability.” In short, secular stagnation may force policymakers to
choose between sluggish growth and bubbles. Bubbles are an alternative way for society to deal
with excess saving when fiscal policy does not take up the challenge. Though eschewing income
distribution as the main cause, the effects of different policies on distribution are acknowledged.
“Policymakers in an economy with excess saving face a major dilemma. Either they set monetary
policy to allow the interest rate to fall until the point at which rational bubbles emerge to absorb the
excess saving, or they avoid the interest rate from falling that far by using fiscal policy for the
absorption of the saving. There are profound differences in the distributional impacts of the two.
Using monetary policy favours the current owners of bubbly assets, predominantly the richer
elderly; using fiscal policy allows for a broader spreading of the benefits. But trying to avoid this
dilemma by picking neither of the two will lead to a failure of the capital market to clear and hence
to a long, dragged-out Keynesian recession, as shown by Japan’s experience since 1990.” (Teulings
and Baldwin 2014).
4. Bubbles, busts and growth
Bubbles create discontinuities, disproportions, disequilibria; busts inevitably trigger intense
processes of restructuring and deleveraging. After the bubble bursts, economy and society are no
longer the same. Whether the change involves creative destruction or plain destruction depends on a
host of factors, such as the sectors involved, their impact on the rest of the economy and society
through multiplier/propagation effects, the policies implemented in the bubble and in its aftermath
to overcome the recessionary consequences of de-leveraging (such as measures to reduce the
disruptive effects of debt deflation, bankruptcies laws, macroeconomic policies). The effects on the
overall economy differ also with domestic and international conditions.
13
According to Stockhammer et al. (2011), globalization has affected how changes in the income distribution influence
aggregate demand, but these effects have been and still are rather modest. The changes have not been sufficient to
undermine the wage-led demand regime in Germany.
6
There are two main channels through which the bursting of a bubble negatively affects demand and
growth: deleveraging and increase in inequality.
De-leveraging. “When a debt-financed bubble bursts, asset prices collapse while liabilities remain,
leaving millions of private sector balance sheets underwater. In order to regain their financial health
and credit ratings, households and businesses are forced to repair their balance sheets by increasing
savings or paying down debt. [...] people with negative equity are not interested in increasing
borrowing at any interest rate. Nor will there be many willing lenders for those with impaired
balance sheets, especially when the lenders themselves have balance sheet problems. [...] This act of
deleveraging reduces aggregate demand and throws the economy into a very special type of
recession”. This is the balance-sheet recession described by Koo (2011). We are in the world of
Fisher, Keynes, Minsky: there is little that monetary policy can do to restart demand, apart from
trying hard to avoid that the debt default mechanism spreads to the whole economy by providing
liquidity to the segments more under pressure. This calls for fiscal policy to absorb the excess
saving after a bubble has burst and the private sector has to deleverage14.
Increasing inequality. Bubbles entail rapid accumulation and destruction of wealth. The housing
and stock markets give and they also take away, though they give to some and take away from
others. In the US, the one-percenters saw their incomes slide 36.3% during the 2007-2009 recession
compared with a fall by 11.6% in incomes of the 99-percenters, but as the US emerged from
recession, about 95% of the income gains from 2009 to 2012 accrued to the top 1% of American
families (Saez 2013). The highest earners were only temporarily set back by the most recent
downturn, continuing the trend which had been unfolding for more than 30 years. Conversely, the
burst of the construction bubbles in Japan and in Sweden did not lead to comparable increase in
inequality (Koo 2011), but the implementation of austerity policies in the euro-zone has
transformed the deleveraging first into a balance sheet recession (spreading from the private to the
public sector) and then into a tragedy.
Finally, in a bubble, speculative investments may end up in projects whose profitability depends on
the expectation that their prices would continue to rise. Much of this capital may turn out to be
scarcely productive when the bubble bursts – empty buildings, unessential infrastructure and excess
capacity in manufacturing – and will take a long time to dispose of.
