Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Chapter 1 Understanding Asia’s Economies Asian economies, both individually and in aggregate, have been growing and developing impressively during most of the post-war era. Asian economies have taken turns to achieve high economic growth rates: first Japan; then South Korea, Hong Kong, Taiwan, and Singapore, followed by Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, and Thailand; China and India are now powering ahead; with Vietnam, Cambodia, Laos, and other Asian countries seemingly poised to participate in the Asian economic growth story as well. At times, such high levels of economic growth seem unstoppable. As shown in Figure 1.1, for the period from 1980 to 2006, the average real gross domestic product (GDP hereafter) growth rate for China, India, Japan, and “other Asian economies” (the Asian export economies as indicated in Figure 1.1) were respectively 9.8, 5.9, 2.4, and 5.7 per cent. If we exclude the impact of the 1997-1998 Asian financial crisis, real GDP growth rates would be even higher, especially for “other Asian economies”. Figure 1.1 Real GDP Growth in Asia: 1980 – 2006 Numbers in brackets are average real GDP growth rates 1980- 2006 Percent 20 China (9.78%) India (5.91%) Japan (2.38%) Others* (5.73%) 15 10 5 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 -5 -10 * Others include Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand. Source : IMF; authors’ calculations. This remarkable success has given rise to two opposing views about Asian development model (s).1 One is that all is well – indeed, in some ways things may be even better than they look and with some minor policy adjustments, there is no reason that the party cannot continue indefinitely. Asian economies are fondly referred to as the “miracle” economies and they epitomize the virtues of the capitalist system, although this capitalist system differs in many aspects from that in the western world. Openness to trade, high domestic savings and investment, 1 We focus on the common features of different Asian economic stories in this book. By no means does it suggest that there is only one Asian model of economic development, although economists, policy makers, and analysts from the academic and professional worlds often refer to the term “Asian economic model” and have delved into how the model has been working across Asia and over time at length. 1 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) emphasis on human capital development, a disciplined work force, relatively cheap labour, and economic-development-oriented macroeconomic and political policies have all been pointed out as the building blocks of the Asian model. The believers and followers of the Asian miracles are even committed to the view that the destiny of the world economy lies with Asia. The other view is that the economic boom in Asia is built on an inefficient institutional infrastructure and could come crashing down any minute. Systematic limitations such as underdeveloped financial systems, poor corporate governance, lack of sound legal frameworks and effective law enforcement, corrupt governments, and exchange rate management are time bombs haunting the Asian economies. The Asian crisis was a wake-up call for the region and brought to the surface these systematic limitations. Even in academic research, many authors believe that the so called “Asian model” – a common denominator that underlies the Asian success stories – does not stand the statistical evidence. Studying total factor productivity (TFP) in Asian countries, Kim and Lau (1994) and Young (1995) illustrated that the economic growth in Asia was mainly driven by input growth or factor accumulation, not through high rates of efficiency growth measured by TFP. To proponents of this view, the Asian model of development is no different from previously successful ones (for example, the growth of the former Soviet Union and the Warsaw Pact nations) – the secret, if any, is their extraordinary mobilization of resources and willingness to sacrifice current satisfaction for future gain (Krugman 1994). We take a middle road in this book. Instead of either defending or disputing the “Asian Model”, we acknowledge the difficulties of placing the very heterogeneous economies of Asia under one big umbrella – the Asian Model. Asia comprises more than 4 billion people (60 per cent of the world population) in 46 different nation-states. Asia demonstrates a huge disparity in economic development – while Japan and China are respectively the second and fourth largest economies in the world (measured by nominal GDP in 2006), Mongolia, Maldives, Bhutan, and Timor-Leste remain among the smallest. Due to its vast size (44 million km2 in area), a huge range of cultures 2 , environments, historical ties and government systems, Asia, including its economies, can hardly be described by using one single model. Despite this diversity, there are still some common features underneath the successful Asian economic stories. In this chapter, we offer evidence to highlight these common features. While we discuss how these common features work together to power forward the Asian economies, we also pinpoint the systematic limitations inherent in the Asian economies and their implications for Asia’s future. 1.1 Snapshots of the Asian economies in the past one hundred years 1.1.1 The Pre-Modern Period in Asia Asia was rich until quite recently and had been in the forefront of world development for at least two thousand years until the eighteenth or possibly even the early nineteenth century. Maddison (2001) estimated that Asia accounted for 70 per cent of global GDP for the year 1000 A.D., vis-à-vis only 9 per cent for Europe. China and India alternated in being the largest economy in the world from 1 A.D. to about 1800 A.D. Columbus, in his search for the fantasy land – India – accidentally discovered the Americas; the Silk Road had long been the main EastWest trading route. Asia had since suffered a deeply felt eclipse. Even worse, prior to World War II, most Asia countries were under colonial rule and only relatively few managed to stay independent (for 2 For example, there are more 600 languages spoken in Indonesia. More than 415 languages are spoken in India and more than 100 languages are spoken in Philippines. 2 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) example, Japan and Thailand). Due to the Meiji Restoration in 1868, Japan experienced massive institutional changes and development, and managed to develop its economy. Japan was the only Asian country that had kept pace with the industrial revolution in the West in the nineteenth century. The Japanese economy continued to grow well in the first half of the 20th century. Along the way, the fast growing Japanese economy created various shortages of resources essential to economic growth. To secure strategic resources, Japan started its aggressive expansion, beginning with neighbouring Korea and China and then moving into Southeast Asia. In a stark contrast, China’s economic performance was lacklustre during the same period. In the year 1800, per capita income in China, based on Bairoch’s (1993) estimate, was on par with that of Western countries. However, by the end of World War II, per capita income in Western industrialized countries was already a multiple of 6 of the average per capita income in China. China, once the largest economy in the world, was even overtaken by Japan in terms of per capita income as early as 1820. At the same time, Southeast Asia was prospering due to trade and the introduction of various new technologies of that time. The trade volume continued to increase with the opening of the Suez Canal in the 1860s. Singapore, founded in 1819, rose to prominence as trade between the east and the west increased. Malaysia, as a British colony, was the world’s largest producer of tin and rubber. Indonesia, a Dutch colony at the time, was known for its spice production. In 1908, crude oil was first discovered in Persia (now Iran). Afterwards, many oil fields were discovered and it was learnt later that the Middle East possesses the world’s largest oil supplies. This made the rulers of the Arab nations very rich, although the socioeconomic development in that region lagged behind. In 1937, Japan invaded China; in 1941, Japan invaded Malaya and began World War II in Asia. The war had an incredibly destructive impact across the region, destroying established trade networks; interrupting both physical and human capital development in Asia; and dragging the region into a series of geopolitical and ideological problems that were later proven to be detrimental to economic development. 