Download Features of Monopolistic Competition

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Competition law wikipedia , lookup

Externality wikipedia , lookup

Supply and demand wikipedia , lookup

Economic equilibrium wikipedia , lookup

Perfect competition wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
University of Pacific-Economics 53
Lecture Notes #15
I.
Features of Monopolistic Competition
Like the name suggests, a monopolistically competitive industry has features from both a
monopoly market structure and a perfectly competitive market structure.
The features of a monopolistically competitive industry include:
(1) Many firms. Like a perfectly competitive structure, in monopolistic competition there
are a large number of firms. Each firm is small relative to the size of the market.
(2) Entry is easy. Like a perfectly competitive structure, entry into an industry is not
blocked. In the long run, if firms are earning an economic profit, this will attract firms
into the industry. Firms will continue to enter until economic profits are zero.
(3) Firms produce different products. Unlike a perfectly competitive firm which produces
a homogeneous product, a firm that is monopolistically competitive will produce a
slightly different product than their competitors. By producing a unique product that no
other firm provides, a monopolistically competitive firm can act as a monopolist and have
some market power over the price it charges. In other words the firm can raise its prices
and not worry about losing all the demand for their product.
II.
Product Differentiation
The ability of a monopolistically competitive firm to have market power over its price depends
on how well they can differentiate their product from their competitors. In this section we’ll
look at several issues: (1) Why does product differentiation exists? (2) How do firms achieve
product differentiation and (3) What are the costs and benefits of advertising?
A. Why does Product Differentiation Exist?
In some industries, there is no variety of output produced across firms, while in other industries
there is a great deal of variety. Think about when you go to the Supermarket and walk down the
cereal aisle. There are dozens of varieties of cereals for you to choose from. What features
explain why certain industries have variety while other industries do not. The key determinants
of product differentiation are:
Heterogeneity of Consumer Tastes: If every consumer in the market had similar
tastes then there would be no need for variety. For example, if everyone in Stockton
only liked Mexican food then only Mexican restaurants would be successful in
Stockton. As a result the entire restaurant industry would consist of only one variety.
The greater the extent people’s tastes are different the more variety will exist. A
diverse population will probably lead to more variety and choices for consumers.
2. Lack of $eed for Coordination: Some industries require that firms produce the
same output otherwise the industry would not function as well. There are many firms
that produce DVD discs. The output produced are standard in that each disc will play
1.
on any DVD player. Imagine what would happen to the DVD industry if each firm
produced a slightly different DVD that each required a special DVD player to watch.
Obviously such a system would not be feasible. Thus industries in which
coordination is needed will limit product choice.
3. Scale Economies: If in a particular industry it is cheaper to produce a single variety
than to produce a bunch of different varieties then the industry will tend to produce
the single variety. For monopolistically competitive firms, such scale economies do
not exist. In other words there is not much difference between producing varieties
over a standardized product.
B. How do Firms Differentiate their Products?
There are two broad ways in which firms differentiate their products:
(1) Horizontal Differentiation-Horizontal differentiation is the idea that when firms
differentiate their products they make them more attractive to some consumers, but less
attractive for others. For example, a popcorn maker who differentiates his product by
producing kettle corn is likely to make his product popular with some customers, but
others will be less likely to purchase it. In this example, horizontal differentiation has
created variety to reflect the fact that some people like kettle corn popcorn while others
do not.
(2) Vertical Differentiation-Vertical differentiation is the idea that when firms differentiate
their products it is a difference that everyone agrees make the product better than a rival
product. An example of vertical differentiation is a laptop that has 250GB of hard drive
vs. an exact same laptop that has a 500GB hard drive. Why would anyone choose the
250GB hard drive laptop? Well the obvious answer is that the prices must be different
between the two products. Again this reflects, tastes of consumers. Consumers who
value the extra drive space will pay for the more expensive laptop.
All these efforts by monopolistically competitive firms to differentiate their products would be
pointless if consumers didn’t enjoy variety. But for most products, consumers do like having
choices and are variety seeking. People don’t wear the same outfit every day nor do they eat the
same food every day. Thus consumers for the most part like the fact that firms in
monopolistically competitive industries do produce different products.
A branch of economics called behavioral economics has provided some insights on how