In conclusion, when the bubble bursts, processes of de-leveraging, excessive capacity, and
polarization of wealth between winners and losers make the prospect of a rapid recovery less and
less likely, and can turn to the worse if monetary and fiscal policies do not take up the challenge.
While the literature has focused on the disruptive effects of bubbles, and especially of the possibly
devastating effects of debt deflation, the effects of the changes on the economy and society brought
about by the frenzy activity in the boom period have been generally overlooked, or condemned as
waste. However, the bubble is a time of profound structural transformation, and could represent an
opportunity for change and innovation in an otherwise stagnating economy. We may have
multiplier and propagation effects deriving from consumption linkages (Hirschman 1977); demandled growth can activate the supply-side factors of growth, from labour productivity to labour
14
See also Krugman (2014) who argues that temporary fiscal stimulus to support demand while the private sector gets
back to spending normally may not be enough “if negative natural rates are persistent” and quotes Koo in contending
that governments may have to provide stimulus for years to offset the drag of prolonged private-sector balance-sheet
repair: “Any premature withdrawal of fiscal stimulus would unleash the deflationary forces as unborrowed savings
are allowed to become a leakage in the economy’s income stream. Indeed, the US in 1937, Japan in 1997 and the UK
and Eurozone in 2010 all experienced serious double-dip recessions when their governments pursued fiscal
consolidation while their private sectors were still in the process of repairing balance sheets.” (Koo 2014, p. 135).
7
supply; it may foster innovation via dynamic economies of scale and demand-pull innovation15, and
through the stimulus transmitted to producers of inputs and capital goods by the interaction between
demand and supply; fiscal linkages can sustain investment in social infrastructure; last, but not least,
it can favour social innovation and social progress,. Whether the end result on the productive
capacity, the economy and society is creative destruction or plain destruction will depend on the
policies accompanying the boom and the bust.
5. Three euro-zone patterns: smoulder, fatigue, bubble
It has been argued in section 2 that the Eurozone countries have followed two symbiotic models:
debt-led and export-led growth. As usual, reality fits uncomfortably in the straitjacket of models.
Germany certainly followed an export-led model, but smothered growth through a deeply depressed
domestic demand (fig. 2 and 3). Partly dictated by very different macroeconomic conditions, Italy
too followed a path of domestic demand restraint, with exports as the only dynamic component. In
terms of growth, the German “success model” is not very different from the Italian “decline story”:
between 1995 and 2007 Germany’s rate of growth was barely 0.1 percentage points higher than
Italy’s, the laggard of the Eurozone (table 1 and fig. 2). On the bubble side, also Spain and Ireland
trod different paths, though both ended up in a spectacular construction bubble and a sea of private
(turned public) indebtedness. In the following, I will briefly compare the evolution of Germany,
Italy and Spain to assess the relative costs of bubbles and stagnation.
Figure 2. Real GDP 1992-2011 (1992=100)16
169
159
149
Germany
139
129
119
Greece
Spain
Italy
Portugal
109
99
Source: Ameco
Notes: 2005 prices.
15
The evidence of the derived demand-driven influence regarding the European Union (EU) over the period 19952007 is strong and positive, but varies between three EU innovation systems, EU core, East and South (Antonelli and
Gehringer 2013).
16
In 2007 Ireland GDP was 274 (1992 = 100). By comparison, Spain’s GDP at its peak in 2008 was 162.4.
8
Figure 3 Decomposition of GDP growth
Panel a: 1998-2007
Panel b: 2007-2012
Source: Employment and social situation in Europe, 2013 Report, 2014, pp. 293, 303
Table 1 Pre-crisis growth in selected OECD countries 1995-2007 (% per year)
Real GDP
Employment
2.3
1.3
Eurozone
3.2
1.2
USA
2.2
1.1
France
1.6
0.4
Germany
3.3
1.0
UK
3.9
1.3
Greece
7.2
4.3
Ireland
1.5
1.2
Italy
2.4
1.0
Portugal
3.7
3.6
Spain
Source: The Conference Board Total Economy Database
GDP/worker
1.0
2.0
1.1
1.2
2.3
2.6
2.9
0.3
1.4
0.1
9
5.1 Germany: “sick man of Europe” or “imaginary invalid”?
In the 1990s Germany has been hit by two almost simultaneous “shocks”: the opening of the
Eastern markets and the creation of the monetary union. By opening new opportunities for the
German industry, the “new frontier” affected both the German and the Southern periphery’s options
and policies (Soros 2011), besides, of course, the Eastern countries’ ones.