1.1.2 The Post-War Period to the Asian Financial Crisis: 1945-19973 The post-war era eye witnessed new Asian success stories. The GDP growth rate and income per capita in Japan and subsequently in a group of newly industrialized economies (especially the four East Asian tigers – South Korea, Hong Kong, Singapore, and Taiwan) began rising significantly faster than those in the mature Western industrial economies. From 1955 to 1973, Japan maintained an unprecedented 10 per cent of GDP growth rate per annum. Between 1966 and 1990, the Singaporean economy grew a remarkable 8.5 per cent per annum. Taiwan, Hong Kong, and South Korea also achieved similar economic growth rates. Why Japan and the Four Asian Tigers grew so fast has drawn intense attention from the academic and professional worlds. Numerous reasons were suggested; the exact answers remain a heated debate. Obviously, the post-war geopolitical environment favoured Japan and other Asian economies. The United States supported Japan’s rapid economic growth because it was seen as a bulwark to stop the spread of communism (Das 2005). Hong Kong, South Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan also benefited from this geopolitical environment. The favourable environment opened up the US market and allowed Japan and the four tigers to develop labour-intensive, resourceintensive, and capital intensive industries (exactly in that order). 3 There is a library of literature discussing the Asian economies during this period. We will discuss at length the hows and whys in Chapter 1.2. Here we only offer a quick summary. 3 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Japan and the Asian tigers grasped this opportunity and grew through a mobilization of resources. In the case of Singapore, the employed share of the population surged from 27 to 51 per cent from 1966 to 1990. The financial system channelled high savings to high investment – as we will show slightly later (Chapter 1.2); investment as a share of GDP rose to 30-40 per cent during most of economic take-off era. The educational standards of the work force also increased dramatically – the literacy rate increased; college graduates as a share of total population rose; and more and more workers completed secondary education. To a certain extent, the economic success in Japan and the four Asian tigers can be largely accounted for by increases in measured inputs – such as resources, physical capital and participation of labour forces (Krugman 1994; Young 1995). On top of the dramatic factor input growth, sound macroeconomic policies especially the pervasive adoption of the export-led economic development strategy, a benign demographic structure, and eve-improving labour productivity did play their roles along the way. The success of Japan and the four Asian tigers provided a model, which other Asian economies consciously tried to emulate. Economies such as Malaysia, Thailand, Philippines and Indonesia followed the same development mode – resource mobilization and export-led strategy combined with sound macroeconomic policies – and achieved impressive growth. Until late 1970s, China adopted a state-led, central ownership and control economic model similar to that used by the former Soviet Union. While China was able to mobilize huge amounts of resources to develop heavy and chemical industries and had also achieved moderate success, economic development from time to time was disrupted by political turmoil. China’s lacklustre performance was even dimmer when compared to its smaller neighbours, especially in terms of per capita income. When China kicked off its reform policy in the late 1970s, its GDP per capita was only several per cent of that of its closest neighbours, Hong Kong and South Korea. China formally launched the “reform” and “open door” policy in 1978. Many components of the “Asian model” have been gradually introduced – attracting foreign direct investment, promoting export-oriented industries and so on. By 1990, China had become an energetic part of the rapidly growing and globalising Asia. Now, China is moving toward becoming the engine of Asian economic growth. India adopted socialist policies in most of the post-war era, which limited its economic growth (the so-called “Hindu rate of growth”). Beginning 1990, India started to liberalize the economy. Such efforts quickly made India one of the fast-growing economies in the region. Wars driven by the Cold War and ideological conflicts, notably in Vietnam, Cambodia, Laos, and Afghanistan, wrecked the economies of these respective nations. But now it seems that at least Vietnam is back in the race for economic development – the strategies in Vietnam now strongly resemble those adopted in the Asian tigers. Vietnam’s economy has been opened up and exports are driving its growth. Shortly after the United States and Vietnam restored economic and political ties, the Vietnam economy started to grow in 1995. Now it is poised to surge as a new economic tiger in Asia. When the Soviet Union collapsed in 1990-1991, many central Asian states announced independence and were forced to adapt to pressure for democratic and economic change. Those economies still heavily rely on natural resources and they are still in the process of searching for appropriate economic development models. Economically speaking, 1945-1997 was a golden time for an ever increasing percentage of Asia. More than forty years’ rapid economic growth surely impressed the world. To take the highest profile example at the moment, if the growth rate of the past quarter century were to continue, China would overtake the United States as the largest economy in the world somewhere in 2020s. If we measure the size of an economy by GDP computed at the purchasing power parity 4 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) (PPP), conservative estimates show that China is already the second largest economy in the world and will overtake the United States. to become No.1 in 10 years. It is tempting to seriously take such trend projections to forecast the future. However, as we will show in this Chapter and throughout this book, rapid Asian economic development does not come without costs. The rapid growth in most Asian economies has been built upon relatively weak institutional infrastructure. In order to maintain a high level of investment, labour force participation, and other inputs for economic growth, Asian governments have adopted a series of distorted policies which eventually lead to different types of imbalance in the economies. These risks loom large in Asia and from time to time trigger unfavourable dynamics between the real economic sectors and the financial sectors. The outbreak of Asian financial crisis in 1997 epitomized fully those imbalances. In some way, 1997 signalled the end of the fairy tales about the Asian economies – finally Asia was back to “real”. 1.1.3 The Asian economy today 2007 marked the tenth anniversary of the Asian financial crisis, an event (together with the aftermath of the bursting of the earlier Japanese bubble economy) that since overshadowed Asia. Yet 10 years since the crisis, doubts about Asia and its economies still linger. Have Asian firms and regulators made enough progress to prevent another meltdown? What are the implications of the underlying changes for the Asian economies? With the rapid ascent of China and India as new engines of Asian development, can Asia’s economies be the pillars of the world economy? Is there such a thing as the “Asian model”? To overcome the boom and bust cycles inherent in Asian economies, what improvements should be made? The list of questions goes on and on. Figure 1.2 Asia’s Size in the World Economy, 2005 Global GDP in 2005 = $ 44 trillion Rest of world 19% 31% Japan 10% 5% China 7% 28% Other Asia US Source : IMF; authors’ estimations. 5 EU Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Although about 60 per cent of the world’s population lives in Asia, the Asian economies as a whole only accounted for slightly over 22 per cent of global GDP in 2005. As a continent, Asia still lags behind Europe and North America in terms of the size of its economy (Figure 1.2). Moreover, the level of Asian economic development remains highly uneven – Japan and China together, as shown in Figure 1.2, have more than two thirds of Asia’s output, with the other fortyfour states accounting for the rest of one third. While GDP per capita (at current prices) reached the level of US$ 33,403 in Japan and US$ 27,483 in Hong Kong in 2006, Asia also includes some of the poorest nations in the world: GDP per capita is only a few hundred US dollars in Bangladesh, Myanmar, Nepal, Cambodia, Bhutan, Timor-Leste, and Mongolia. When the media and investors all around the world talk about booming Asia, they likely are only pointing to slightly more than ten Asian economies, which are mostly located in East Asia and Southeast Asia – the majority of Asian states are consciously left out. This is the true state of Asia’s economy. From Tables 1.1 to 1.11, we provide summary reports of economic, socioeconomic, and financial facts for eleven Asian economies: China, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan, and Thailand.4 We focus on various aspects of these Asian economies and provide a bird’s view of the state of Asia’s economy. All data are from 2006 unless otherwise specified. Facts should speak louder… 4 We note that we are making the same conceptual mistake as most media and global investors do – taking Asia as a continent consisting of the eleven economies and leaving out a large part of action in the region. 