consumers react when faced with variety. Behavioral economics combines some theory from
psychology with economic theory to explain how decisions are made. Two areas of study in
behavioral economics are worth a quick mention.
• Some studies have shown that too much variety might overwhelm consumers. One study
looked at the impact on consumers when faced with dozens of choices. The study
showed that when faced with a overwhelming set of choices most consumers react by
making no decision at all, or by reverting to a default option. For example, in most
retirement plans, employees have to choose among hundreds of mutual funds (companies
that invest in the stock market). Some people instead of making informed choices,
•
refrain from making any choice and their money goes to some default option (low yield
government fund).
Some studies in behavioral economics have tried to provide another explanation on why
consumers prefer variety. The same firm might differentiate the same product by having
different package sizes or different pricing plans. For example, Oreo cookies can come
in small mini-packages consisting of a couple of cookies or huge boxes sold at Costco
that has hundreds of the same cookie. An example of a firm that has different pricing
plans for the same product is a typical health/fitness club. Users have an option of paying
a daily use fee or they could enroll for a yearly membership. Behavioral economics
explain these types of product differentiation are a result of the fact that some consumers
use these products as a form of commitment device. That is consumers purchase a
specific form of product as a way to commit to a behavior in the future. For example, by
purchasing a yearly membership to the fitness club, a consumer is making a commitment
to work out regularly. Likewise by buying a smaller package of Oreo Cookie the
consumer is committing themselves to eating less of a tasty, yet unhealthy treat.
C. Pros and Cons of Advertising
Advertising is critical in creating product differentiation. It helps inform consumers about the
differences between Good X and Good Y while at the same time creating a brand image that
fosters customer loyalty. Hundreds of millions of dollars are spent annually on advertising.
While some have argued that advertising is useful in creating product differentiation, others have
argued that the resources spent on advertising is wasteful and could have been used for other
purposes. We’ll take a quick examination of the debate on advertising.
• Pro-Advertising Side
Advocates of advertising make the following points:
1. Consumers must have complete information when making choices. Advertising
provides information on product availability, quality and price that allows consumers to
make the best choice possible in the marketplace.
2. Advertising promotes competition. By advertising, new products are able to compete
with established products.
• Critics of Advertising Side
Critics of advertising make the following counterpoints:
1. Advertising is a waste of resources. The millions spent on advertising is wasted since
a lot of the money is used in highlighting small or even non-existent differences among
products. Is there really much difference between a name brand Aspirin bottle or a
generic bottle? Presumably the contents of the bottle will be composed of the same
ingredients.
2. Advertising Increases Costs to Consumers. Firms that spend on advertising will have
that cost built into their cost curves. It’s the cost for them to do business. With higher
cost curves, the firms have to charge a higher price than they would have otherwise
charged.
3. Advertising is a zero-sum game. Firms that are successful in advertising will just take
away market share from a competitor. They won’t increase the demand or profits for the
industry as a whole. “Zero-Sum Game” refers to fact that the gains to the winners will be
exactly offset by the losses from the losers. Thus the industry as a whole does not gain.
4. Advertising creates a barrier to entry. In order to compete with an established name
brand product, a new firm will have to spend vast sums of money just to put itself on the
radar for potential consumers. The fact that one must have millions to spend on
advertising just to get started often makes entry into a firm difficult.
5. Advertising is deceptive and annoying. Proponents of advertising argued that
advertising provides information that allows consumers to make informed choices.
However, most ads have very little useful information to help consumers make choices.
They are meant to persuade us to buying a product and some can be deceptive. Also
there is a cost to society of being bombarded constantly with ads from the morning
newspaper, to listening to the radio while driving to work, to seeing the billboards on the
freeway, to the ads on television.
Not surprising there are economists on both side of the debate. Some economists have shown
that advertising leads to an efficient market as consumers make better, informed choices. Other
studies have shown that advertising creates an industry that is concentrated and results in higher
prices for consumers. Work on this area is still ongoing.
III.
Price and Output Determination Under Monopolistic
Competition
A. Demand Curve Under Monopolistic Competition
Figure 1 shows two demand curves that differ based on the market structure of the industry.
As we have seen the demand curve facing an individual firm in a perfectly competitive
industry is horizontal (perfectly elastic). The demand curve is perfectly elastic because