The Eastern Eldorado. The fall of the Berlin Wall in 1989 entailed dramatic costs of reunification
and huge opportunities of access to neighboring East European countries. The bubble triggered by
reunification was soon smothered by the Bundesbank, but the gigantic industrial policy continued
all through the decade: between 1991 and 2003 net transfers totaled about 900b. euros (half of one
year GDP). The shift of production to Eastern Europe had started quite early, largely as outward
processing trade, and accelerated after the unification, with the increasing commercial integration
with the Visegrad countries (Poland, Slovakia, Czech Republic, and Hungary). Between 1995 and
2007 the share of imported inputs in the tradable manufacturing increased by 8 percentage points,
with the greatest increase occurring between 1995-2000. Although Germany continued to maintain
its traditional exports to Europe, where it was able to fend off competition from Asian sources, its
imports of intermediate goods were increasingly tilted towards goods produced by Visegrad
countries and China (Figure 4). While German exports stayed largely insulated from Asian and
lower-wage European competition due to Germany’s specialization, much of advanced Europe—
including the periphery—faced the new reality of global low-wage competition, also when selling
to Germany (Bornhorst and Mody 2012, p. 14). In 2011 China became Germany’s second most
important import partner after the Netherlands, overtaking France.
Figure 4
Source: Bornhorst and Mody (2012)
In the same decade of the ‘90s flexible working practices developed and spread. In the early to mid90s opting out and “opening clauses” (that is deviations from industry-wide standards) “allowed for
an unprecedented increase in the decentralization (localization) of the process that sets wages,
hours, and other aspects of working conditions, from the industry- and region-wide level to the level
of the single firm or even the single worker, which in particular helped to bring down wages at the
lower end of the wage distribution” (Dustmann et al 2014, p. 176) 17. In addition, East Germany was
17
“Real wages at the 15th percentile fell dramatically from the mid-90s onwards. From the early 2000s onwards,
median real wages started to fall, and only wages at the top of the distribution continued to rise” (Dustmann et al
10
able to decouple itself from West German wage-setting mechanisms and unit labour costs declined
rapidly in relative terms.
Why was this possible after the mid-90s but not before? The threat to move industry east compelled
work councils and unions to make concessions. This intrinsic flexibility became only evident under
the difficult economic circumstances and the extreme duress in which Germany found itself in the
decade after reunification, because of the macroeconomic policies of the government, obsessed by
the cost of reunification. The process following reunification has been seen uniquely as a (transfer)
cost, rather than an injection of demand – to be financed by increased taxation on the west
(Lehndorff 2014).
When, by the end of the ‘90s, globalization and liberalization raised worries about the survival of
the “German model”, and Germany came to be referred as the sick man of Europe (Streek 1997;
Sinn 2003), the German industry was well ahead on its new path. The Hartz reforms were
implemented starting in 2003, hence nearly a decade after the process of wage decentralization and
the improvement in competitiveness had begun in Germany. The scale of the reforms is modest
enough that they seem unlikely to have triggered the dramatic increase in competitiveness or the
enormous drop in German unemployment, or to have led Germany’s labor market through the deep
recession in 2008–2009; nor can they account for the wage restraint witnessed since the mid 1990s.