6 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.1 China Macroeconomics GDP ($ billion) GDP per capita ($) PPP GDP per capita ($) Exports ($bn/% of GDP) Imports ($bn/% of GDP) FDI inflow ($bn/% of GDP) FDI outflow ($bn/% of GDP) Foreign currency reserves ($bn/% of GDP) External debts ($bn/% of GDP) investment ($bn/% of GDP) Top 3 trading partners Number of firms in Global Top 500 GATT/ATO accession date 2,765 2,104 7,600 1,062/38 853/31 69.0/2.5 57.2/2.1 1,066/39 323/12 1,180/43 EU, US, Japan 20 11-Dec-2001 Socioeconomics Population (million) Number of Households (million) (2005) Mobile phones per 100 people Internet subscribers per 100 people Literacy rate, % (aged over 15) (2002) Gini Index (2002) % of population above 65 years old 1,314 407 33 9 90.9 44 7.7 Capital Markets & Banking Sector Number of listed firms 1,421 Equity market capitalization ($bn /% of GDP) 1,121/41 Trading volume ($bn /% of market cap) 1,639/123 Life insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 1.8 Non-Life insurance premium Volume / GDP (%)* 0.9 Private bond market capitalization / GDP (%)* 10.4 Public bond market capitalization / GDP (%)* 15.2 Private credit by deposit money banks and 135.3 other financial institutions / GDP (%)** Financial system deposits / GDP (%)** 164.8 Financial derivative traded on exchanges** NO Ratio of non-performing loans (%)** 15.6 Number of ATMs per 100,000 people** 3.8 Number of branches per 100,000 people** 1.3 All data are in 2006 unless otherwise specified.* Data in 2005. ** Data in 2004. Source: CEIC; CIA World Factbook; IMF; Fortune Magazine; authors’ calculations. 7 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.2 Hong Kong Macroeconomics GDP ($billion) GDP per capita ($) PPP GDP per capita ($) Exports ($bn/% of GDP) Imports ($bn/% of GDP) FDI inflow ($bn/% of GDP) * FDI outflow ($bn/% of GDP) * Foreign currency reserves ($bn/% of GDP) External debts ($bn/% of GDP) investment ($bn/% of GDP) Top 3 trading partners Number of firms in Global Top 500 GATT/WTO accession date 190 27,483 36,500 390/205 368/194 34/18 27/14 133/70 513/270 41/22 Japan, China, EU 0 23-Apr-1986 Socioeconomics Population (million) Number of Households (million) Mobile phones per 100 people (2005) Internet subscribers per 100 people (2005) Literacy rate , % (2002) Gini Index (2001) % of population above 65 years old 6.9 2.2 126 71 93.5 52.3 12.8 Capital Markets & Banking Sector Number of listed firms 975 Equity market capitalization ($bn /% of GDP) 1,704/897 Trading volume ($bn /% of market cap) 1,072/63 Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 8.6 Non-Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 1.3 Private Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 17.8 Public Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 9.1 Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions / GDP* (%) 141.9 Financial system deposits / GDP* (%) 242.3 Financial derivative traded on exchanges** YES Ratio of non-performing loans (%)** 2.2 Number of ATMs per 100,000 people** n.a. Number of branches per 100,000 people** n.a. All data are in 2006 unless otherwise specified.* Data in 2005; ** Data in 2004. Source: CEIC; CIA World Factbook; IMF; Fortune Magazine; authors’ calculations. 8 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.3 India Macroeconomics GDP ($billion) GDP per capita ($) PPP GDP per capita ($) Exports ($bn/% of GDP) Imports ($bn/% of GDP) FDI inflow ($bn/% of GDP) FDI outflow ($bn/% of GDP) Foreign currency reserves ($bn/% of GDP) External debts ($bn/% of GDP) investment ($bn/% of GDP) Top 3 trading partners Number of firms in Global Top 500 GATT/WTO accession date 924 843 3,700 212/23 238/26 11/1.2 n.a. 177/19 142/15 264/35 US, EU, China 6 1-Jan-1995 Socioeconomics Population (million) Number of Households (million) Mobile phones per 100 people Internet subscribers per 100 people (2005) Literacy rate, %, (2003) Gini Index (2000) % of population above 65 years old 1,096 n.a. 6.3 5.5 59.5 32.5 4.9 Capital Markets & Banking Sector Number of listed firms 4,796 Equity market capitalization ($bn /% of GDP) 1,579/171 Trading volume ($bn /% of market cap) 647/41 Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 2.6 Non-Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 0.6 Private Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 1.0 Public Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 32.9 Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions / GDP (%)* 36.8 Financial system deposits / GDP (%)* 52.2 Financial derivative traded on exchanges** YES Ratio of non-performing loans (%)** 6.6 Number of ATMs per 100,000 people** n.a. Number of branches per 100,000 people** 6.3 All data are in 2006 unless otherwise specified.* Data in 2005. ** Data in 2004. Source: CEIC; CIA World Factbook; IMF; Fortune Magazine; authors’ calculations. 9 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.4 Indonesia Macroeconomics GDP ($billion) GDP per capita ($) PPP GDP per capita ($) Exports ($bn/% of GDP) Imports ($bn/% of GDP) FDI inflow ($bn/% of GDP) FDI outflow ($bn/% of GDP) Foreign currency reserves ($bn/% of GDP) External debts ($bn/% of GDP) investment ($bn/% of GDP) Top 3 trading partners Number of firms in Global Top 500 GATT/WTO accession date 370 1,510 3,800 114/31 96/26 16/4.3 n.a. 43/12 125/34 91/25 Japan, Singapore, US 0 1-Jan-1995 Socioeconomics Population (million) Number of Households (million) Mobile phones per 100 people Internet subscribers per 100 people* Literacy rate, % (2002) Gini Index (2004) % of population above 65 years old 245 60 19.1 6.5 87.9 34.8 5.4 Capital Markets & Banking Sector Number of listed firms 344 Equity market capitalization ($bn /% of GDP) 138/37 Trading volume ($bn /% of market cap) 50/36 Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 0.8 Non-Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 0.7 Private Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 2.4 Public Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 16.6 Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions / GDP (%)* 21.8 Financial system deposits / GDP (%)* 36.2 Financial derivative traded on exchanges** YES Ratio of non-performing loans (%)** 13.4 Number of ATMs per 100,000 people** 4.8 Number of branches per 100,000 people** 8.4 All data are in 2006 unless otherwise specified.* Data in 2005. ** Data in 2004. Source: CEIC; CIA World Factbook; IMF; Fortune Magazine; authors’ calculations. 10 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.5 Japan Macroeconomics GDP ($billion) GDP per capita ($) PPP GDP per capita ($) Exports ($bn/% of GDP) Imports ($bn/% of GDP) FDI inflow ($bn/% of GDP) (2004) FDI outflow ($bn/% of GDP) (2004) Foreign currency reserves ($bn/% of GDP) External debts ($bn/% of GDP) investment ($bn/% of GDP) Top 3 trading partners Number of firms in Global Top 500 GATT/WTO accession date 4,269 33,403 33,100 687/16 634/15 34/0.8 32/0.7 880/21 1,513/35 1,028/24 US, China, EU 70 10-Sep-1955 Socioeconomics Population (million) Number of Households (million) Mobile phones per 100 people (2005) Internet subscribers per 100 people (2005) Literacy rate, %, (2002) Gini Index(2002) % of population above 65 years old 128 n.a. 74.0 67.4 99 38.1 20.0 Capital Markets & Banking Sector Number of listed firms 2,811 Equity market capitalization ($bn /% of GDP) 4,591/108 Trading volume ($bn /% of market cap) 5,912/129 Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 8.3 Non-Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 2.2 Private Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 42.4 Public Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 150.2 Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions / GDP (%)* 98 Financial system deposits / GDP (%)* 123.2 Financial derivative traded on exchanges** YES Ratio of non-performing loans (%)** 2.9 Number of ATMs per 100,000 people** 113.7 Number of branches per 100,000 people** 10.0 All data are in 2006 unless otherwise specified.* Data in 2005. ** Data in 2004. Source: CEIC; CIA World Factbook; IMF; Fortune Magazine; authors’ calculations. 