consumer demand will drop to 0 if the firm raises the price by even the tiniest amount. This
has to hold under perfect competition because every firm in the industry is producing the
same product, and if one firm tries to raise its price, all consumers will go to other firms. A
monopolistically competitive firm doesn’t have this problem. Since they produce slightly
different versions of products, their products are unique and thus they will not lose demand if
they raise their price somewhat. For example, if Pepsi raises its price by a couple of cents, it
will not suddenly see all of its customers go drink Coca-Cola. Some people would be willing
to pay the higher price for Pepsi rather than switch to Coke. Thus the demand curve for a
monopolistically competitive firm will be downward sloping like a monopolist demand
curve. However, the demand curve for a monopolistically competitive firm will be
relatively flat. The product produced by a monopolistically competitive firm will have
many close substitutes. Recall from Chapter 5, then the presence of close substitutes will
make consumers very responsive to any change in price. Thus the demand curve for a firm
under monopolistic competition will be elastic and the slope will be flat. Figure 1 illustrates
these two demand curves.
Figure 1: Demand Curves Facing a Perfectly Competitive Firm and a Monopolistically
Competitive Firm
B. Price and Output Determination Under Monopolistic Competition
Where will a monopolistically competitive firm produce in the short run? We’ve seen that
because of product differentiation, the firm will face a downward sloping (yet flat) demand
curve. Because the monopolistically competitive firm has some degree of market power, it must
lower its price on all units, just like a monopolist, if it wants to sell more output. Thus the
marginal revenue curve will be below the demand curve. If we add our cost curves, we’ll find
that a price and output are determined in the same manner as a monopolist.
Figure 2
Figure 2 shows two price/output decisions for a firm in a monopolistically competitive industry.
Figure 2(a) shows that the firm will produce where MR=MC. At that point, the quantity
produced will be 2,000 units and the price charged will be $6. Thus total revenue will be
$12,000. At 2,000 units the ATC will be $5. Thus total costs will be $10,000. Total profits will
therefore be $12,000-$10,000 = $2,000. Thus in this case the firm is producing a positive
economic profit.
Figure 2(b) shows a different firm with a different demand and marginal revenue curve. At the
point where MR=MC the firm will produce at an output of 1,000 units and will charge a price of
$5. Thus total revenue will be $5,000. At 1,000 units, the ATC will be $6. T he resulting total
costs will be $6,000. This firm will thus be losing $1,000.
As with a perfectly competitive firm, a monopolistically competitive firm will still continue to
operate in the short run, even if it suffering losses as long as the price is above the average
variable cost. In the long-run situation however profits and losses will not be maintained.
C. Price and Output Determination Under Monopolistic Competition in
the Long-Run
One of the assumptions we made about a monopolistically competitive industry was that entry
and exit in the industry is easy. The presence of economic profits will attract new firms into the
industry, while the existence of losses will cause firms to leave the industry. There is a slight
difference between perfect competition and monopolistic competition. The difference is that
each firm under monopolistic competition produces a different, unique product. A new firm that
enters an industry will not produce the exact same good but a close substitute. The result will be
that the demand curve facing the existing firms will shift to the left. As consumers have more
options, they will demand less of any particular good. The entry of new firms will continue until
there is no more economic profit. This will occur where the demand curve is tangent to the ATC
curve
***The long-run profit-maximizing equilibrium for a monopolistically competitive firm is
the point where the demand curve is tangent to the ATC curve***
This will be the long-run equilibrium as well even if the firm was initially suffering losses. If
firms in the industry was initially suffering losses, then firms will be leaving the industry. That
would result in less choice in the market, and the demand curve facing the remaining firms will
shift to the right. This will continue until the demand curve is tangent to the ATC curve.
Figure 3 illustrates this long-run equilibrium.
Figure 3: Long-Run Equilibrium under a Monopolistically Competitive Structure
D. Economic Efficiency of a Monopolistically Competitive Industry
There is a social cost to a monopolistically competitive industry. Firms act as mini-monopolist
for their own unique product and as a result the price will be higher than what is socially optimal
(Price will be greater than marginal cost), and the resulting output will also be lower than what is
optimal. A second cost is that scale economies are not achieved. Notice in Figure 3, where the
firm is producing at its LRAC curve. It’s producing at a point above the minimum point of the
LRAC. This means if the firm could produce more it will see lower costs. Economists,
however, balanced these costs with the fact that monopolistically competitive firms result in new
products being introduced, old products being improved, and lots of variety being created for
consumers. For the most part these gains seem to offset any social costs that might have arisen.