It is restructuring by Germany’s private sector, using traditional German institutions based on
employer-worker cooperation, and not government labor market and welfare state reforms that are
to be credited for the German quick recovery after the recent crisis (Lehndorff 2014). Work-time
accounts provided internal flexibility for core workers, with lesser need to resort to temporary
workers. Moreover, in the previous boom firms held back in hiring, piling up time accounts so that
in the ensuing downturn they simply let the account deplete, with the help of public subsidies
(Bornhorst and Mody 2012, p. 19; Lenhdorff 2014). Indeed, discretionary stimulus is pragmatically
used in Germany, even if it is often downplayed in public discourse.
If the Hartz reforms cannot be credited for the remarkable rebound of the German economy in the
crisis, they can be blamed for the equally remarkable increase in inequality and in the share of
working poors. By relying on exports while suffocating domestic demand – the fixed investment
share has been constantly decreasing since unification and, even in the deep of the crisis, it has been
smaller than the Italian and French shares – the German economy produced spectacular surpluses,
but its model is one of structural under-employment. The virtuous response of working hours to the
cycle, ensured by work-time accounts and internal flexibility in manufacturing, should not conceal
the structural segmentation of the labour market: in 2013, 26 per cent of total employment and 45.1
per cent of women, worked part-time (often with a mini-job), compared with 21.6 per cent and 36.3
per cent respectively for the Eurozone. While the total number of people in employment has
increased, the total number of hours worked has diminished (Weinkopf 2013) (figure 5).
2014, p. 170). The 15th percentile declined dramatically
manufacturing (since 2004); tradable services.
in all disaggregation: non-tradable sector; tradable
11
Figure 5 Total employment 1992-2014 (200 = 100).
135
125
115
Germany
Ireland
105
95
Greece
Spain
Italy
85
Portugal
75
Source: Ameco.
5.2 Italy
Since the second half of the 1990s growth in Italy fell well below the EU average. The currency
crisis of September 1992 and the ensuing severe recession marked a watershed between two
different economic policy scenarios. With the decision to enter the Economic and Monetary Union
(EMU), the European Monetary System (EMS) first and the EMU afterwards provided the
legitimacy of an external constraint for unpopular policy measures aimed at coping with structural
disequilibria. Major supply-side reforms were implemented in the aftermath of the 1992 crisis in the
fields of labour market and industrial relations, privatisation and corporate governance,
administrative decentralisation, pensions and social protection. They shared the common principle
of letting the market work, but while the pars destruens was fully or partly implemented, the pars
construens was constantly delayed, due partly to budget and external constraints.
The extremely low rate of growth had given support to the hypothesis of a long-run economic
decline. According to this view, firms’ size and industrial specialisation resulted in a lack of product
and process innovation leading, in turn, to a loss of competitiveness, as evidenced – inter alia – by
the decline in Italy’s export share. Labour reforms and the deregulation of the labour and product
markets were deemed necessary to resume growth.
This interpretation, which enjoyed increasing popularity to become the consensus view, had come
up for reconsideration in the very years preceding the crisis. Firm-level evidence from Italian
manufacturing confirmed that low-tech businesses, which arguably benefited most from
devaluations, had been restructuring more since the adoption of the euro. Restructuring entailed a
shift of business focus from production to upstream and downstream activities, such as product
design, advertising, marketing and distribution, and a corresponding reduction in the share of bluecollar workers. The process of change had been led by medium-sized firms, firmly rooted in district
12
economies (Coltorti 2007), and had been accompanied by outsourcing (Breda and Cappariello
2010). The new challenges posed by globalisation, the diffusion of information and communication
technologies (ICT) and the adoption of the euro were inducing the most dynamic among Italian
firms to rethink their organisation and their degree of vertical specialisation. The conclusion was
that, since the adoption of the euro, a reallocation of activity had occurred within rather than across
sectors, supporting the productivity growth in those sectors that once relied more on competitive
devaluations to regain price competitiveness (Bugamelli et al. 2009). While this evidence cut the
nexus which had linked the data on ‘frozen specialisation’ with the hypothesis of a lack of
innovation and restructuring, it also made evident that the crisis struck Italian medium-sized firms
just as they were crossing the ford.