11 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.6 South Korea Macroeconomics GDP ($billion) GDP per capita ($) PPP GDP per capita ($) Exports ($bn/% of GDP) Imports ($bn/% of GDP) FDI inflow ($bn/% of GDP) FDI outflow ($bn/% of GDP) Foreign currency reserves ($bn/% of GDP) External debts ($bn/% of GDP) investment ($bn/% of GDP) Top 3 trading partners Number of firms in Global Top 500 GATT/WTO accession date 912 18,882 24,200 394/43 384/42 11/1.2 18/2.0 239/26 263/29 272/30 China, EU, Japan 12 14-Apr-1967 Socioeconomics Population (million) Number of Households (million) Mobile phones per 100 people (2005) Internet subscribers per 100 people (2005) Literacy rate, % (2002) Gini Index(2000) % of population above 65 years old 48 18 79.9 70.6 97.9 35.8 9.2 Capital Markets & Banking Sector Number of listed firms 731 Equity market capitalization ($bn /% of GDP) 758/83 Trading volume ($bn /% of market cap) 913/120 Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 7.5 Non-Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 3.1 Private Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 52.8 Public Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 25.3 Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions / GDP (%)* 79.9 Financial system deposits / GDP (%)* 43.8 Financial derivative traded on exchanges** YES Ratio of non-performing loans (%)** 1.9 Number of ATMs per 100,000 people** 90.0 Number of branches per 100,000 people** 13.4 All data are in 2006 unless otherwise specified.* Data in 2005. ** Data in 2004. Source: CEIC; CIA World Factbook; IMF; Fortune Magazine; authors’ calculations. 12 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.7 Malaysia Macroeconomics GDP ($billion) GDP per capita ($) PPP GDP per capita ($) Exports ($bn/% of GDP) Imports ($bn/% of GDP) FDI inflow ($bn/% of GDP) *** FDI outflow ($bn/% of GDP) *** Foreign currency reserves ($bn/% of GDP) External debts ($bn/% of GDP) investment ($bn/% of GDP) Top 3 trading partners Number of firms in Global Top 500 GATT/WTO accession date 161 6,059 12,700 189/117 153/95 5/3.1 2/1.2 78/49 52/32 31/20 US, Singapore, EU 1 24-Oct-1957 Socioeconomics Population (million) Number of Households (million) Mobile phones per 100 people (2005) Internet subscribers per100 people (2005) Literacy rate, %, (2002) Gini Index(2002) % of population above 65 years old 27 n.a. 72.4 40.8 88.7 46.1 4.7 Capital Markets & Banking Sector Number of listed firms 1,027 Equity market capitalization ($bn /% of GDP) 239/148 Trading volume ($bn /% of market cap) 78/33 Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 3.7 Non-Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 1.9 Private Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 52.2 Public Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 38.2 Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions / GDP (%)* 117.8 Financial system deposits / GDP (%)* 105.9 Financial derivative traded on exchanges** YES Ratio of non-performing loans (%)** 11.8 Number of ATMs per 100,000 people** 16.4 Number of branches per 100,000 people** 9.8 All data are in 2006 unless otherwise specified.* Data in 2005. ** Data in 2004. Source: CEIC; CIA World Factbook; IMF; Fortune Magazine; authors’ calculations. *** FDI for Malaysia is referred to as equity investment in the CEIC database. 13 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.8 Philippines Macroeconomics GDP ($billion) GDP per capita ($) PPP GDP per capita ($) Exports ($bn/% of GDP) Imports ($bn/% of GDP) FDI inflow ($bn/% of GDP) FDI outflow ($bn/% of GDP) *** Foreign currency reserves ($bn/% of GDP) External debts ($bn/% of GDP) investment ($bn/% of GDP) Top 3 trading partners Number of firms in Global Top 500 GATT/WTO accession date 123 1,382 5,000 57/46 59/48 2/2 0.7/0.6 23/18.7 53/43 18/15 US, Japan, China 0 27-Dec-1979 Socioeconomics Population (million) Number of Households (million) Mobile phones per 100 people (2005) Internet subscribers per 100 people (2005) Literacy rate, % (2002) Gini Index (2003) % of population above 65 years old 89 n.a. 36.9 8.8 92.6 46.1 4.1 Capital Markets & Banking Sector Number of listed firms 240 Equity market capitalization ($bn /% of GDP) 146/119 Trading volume ($bn /% of market cap) 12/8 Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 0.9 Non-Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 0.6 Private Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 0.3 Public Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 38.4 Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions / GDP (%)* 30.6 Financial system deposits / GDP ( %)* 50.2 Financial derivative traded on exchanges** YES Ratio of non-performing loans (%) ** 24.7 Number of ATMs per 100,000 people** 5.3 Number of branches per 100,000 people** 7.8 All data are in 2006 unless otherwise specified.* Data in 2005. ** Data in 2004. Source: CEIC; CIA World Factbook; IMF; Fortune Magazine; authors’ calculations. *** FDI for Philippines is referred to as equity investment in the CEIC database. 14 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.9 Singapore Macroeconomics GDP ($billion) GDP per capita ($) PPP GDP per capita ($) Exports ($bn/% of GDP) Imports ($bn/% of GDP) FDI inflow ($bn/% of GDP) *** FDI outflow ($bn/% of GDP) Foreign currency reserves ($bn/% of GDP) External debts ($bn/% of GDP) investment ($bn/% of GDP) Top 3 trading partners Number of firms in Global Top 500 GATT/WTO accession date 137 30,430 30,900 346/252 302/221 5/3.6 n.a. 136/99 0/0 26/19 Malaysia, EU, US 1 20-Aug-1973 Socioeconomics Population (million) Number of Households (million) Mobile phones per 100 people (2005) Internet subscribers per 100 people (2005) Literacy rate, % (2002) Gini Index (1998) % of population above 65 years old 4.5 n.a. 97.4 53.8 92.5 42.5 8.3 Capital Markets & Banking Sector Number of listed firms 539 Equity market capitalization ($bn /% of GDP) 378/276 Trading volume ($bn /% of market cap) 183/48 Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 6.1 Non-Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 2.6 Private Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 18.8 Public Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 39.2 Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions / GDP (%)* 109 Financial system deposits / GDP (%)* 105.4 Financial derivative traded on exchanges** YES Ratio of non-performing loans (%)** 2.9 Number of ATMs per 100,000 people** 37.9 Number of branches per 100,000 people** 9.1 All data are in 2006 unless otherwise specified.* Data in 2005. ** Data in 2004. Source: CEIC; CIA World Factbook; IMF; Fortune Magazine; authors’ calculations. *** FDI for Singapore is referred to as foreign net investment commitment in the CEIC database. 15 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.10 Taiwan Macroeconomics GDP ($billion) GDP per capita ($) PPP GDP per capita ($) Exports ($bn/% of GDP) Imports ($bn/% of GDP) FDI inflow ($bn/% of GDP) FDI outflow ($bn/% of GDP) Foreign currency reserves ($bn/% of GDP) External debts ($bn/% of GDP) investment ($bn/% of GDP) Top 3 trading partners Number of firms in Global Top 500 GATT/WTO accession date (Chinese Taipei) 365 16,000 29,000 255/70 235/64 14/3.8 4/1.1 266/73 86/24 72/20 China, Japan, US 3 1-Jan-2002 Socioeconomics Population (million) Number of Households (million) Mobile phones per 100 people (2005) Internet subscribers/100 people (2005) Literacy rate, %, (2003) Gini Index % of population above 65 years old 23 n.a. 96.4 57.4 96.1 n.a. 9.8 Capital Markets & Banking Sector Number of listed firms 688 Equity market capitalization ($bn /% of GDP) 596/163 Trading volume ($bn /% of market cap) 735/123 Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 11.2 Non-Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 2.9 Private Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 28.1 Public Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 27.8 Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions / GDP (%)* n.a. Financial system deposits / GDP (%)* n.a. Financial derivative traded on exchanges** YES Ratio of non-performing loans (%) ** n.a. Number of ATMs per 100,000 people** n.a. Number of branches per 100,000 people** n.a. All data are in 2006 unless otherwise specified.* Data in 2005. ** Data in 2004. Source: CEIC; CIA World Factbook; IMF; Fortune Magazine; authors’ calculations. 16 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.11 Thailand Macroeconomics GDP ($billion) GDP per capita ($) PPP GDP per capita ($) Exports ($bn/% of GDP) Imports ($bn/% of GDP) FDI inflow ($bn/% of GDP) *** FDI outflow ($bn/% of GDP) *** Foreign currency reserves ($bn/% of GDP) External debts ($bn/% of GDP) investment ($bn/% of GDP) Top 3 trading partners Number of firms in Global Top 500 GATT/WTO accession date 218 3,354 9,100 161/74 152/70 7/3.2 0.8/0.4 67/31 60/28 61/28 Japan, EU, US 1 20-Nov-1982 Socioeconomics Population (million) Number of Households (million) (2004) Mobile phones per 100 people (2005) Internet subscribers per 100 people (2005) Literacy rate, %, (2002) Gini Index(2002) % of population above 65 years old 65 19 42.1 13.0 92.6 51.1 8.0 Capital Markets & Banking Sector Number of listed firms 476 Equity market capitalization ($bn /% of GDP) 142/65 Trading volume ($bn /% of market cap) 95/67 Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 2.0 Non-Life Insurance Premium Volume / GDP (%)* 1.6 Private Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 20.2 Public Bond Market Capitalization / GDP (%)* 21.1 Private credit by deposit money banks and other financial institutions / GDP (%)* 93.3 Financial system deposits / GDP (%)* 90 Financial derivative traded on exchanges** YES Ratio of non-performing loans (%)** 11.9 Number of ATMs per 100,000 people** 17.0 Number of branches per 100,000 people** 7.2 All data are in 2006 unless otherwise specified.* Data in 2005. ** Data in 2004. Source: CEIC; CIA World Factbook; IMF; Fortune Magazine; authors’ calculations. *** FDI for Thailand is referred to as foreign equity investment in the CEIC database. 17 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) 1.2 The common threads underneath the Asian success stories Identifying the common denominator of Asian success stories turns out to be not so outrageous. A careful examination of the driving forces behind rapid economic growth in Japan, the four East Asian tigers, surging smaller tigers, China, and India in recent years immediately yields several common threads – higher rates of savings and investment, export-led growth strategies, large pools of surplus labour, sound and relatively stable macroeconomic policies and benign external environments, and continuous improvements in productivity. 1.2.1 Investment! It has always been investment One of the most prominent features in Asia, from a real economic perspective, is that the rate of investment has always hovered at higher levels and thereby drives the economic development in different Asian economies. Critics of Asian economic miracles –the most notable being Paul Krugman and Alwyn Young – often argue that Asian economic development was nothing more than large amounts of measured inputs, especially the input of physical capital. Thanks to high savings and the Asian culture of sacrificing current for future satisfaction, Asian economies such as Japan, Singapore, South Korea, and China are able to mobilize resources (physical, human, and financial resources) and put them into economic development. This feature underpins the economic development of most Asian economies. In some sense, Krugman and Young are right – Asian economic stories have always been investment stories. As shown in Figure 1.3, the average savings rates in China, Japan, India, and the Asian export economies including Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, and Thailand for the period from 1970 to 2004 were respectively 35.4, 32.1, 21.2 and 29.9 per cent. Although the savings rate in India has been lower than other Asian economies, it is still significantly higher than the levels in the United States and most European countries. More importantly, Figure 1.3 shows that it is roughly going through an upward trend over time. High savings fuel higher investment. It is worth pointing out that focusing too much on a higher level of investment might be misleading in the sense that it downplays the important contribution of technological advancement in Asia. Productivity level increases along with economic growth – Japan was the first of this trend, and it has been repeatedly observed in other parts of Asia too. Still, the Asian economic story is largely an investment story. Fixed asset investment, especially capital expenditures on infrastructure and construction, has been driving economic growth. Figure 1.4 shows the fixed asset investment as a share of GDP in Asia for the period from 1980 to 2006. A first read of the figure leads to the conclusion that Asian economies invest a lot! Take Japan as the example. Although its fixed asset investment as a share of GDP has been steadily declining over the examined time period, it remains within the range of 24-34 per cent. The Asian export economies, including Hong Kong, Indonesia, Philippines, South Korea, Singapore, Taiwan, and Thailand, have fixed asset investment as high as 20-35 per cent of their respective GDPs. Likewise, China has maintained a spectacular investment record throughout the past quarter century. Even though the Chinese economy is still volatile and continuously goes through boombust cycles, fixed asset investment has been fixed at higher levels and has been driving the economy forward: in the past five years, investment as a share of GDP even exceeded 40 per cent. India started with relatively lower levels of fixed asset investment in the early 1980s, but its investment has since started to pick up, especially after India liberalized the economy in early 18 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) 1990s. In the past two or three years, the fixed asset investment in India has exceeded most of the Asia export economies and is approaching the level of 35 per cent. Figure 1.3 Gross National Savings as a Share of GDP Figure in Asia China (35.4%) India (21.2%) 45 Japan (32.1%) Others (29.9%) 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1970 1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 * Others include Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand. Source : World Bank Development Data; authors’ calculations. Looking only at investment data clearly is not enough. Another consideration is consumption and the role of the Asian consumer. Some observers claim that Asia is expecting a pending consumer “take-off” because of the economic development and changes in Asian people’s life styles (especially the increase in their propensities to consume). Domestic consumption thus is believed to be replacing fixed asset investment and exports to become the major driver of Asia’s economy (for research disputing this view, see Anderson 2006). This view challenges the traditional viewpoint about Asian economic development that exports and fixed asset investment are the major drivers of economic growth in Asia. If it is true, it will have many implications on our understanding of the Asian economies. However, as shown in Figure 1.5, it is not happening. We do not see an obvious upward trend in Asian people’s consumption. For Japan and Asian export economies (“others” in Figure 1.5), consumption as a share of GDP has been quite stable during 1980-2006. Domestic demand does has not yet taken off. For China and India, the two fast-growing economies now labeled new engines of the world economy, the share of consumption in GDP actually declines steadily. Such a pattern is more pronounced for India – in the past quarter century, the share of consumption decreased from 80 per cent to below 60 per cent. Although the Indian economy has many distinct features, it has one thing in common with other Asian economies – saving more, and investing more. 19 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Figure 1.4 Investment/GDP in Asia: 1980 – 2006 China 50% Asian Financial Crisis India Japan 45% Others* 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2000 2002 2006 * Others include Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand. Source : CEIC; authors’ estimations. Figure 1.5 Consumption/GDP in Asia: 1980 – 2006 China 85% India 80% Japan Others* 75% 70% 65% 60% 55% 50% 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 * Others include Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand. Source : CEIC; authors’ estimations. 20 2004 2006 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Box 1.1 GDP Accounting In a given open economy, the total output in a given time period (normally a year or a quarter) can be measured by gross domestic product (GDP). GDP consists of four components: GDP = C +I +G + X- IM, (1.1) where C is consumption (some call it private consumption), I stands for investment (nonresidential and residential included), G is the government spending (some call it government consumption), X stands for export, and IM is import. X-IM is also called net exports or the trade balance. That is, if exports exceed imports, we say that the country has a trade surplus. If exports are smaller than imports, then a country is said to run a trade deficit. One quick takeaway from Equation (1.1) is that GDP growth could be driven by any of the aforementioned four components – consumption, investment, export, or government spending, although in real economy the four components are always work together to drive the GDP growth. Implications. First, Asian economic development is still investment-driven. Revisiting Figure 1.4 demonstrates this point well from a different angle – the sharp drop in fixed asset investment after the Asian financial crisis (more than 5 percentage points for Asia export economies) led to the so-called Asian malaise, which affected Asia for almost ten years since 1997. Second, since investment plays such an important a role in Asian economic development, key things to watch out about the Asian economies include: 5 (1) Can fixed asset investment maintain at such high a level? (2) How efficient is the investment? (3) From where do the funds for investment come? 1.2.2 Export-led growth Trade has always been one of the most important aspects of Asia’s economies. All of the 11 economies we mentioned earlier are members of the World Trade Organization (WTO) (see Tables 1-11). Most Asian countries have been, and are still, very export-oriented. Figure 1.6 shows the ratio of exports to GDP – a common measure of an economy’s external exposure – for the Asian economies over 1980-2006. We start with the relative smaller economics (“others” in Figure 1.6). We see a clear and upward trend in the ratio of exports to GDP. Despite a slight decline in export/GDP after the Asian financial crisis, these export-led economies have gradually recovered and the level of export/GDP has gone back and even exceeded its pre-crisis level. Figure 1.7A shows that except for a few years, exports in those export-led economies have grown more than 10 per cent on a year to year basis. In early stages of Japan’s economic development, its economy had largely relied on exports. Now, the Japanese economy has become large enough to rely on domestic spending to drive its growth. However, given its size, a more than 15 per cent of export/GDP ratio still suggests that the external exposures of the Japanese economy are large and its economy is very 5 We will elaborate on the three things in Chapter 1.3. 