This rejuvenation process had three main weaknesses.
1. Restructuring had not been supported by an adequate expansion of the domestic market. The
labour market reforms of the late 1980s and 1990s resulted in an increasing share of precarious,
badly paid jobs, and stagnating real wages. Two major consequences followed. On the one hand,
the stagnation in consumption accounted for the limited expansion of the productive capacity:
innovative firms focussed more on the efficient exploitation of existing capacity than on the
expansion of new capacity, making for a productive base too small to absorb the entire labour force
at fair wages. On the other hand, the creation of an ample reservoir of cheap labour allowed the
survival of marginal firms.
2.Widening of the north-south divide: since the mid-1990s the gap in per capita income started to
increase again. In 1992 the Cassa per il Mezzogiorno was dissolved, ending the experience of active
policy of industrialisation. However, the Southern industry was too fragile to stand the harsh
competition of a monetary union unaided: it is more dependent on domestic demand, while the
incompleteness of its value chains makes it dependent on external inputs, so that the leak of imports
from the Centre-North weakens the correlation between demand and production18; finally a much
higher share of firms in the southern value chains are in a weaker contractual position than their
northern counterparts. Since the inception of the common currency the gap between the South and
the Centre-north of Italy widened again (and got worse in the crisis).
3. Micro-led restructuring, without a macro framework: the process of restructuring has occurred in
a void of national coordination and guidance and the crisis has accelerated the trend, inducing even
more fragmentation.
Aggregate demand had no explicative role in the interpretation of the slow growth of the Italian
economy: the effects of the macroeconomic policies undertaken in this period on income
distribution and domestic demand were simply negated. Thus, the long, painful period of cutbacks
that started in the 1990s had no corresponding results in terms of improved public finances. When,
in 2007, Spain made il sorpasso of the Italian economy in terms of GDP per capita, an event much
18
Bronzini et al. (2013) have estimated the degree of completeness of the value chains, showing that the linkages
(measured in terms of additional workers) activated in the South are seldom greater than half the number observed in
the Centre-North.
13
hailed by the Spanish government and mass media19, the Italian economy and society was worn-out
by two decades of restructuring fatigue.
5.3 Spain.
Halfway through the past decade, the Spanish economy appeared to be extremely successful in
many aspects: it was experiencing a decade of sustained growth in production, output and
employment, unemployment was going down, women were entering the labour market. The engine
of this growth was construction, mostly the residential sector but also public works. Property
development, construction and tourism have represented the focus of growth ever since the Franco
era, with the conspicuous absence of manufacturing. According to López and Rodríguez (2011)
Spain was integrated into the wider European economy on the basis of partial de-industrialisation
and persisting structural weaknesses: labour intensive industries, low productivity increases, and
little has changed over time. The phase of spectacular economic growth from 1994 to 2007 masked
these problems and, to some extent, aggravated them. While financial inflows and European
economic integration initially fostered manufacturing investment, they soon fuelled an
unsustainable property boom. Taking loans from abroad to transform them into loans for property
developers and individual buyers, the financial sector played a crucial role in the buildup of
household indebtedness, growing eventually into a bubble. The explosion of mortgages taken out by
households throughout the country has its counterpart in Spain’s mounting external debt (Banyuls
and Recio 2014).