21 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) sensitive to the changes in the global markets. Japan’s exports recovered in recent years too – the year to year export growth rate has been increased to 13.7 per cent in 2006 (Figure 1.7B). Figure 1.6 Export/GDP in Asia: 1980 – 2006 70% China 65% India 60% Japan Others* 55% 50% 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 * Others include Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand. Source : CEIC; authors’ estimations. Both China and India are large, fast-growing, domestic-led and insulated from the global cycle. In terms of the ratio of export to GDP, the levels in China and India are not comparable to those in export-led Asian economies such as Hong Kong, Singapore and Taiwan. But we do observe an upward trend in export/GDP for both nations (Figure 1.6). In early 1980s, the Chinese economy was relatively closed from the outside world. Exports however started to take off since mid-1980s, thanks to the reform and open door policies adopted by the Chinese government and a large amount of foreign capital swarmed into the export-oriented sectors. As shown in Figure 1.7C, since 1987, China has managed to maintain a year to year export growth rate close to 20 per cent except for 1989 (political instability), 1993 (credit tightening), 1998, 1999 (aftermath of the Asian financial crisis), and 2001 (burst of IT and telecommunication bubbles). In 2006, according to the estimates of the CEIC database, the total exports in China amounted to US$ 1,062 billion, which accounted for 38 per cent of China’s GDP. While it is naive to argue that exports are the sole driver of China’s economic development, its important role is undeniable. After following the stagnant decade of the 1980s, India’s exports gradually picked up and really took off in recent years. In 2006, exports had accounted for 23 per cent of India’s GDP, indicating that India is becoming an important participant of global trade. The trend demonstrated in India seems to suggest that India is emulating its Asian neighbours (at least partially) in the selection of economic development strategy. As shown in Figure 1.7D, the year to year growth rates of exports in India even dwarf those in China since 1990. [Insert Figure 1.7 ABCD here] It is not the end of the story. More and more Asian states have adopted export-oriented economic policies. The continued rise of low-end economies actually implies more export-led 22 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) growth to come – Vietnam has been lined up for next round of explosion of exports and economic growth, likely followed by Cambodia, Lao, Bangladesh, etc. Implications. First, the reliance on exports leaves the Asian economies vulnerable. Asia was, still is and will be in the foreseeable future, sensitive to economic changes in the United States and the European Union, especially for smaller Asian economies. This might not apply to China and India as their economies are still largely insulated from the US and EU and they both have sizeable domestic markets. But their reliance on exports and linkage to the global markets is creasing over time. As a result, they will be less and less immune to changes in the global markets too. Second, Japan remains the largest economy in Asia, as well as the largest buyer in this region, suggesting (1) Japan’s economic recovery is important for Asia’s economies; and (2) promoting intra-regional trade is important for the stable development – although China and India remain the fastest growing economies in the world, they are still relatively domestic-demandoriented and cannot drive Asia.6 Third, the export-led growth leads to a quick accumulation of foreign exchange reserves, which brings external pressures from the US and EU and greatly limits the spectrum of monetary and exchange rate policy instruments the Asian governments can use to fine tune their economies. In one word, Asian economies and financial markets are not sufficiently mature enough to generate their dynamics inside. They are still exposed to volatilities in the global markets and are not able to provide a counterbalance to US or EU on a global scale. 1.2.3 Sound fiscal, monetary and exchange rate policies A stable macroeconomic and policy environment is imperative for the implementation of the investment-driven and export-oriented growth strategies. In most of the post-war era, Asian governments have been prudent in designing and implementing their fiscal, monetary, and exchange rate policies. For developing economies, which include most of the Asian economies, governments are heavily involved in economic activities – besides running state-owned enterprises by themselves, governments also spend on education, infrastructure, pensions system, and so on. In the developing economies, tax revenues and the amount of capital the government can mobilize through financial system are normally limited. Governments thus are constantly attempted to run high levels of budget deficits. To meet the fiscal deficits, the governments have strong incentives to force their central banks to print more money or to borrow foreign debts. We have observed this type of governmental behaviour repeatedly in Latin American economies and African economies. However, it has been relatively rare in Asia due to various reasons to which we will come below. Asian governments in general have been quite restrained in their spending, especially compared to governments in most other developing economies. Figure 1.8 shows the budget balance as a share of GDP for the Asian economies vis-à-vis the United States. Due to a decent fiscal network and high levels of savings rate mobilized through more developed banking system, budget deficits in Asia are even below those of the United States. Inflation in Asia has also been quite low. Figure 1.9 presents the inflation for the Asian economies vis-à-vis United States since 1980. The inflation rate in Asia has been kept at one-digit 6 Economists believe that the trade data for China are misleading. For example, over half of mainland Chinese imports are for processing and re-export to third countries. Once the processing trade is taken away and re-assigned to their eventual financial destination market, China is not buying that much from their smaller neighbors (Anderson 2006). 23 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) level for most of 1980-2006. The average inflation rate for Asia export economies (“others” in Figure 1.9), measured based on the consumer product index (CPI), is about 8 per cent for the same time period. Although it is 3-5 percentage points higher than that of the developed economies such as the US and EU, it is significantly lower than the inflation rate seen in Latin American countries. Even Asia’s high inflation relative to the United States can be justified by economics theory. In fast-growing economies, productivity improves faster in labour-intensive manufacturing sectors and export sectors, which however also pushes up prices for agriculture, services, and other industries as wages and incomes rise. Therefore, the average inflation in a fast-growing economy should be high enough to avoid outright deflation in the areas where productivity is rising most rapidly. This is called the “Balassa-Samuelson effect”, which points to relative productivity growth differentials as a driver of inflation. Figure 1.8 Budge Balance As a Share of GDP: Asia vs. US China India Japan Budget Balance/GDP (percent) 4 Others* United States 2 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 -2 -4 -6 -8 -10 * Others include Hong Kong, Indonesia, South Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Taiwan, and Tailand. We do not include Singapore as its budge balances were consistently positive for majority of our sample period, which makes it an obvously outlier. Source : CEIC; authors’ calculations. Taking into account the fast-growing and export-led nature of the Asian economies, Asia’s inflation has been within a reasonable range and it is even comparable to that of the developed economies. This provides Asia with a relatively stable macroeconomic and policy environment to pursue its economic goals. As most Asian economies adopt the “export-oriented” strategy, managing exchange rate is an integral part of Asian economies’ portfolios of macroeconomic policy instruments. In most of the post-war era, Asian governments have been reasonably successful with their exchange rate management. We discuss this point by beginning with the Asia growth model. In order to growth, Asia needs to expand rapidly into labour-intensive manufacturing exports. Exports contribute significantly to Asia’s economic growth (this even applies to China and India now). The developed countries such as the United States and the EU are naturally the destination of the exported goods from Asia. To facilitate the exports, the Asian governments have incentives to peg their exchange rates to the US dollar at an undervalued level. Thus, they can keep the wages low at home and maximize the competitiveness of their products in the global markets. At times, Asian countries used this strategy. It results in current account surplus (deficit of current account 24 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) for the US). However, as long as the governments control private capital flows, the net export proceeds go directly into the central bank’s official foreign exchange reserves. Figure 1.9 Inflation Based on CPI: Asia vs. US Numbers in brackets are average inflation from 1980 to 2006 30 China (5.96%) India (8.03%) Japan (1.29%) 25 Others* (5.66%) United States (3.89%) 20 15 10 5 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 -5 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Year * Others include Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand. Source : IMF; authors’ estimations. This type of “imbalance” in exports and imports works pretty well in Asia. As long as Asian economies can export more and the developed economies are willing to import their goods and services, the imbalance does not matter much. However, as we will discuss in Section 1.3, this strategy does lead to some fundamental problems and from time to time, Asian countries are facing huge amount of pressure from the developed countries to re-valuate their currencies: the case of Japan in the 1980s and China in recent years, with the US and EU today pressuring China for a sharp and fast appreciation of China’s currency, the yuan. 1.2.4 Abundant supply of low-cost labour Asia’s demographic structure – more than 60 per cent of world population and relatively smaller fraction of population aged over 65 years old (Tables 1.1-1.11) – provides Asia with a huge supply of low-cost workers to become home of the world’s manufacturing workshop supplying everything from textiles to toys to computers. Although having 60 per cent of the world population, Asia only accounts for slightly over 20 per cent of global output. If we exclude Japan from the statistics for Asia, the share of global GDP contributed by Asia immediately drops to less than 15 per cent, which indicates that most Asian countries are low income or middle-income nations. The abundance of low-cost workers allows Asian countries to support economic growth by focusing on manufacturing exports. A research report issued by the consulting firm McKinsey & Company compares the hourly compensation for manufacturing workers in selected countries (Farrell, Puron and Remes 2005). In 2003, the average hourly compensation for manufacturing workers in United States, Canada and Mexico was respectively US$ 21.3, 18 and 2.1, while in China, Philippines, and India 25 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) the number was US$ 0.7, 0.7 and 0.4 respectively. That is, even Mexico’s labour cost is three times that of China. In Asia, besides China and India, there are many countries with labour costs even lower or at least comparable to that of China’s, including Indonesia (227 million), Bangladesh (133 million), and Vietnam (81 million).7 From the point of view of demographic structure, and taking Asia as a whole, the Asian model of development seems sustainable. Of course, no place can remain the world’s low-cost producer for ever – while we are seeing the “Made in China” stamp on almost everything now, we might be seeing the “Made in Vietnam” or “Made in Indonesia” stamps everywhere ten years from today. The education level of the Asian population is also improving over time, which allows some economies to gradually transform their industrial focus from low-cost manufacturing to services or high-end manufacturing sectors. For example, in 2003 China had roughly 9.6 million young professional graduates with up to seven years’ work experience and an additional 97 million people that would qualify for support-staff positions. China has about 1.6 million young engineers. About one third of university students in China study engineering, compared with 20 per cent in Germany. The talent pool is large. Since the heterogeneity in the economies and income disparity among people are both large in Asia, the trend described as a series of economic events has been repeatedly observed in the region – an economy started out in the simple, labourintensive parts of an industry but over time hone its skills and capabilities to compete in more profitable areas such as services sectors and high-end components of the value chain for a given sector – marketing, product design, research and development (R&D), and distribution. 1.2.5 Improvement in productivity? We have not discussed this factor until now as it is likely the most controversial factor about Asia’s economies. The conventional wisdom on the Asian economies, especially the East Asian newly industrialized countries (NICs), says that the productivity growth in these economies, especially in their manufacturing sectors, has been extraordinarily high. This seems to be consistent with experiences of Japan, the NICs and China. In his study of labour productivity in different countries, Lewis (2003) reports that Japan definitely has two faces – while some sectors in the Japanese economy has labour productivity significantly lower than that of the United States (e.g., retail, housing construction, food processing), sectors such as steel, automotive parts, metalworking, cars, and consumer electronics have higher labour productivity levels. It is interesting to note that the sectors in which Japan boasts higher labour productivities are also the sectors Japan has a competitive edge over the US, which indicates strongly that improvement in productivity matters a lot for economic development, and some Asian economies (at a minimum, Japan) has partially achieved that goal. South Korea, Hong Kong, Singapore, and Taiwan, China, India, and some other Asian economies have also made a stride in improving their levels of labour productivity, which significantly contributes to the growth in those economies. What accounts for the improvement in productivity? Many factors have been identified in empirical studies or suggested in theoretical research. It is a long list including benign fiscal/macroeconomic environment, reasonable input factor prices, appropriate income level and distribution, well-enforced labour rules and unionism, availability of skilled workers, welldesigned incentive mechanism, culture, product market competition and regulations, barriers to trade, capital intensity of the industry, operation efficiency, and etc. (see Lewis 2003). Among the numerous factors named above, educational attainment is particularly important. Young (1995) provides the educational attainment of the working population for the four East Asian tigers from 1966 to 1991 (Table 1.12). Obviously, from 1966 to 1991, during which the four economies had 7 Numbers in brackets are the population. 