The way in which, when the bubble burst, deleverage has been implemented within the Maastricht
framework, as well as its consequences on indebtedness, are well known. Less attention has been
devoted to the analysis of how the bubble has changed the Spanish economy. The impact of the
construction and real estate industry on the overall economic activity is unquestionable: the
enormous building activity boosted employment (fig. 5) and tax revenues. Bielsa and Duarte (2011)
have estimated the direct and indirect effects on the overall economy: each direct job generated in
the construction–real estate block is matched by almost one other job in dependent sectors,
underlining the strong dependence of the Spanish economy on the construction and real estate
sectors. As the authors point out, this is a lower bound estimate, since they did not account for the
income multiplier effects generated throughout the economy by the huge creation of (direct and
indirect) employment. Although the direct import content of construction may be assumed to be
rather low (it is not considered in Bielsa and Duarte’s analysis), it is not so for the import content of
the input-producing industries (including investment goods) and of the consumption and investment
goods activated by the higher employment and income: in the boom years Spain recorded
increasing current account deficits, financed by huge inflows of short-term capital. The aggregate
indicators signaled a persistently low rate of growth of productivity. However, as observed by
Haltiwanger (2013, p. 206), “rapid growth in a sector is often accompanied by a wave of entry, and
the entrants tend to be extremely dispersed in terms of productivity and growth rates… [so that]for a
time one may observe a greater dispersion of productivity among firms and possibly a leftward shift
in the size distribution even as the sector grows”. Thus, it is not possible to rule out a process of upgrading and innovation in the construction industry and in those sectors producing inputs and
19
Ana Carbajosa ans Serafí del Arco, “España supera por primera vez a Italia en riqueza por habitante”, El País,
December 18, 2007). Quoted in Munoz de Bustillo and Antòn (2014).
14
machinery, if not for the economy at large. Just to give an example, in 2012 Spain became the
world leader in the production of ceramic tiles (overtaking Italy) and Spanish producers of
machinery for the tiles industry are now competing with Italian (and Portuguese) firms for the
control of the markets of the main producers of ceramic tiles: China, Turkey, Mexico, Brazil,
besides Spain itself (Vesentini 2014). Last but not least, the long period of sustained growth led to a
deep transformation of the Spanish society, marked by the opposition between a neoliberal
economic policy orientation20 and a strong demand for social-democratic policies, which led to the
expansion of social services. One striking indicator is the enormous increase in female employment:
on the eve of the crisis the female employment rate was 55 per cent, up from 40 per cent in 2000
and 30 per cent in 1990. This data compares with 59 per cent in the EU27, and 47 and 49 per cent
respectively in Italy and Greece (2008). The balance between a neoliberal economic orientation and
progressive social policies was made possible by international financial inflows, that sustained the
boom, while hiding the piling up of structural problems. However, their prompt availability also
undermined the quest for alternative development patterns. The development model remained
focused on construction, mobilised a reserve workforce employed in very precarious conditions,
wasted the opportunity provided by buoyant tax revenues to address the structural problems of the
Spanish economy, and delayed the need to tackle the chronic current account deficit through
policies aimed at favouring import substitution, enlarging and diversifying the productive basis.
When the crisis and the fiscal consolidation arrived, unemployment rates soared, and the social
rights that had survived the conservative mandate, could no longer be defended. Fiscal austerity and
cuts in social services, education, R&D, local development policies, essential to pursue innovation
and rejuvenation of industry, doom the same possibility of a new model, reinforcing the old
production model based on low wages and precarious employment. Yet - in spite of austerity,
deleveraging and balance sheet recession; of the increase in youth and total unemployment and the
fall in employment, which in 2014 reverted back to the level recorded in 2002; of the forced cuts in
wages; of the huge flow of outmigration, of foreigners and natives alike – in 2014 total employment
was still higher than the level recorded at the beginning of the boom, and GDP growth was still
higher than the EU15 average (figure 6)21.
20
The Socialist Party, ruling from 1982 to 1986 and from 2004 to 2011, reflected this contradiction from within..
Although the 1986-2004 conservative mandates introduced important regressive elements, they took place in a
context that forced part of the acquired social rights to be preserved (Banyuls and Recio 2014).
21
The same is true for Ireland.
15
Figure 6. Real GDP and employment growth in the EU and Spain (1992-2012)
180
Employment in 1992 = 100
EU(15)
158.8
160
140
Spain
134.8
117.2
120
100
80
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
60
Source: Munoz de Bustillo and Antòn (2014).
6. Conclusion: vice versus virtue?
Over the last decades, a steeply declining wage share has aggravated the shortage of demand
relative to full employment output, and a finance dominated accumulation regime has heightened
financial instability. As argued by Summers, in these conditions, it may be impossible for an
economy to achieve full employment, satisfactory growth and financial stability simultaneously
simply through the operation of conventional monetary policy”. And nonetheless, in the Eurozone
fiscal policy has been severely restricted and monetary policy has been insulated from national
governments, the exact opposite of what should have been done. Koo (2014) contends that
“handling a balance sheet recession requires centralised political power22 … Japan struggled for 20
years to find a workable solution. The fragmented decision-making process in Europe might cause
even more difficulty in finding a way out”.
In the euro era, Germany and Germany-inspired rules smothered growth, its own and that of the
entire area. Italy trailed behind Germany, encumbered by a huge public debt and its lack of resolve.
For the rest of the peripheral countries debt-led growth might have represented a “rational” response
to an irrational construction. Waste and ruin have been made worse by bad policy.
22
See also Goodhart (1998) on the metallist interpretation of money (as opposed to the Chartalist view) underlying
the OCA approach and the construction of the EMU.
16
This paper did not want to argue that debt-led growth is a good thing. Bubbles can be extremely
costly. Fiscal and monetary policy are needed, and must work together, to prevent bubbles when
possible, and to assuage the costs of their bursting. Its ambition was a more limited one, that is, to
point out that, if vice is no panacea, virtue has not much to be recommended either. We can abhor
the “waste” of resources and the destruction of wealth produced by bubbles only if we are willing
(or used) to disregard the waste of capacity and resources, human and otherwise, caused by
widespread, extended “lapses” from full employment.
17
References
Antonelli, C. and Gehringer, A., (2013), Demand pull and technological flows within innovation
systems: the intra-European evidence,
Bhaduri, A., and S. Marglin, (1990), “Unemployment and the real wage: the economic basis for
contesting political ideologies,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, 14, 375-93
Banyuls J. and Recio, A. (2014), A crisis inside the crisis. Spain under the regime of a conservative
neoliberalism, in S. Lehndorff (ed.)
Barba, A. e Pivetti, M. (2012), Distribution and accumulation in post-1980 advanced capitalism,
Review of Keynesian Economics, Inaugural Issue, Autumn 2012, pp. 126–142
Bielsa, J. and R. Duarte (2011), “Size and linkages of the Spanish construction industry: key sector
or deformation of the economy” Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol 35 (2), 317-334
Boitani, A. and Landi, L. (2014), Oltre i soliti sospetti, Lavoce.com, 21.08.14
Bornhorst, F. and Mody, A. (2012), Tests of German Resilience, IMF WP no. 12/239
Bugamelli, M., Luigi Cannari, Francesca Lotti e Silvia Magri (2012), Il gap innovativo del sistema
produttivo italiano: radici e possibili rimedi, Questioni di Economia e Finanza (Occasional papers),
no. 121
Dustmann, C., Fitzenberger, B., Schönberg, U. and Spitz-Oener, A. (2014), “From Sick Man of
Europe to Economic Superstar: Germany’s Resurgent Economy” Journal of Economic
Perspectives—Volume 28, Number 1—Winter 2014—Pages 167–188
Eccles, M. (1951), Beckoning Frontiers, Alfred A. Knopf, New York.
Garegnani, P. (1992), Some Notes for an Analysis of Accumulatio, in J. Halevi, D. Laibman and
E.J. Nell (eds) Beyond the Steady State. A Revival of Growth Theory, London, Macmillan.
Garbellini N., Marelli, E. and A.L. Wirkierman, (2014), “Domestic demand and global production
in the Eurozone: A multi-regional input-output assessment of the global crisis”, International
Review of Applied Economics, 28, 3, pp. 335-363.
Haltiwanger, J. (2013), General discussion, in Reis (2013), p. 206.
Hirschman, A.O. (1977), A generalised linkage approach to development, with special reference to
staples, Economic development and cultural change, 25, suppl., pp. 67-98.
Kalecki, M. (1971), Selected Essays in the Dynamics of the Capitalist Economy, Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press.
Koo, R. C. (2011), “The world in balance sheet recession: causes, cure, and politics”, real-world
economics
review,
issue
no.
58,
12
December
2011,
pp.19-37,
http://www.paecon.net/PAEReview/issue58/Koo58.pdf
Koo, R.C. (2014), Balance sheet recession is cause for secular stagnation, in Teulings and Baldwin
(2014).
Lavoie M. and Stockhammer E. (2012) Wage-led growth: Concept, theories and policies,
Conditions of Work and Employment Series No. 41, ILO, Geneva
Lehndorff, S. (2014), Model or liability? The new career of the ‘German model’, forthcoming
Lopèz, I and E. Rodriguez (2011), “The Spanish Model” New Left Review 69, may-june, pp 1-28
Munoz de Bustillo, R. and Anton, J. (2014), Crisis, fiscal consolidation and the cutbacks in the
welfare state in Spain, Economia & Lavoro, n. 2, pp. 93-107.
18
Onaran, Ö. and Galanis, G. (2012), “Is aggregate demand wage-led or profit-led? National and
global effects”, ILO Working Papers, Conditions of Work and Employment Series No. 40, Geneva.
Ostry, J.D., Berg, A. and Tsangarides, C.G. (2014), Redistribution, Inequality, and Growth, IMF,
SDN/14/02
Reis, R. (2013), The Portuguese Slump and Crash and the Euro Crisis, BPEA
Saez E. (2013), Striking it Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States
http://eml.berkeley.edu/~saez/saez-UStopincomes-2012.pdf
Simonazzi, A., Ginzburg, A. e Nocella, G., (2013) “Economic relations between Germany and
Southern Europe”, The Cambridge Journal of Economics,
Sinn H.W. (2003) The Sick Man of Europe: Diagnosis and Therapyof a Kathedersozialist, IFO,
Munich.
Steindl, J. (1952), Maturity and Stagnation in American Capitalism, Basil Blackwell, Oxford
Stockhammer, E. (2011), Peripheral Europe’s Debt and German Wages. The Role of Wage Policy
in the Euro Area, Research on Money and Finance Discussion Paper no. 29, Kingston University,
London
Stockhammer E. and Onaran O. (2012), Wage-led growth: Theory, Evidence, Policy, PERI
Working Paper 300, Nov.
Stockhammer E., Hein E. and Grafl L. (2011), Globalization and the effects of changes in
functional income distribution on aggregate demand in Germany, International Review of Applied
Economics, 25:1, 1-23
Streek, W. (1997), German Capitalism: Does it Exist? Can it Survive? In: Crouch, Colin and
Wolfgang Streeck, eds., (1997), Political Economy of Modern Capitalism: Mapping Convergence
and Diversity. London, Sage, 33-54
Summers, L.H. (2014a), U.S. Economic Prospects: Secular Stagnation, Hysteresis, and the Zero
Lower Bound, Business Economics 49(2).
Summers, L.H. (2014b), Reflections on the “New secular stagnation hypothesis”, in Teulings and
Balwin (2014)
Teulings, C. and Baldwin, R. (eds.) (2014), Secular Stagnation: Facts, Causes and Cures, vox.org
Vesentini, I. (2014), Piastrelle, leadership a rischio, Il Sole 24 Ore, 29-8, p. 9.
Vianello, F. (1985) The pace of accumulation, Political Economy: Studies in the Surplus Approach,
1(1), pp. 69–87.
Wade, R. (2010), Income Inequality, International Payments Imbalances, and Crises,
http://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2010/07/income-inequality-internationalpayments-imbalances-and-crises.html
Weinkopf,C. (2013), Female employment in Germany – robust against the crisis but vulnerable as
regards the quality of jobs, paper presented at the 34th Annual Conference, International Working
Party on Labour Market Segmentation, Dublin.
19