26 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) achieved astoundingly high economic growth, the education attainment of their working population improved significantly as well. In South Korea for example, the percentage of working population without any education dropped from 31 to 6.4 per cent, while about 75 per cent of the working population has finished secondary education or even more. The human capital accumulation directly explains a fraction of labour productivity improvement. Table 1.12 Educational attainment of the working population (%) Hong Kong 1966 1991 None 19.2 5.6 Primary 53.6 Secondary + 27.2 Singapore 1966 South Korea Taiwan 1991 1966 1991 1966 1991 55.1 nil. 31.1 6.4 17.0 4.5 22.9 28.2 33.7 42.4 18.5 57.2 28.0 71.4 15.8 66.3 26.5 75.0 25.8 67.6 Note: Self-taught included under primary. All percentages are calculated net of those reported as unknown. Source: Young (1995) The critics of Asian economic miracles believe that improvement in productivity is a misperception. The research by Young (1995) provided detailed analyses to identify a striking finding he believed that had been buried in statistics about Asia – while the growth of output and manufacturing exports in the four East Asian tigers (Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea, and Singapore) is virtually unprecedented, the growth of total factor productivity (a common measure of productivity) in these economies is not. Specifically, over the period from 1966 to 1991, productivity growth in the aggregate non-agricultural economy of the four NICs ranges from a low of 0.2 per cent in Singapore to a high of 2.3 per cent in Hong Kong, which is not impressive at all since France, the United Kingdom and Italy had achieved similar productivity growth during the same time period. In a recent academic article, Young (2003) applies similar analysis to China and claims that the Chinese model of development is no different from that of the NICs. When it comes to productivity – especially productivity measured by total factor productivity – the performance of Asia’s economies is not that spectacular. The debate is still on-going. Recent works, for example Hotz (2005), point out that results in Young (1995, 2003) are based on databases that need cleaning up. After correcting the data problems, many conclusions will no longer be valid. The debate will always go on as long as Asia’s economies continue to grow and attract attention from economists, practitioners and policymakers. The bottom line is that when it comes to the sustainability of Asian economic development, productivity matters a lot and it is likely one of the most fundamental drivers going forward. 1.3 The potential holes in the Asian model of development The Asian model of development, as we characterize in Section 1.2, has helped one after another Asian economies to unleash rapid growth. But the model does not come without costs. The success and sustainability of this model largely hinges on the following assumptions: • There exists an effective financial intermediation, which continuously channels the scarce capital to the most wanted and most profitable sectors in an economy. 27 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) • The reliance on foreign markets, especially the US and EU markets, can be taken as a pre-condition for economic development without worrying about the collapse of foreign markets, protectionism, and weak domestic consumption. • The trend of higher levels of savings rate will continue in Asia; meanwhile, Asia will continue to provide a large number of low-income workers. • The costs and welfare loss associated with the accumulation of international reserves can be managed at a sustainable level. The particular approach to macroeconomic and structural policies that have been adopted by the Asian governments can deliver high growth along with a reasonable degree of macroeconomic stability. • The regional competition, especially the competition for cheaper factor inputs (e.g., labour), will not generate imbalances and become a source of instability. • … That list obviously can go on and on. The key point is that not all of the above assumptions can hold in reality for all countries in all time. The weak or missing links in a certain Asian economy could easily trigger unfavourable economic dynamics, which, in the context of globalization, could spread to other Asian economies and have serious adverse repercussions on growth and welfare. 1.3.1 Costly financial intermediation As mentioned earlier, the Asian economies can largely be characterized by higher levels of fixed asset investment. Asia’s economy would grow even faster and in a much healthier way if the financial system in Asia can improve its efficiency and channel savings into more productive areas. Although Asia’s economies have grown at a very high rate, most economies’ financial systems are still under-developed. Using the ratio of the market capitalization of bonds and equities plus the market value of private credits extended by deposit taking and other financial intermediaries to GDP as a measure of the level of financial development, as shown in Figure 1.10, most Asian economies are less financially developed. On the face of it, Asia’s financial systems are better at allocating capital than are their counterparts in many other emerging markets economies. It has some high-performing private and foreign banks, and its stock of nonperforming loans, has been declining since the Asian financial crisis. It has relatively well-run equity markets. However, the most productive part of the economy is not the main recipient of funding from the financial system, causing significant social welfare loss and eventually endangering the stability of the economies. We use China and India, the two fastest-growing economies in Asia, as the examples. China China’s striking economic growth in the past quarter century has been largely driven by fixed asset investments. Three distinct features characterize the fixed asset investments during China’s reform period. First, due to a high gross domestic savings rate and success in attracting FDI, the rate of China's fixed asset investments has hovered at a high level, which from time to time raises the concern that China might have invested too much and the economy is overheating. Second, more than 50 percent of fixed asset investment concentrates in the state or quasistate sectors (Table 1.13), where productivity and investment efficiency are believed to be considerably low. Third, because the capital markets in China, including both the equity markets 28 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) and corporate bond markets, are poorly developed, bank lending has been the main funding source of China's investment boom. The excessive amount of capital allocated to the state sector causes widespread inefficiency among SOEs, reduces overall productivity of the economy and results in a large amount of non-performing loans. Prior literature has identified several sources of inefficiency in corporate investment, and attributes them to insufficient institutions and a low level of financial development. The foremost one is a state-dominated financial system that systematically allocates capital away from more productive sectors/regions towards less effective sectors/regions (see, e.g., Brandt and Li, 2003; Cull and Xu, 2003; Liu and Siu 2007, and Boyreau-Debray and Wei, 2005). Legally and financially, inefficient SOEs are favoured at the expense of more efficient non-state sectors (Huang, 2003). Figure 1.10 Financial Deepening vs. GDP Per Capita*, 2004 600% Financially developed 500% United States Switzerland 400% Financial deepening South Africa Malaysia Denmark Netherland 300% 200% Korea Less financially developed Chile China 100% India Thailand Spain France Japan Ireland Germany Norway Italy Brazil Philippines Indonesia Columbia 0% 1,000 Belgium Singapore UK Australia Sweden Russia Poland Mexico Argentina 10,000 100,000 Log GDP per capita (at PPP), 2004 * Degree of financial deepening is defined as the ratio of the sum of equity, bond and private credits (all in market values) to the PPP-based GDP. ** Hong Kong is an outlier with the degree of financial deepening at 694%, and GDP per capita measured at $34,200. Source : International Monetary Fund; CIA World Fact book; authors’ estimations. Despite numerous anecdotes and sound economic intuitions, it remains empirically difficult to map out the dynamic relations between corporate investment behaviour and institutions and financial development. Liu and Siu (2007) propose an innovative approach to quantify the investment efficiency across different sectors in China. They estimate structural investment models that characterize the Chinese firms’ investment behaviour to derive the effective discount rate perceived by firm managers in deciding investment spending. The “implied” cost of capital is similar to the managerial hurdle rate, and is potentially a function of variables measuring institutions and financial development. They thus infer the return on invested capital (ROIC) from firms’ actual capital expenditures. They document robust evidence that ownership is the primary institutional factor affecting the firm-level return on invested capital in China, and that return on invested capital for a non-state firm is approximately 10 percentage points higher than that of an otherwise similar state firm. 29 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Table 1.13 Fixed asset investment by corporate ownership 2000-2005 in China Fixed Asset Investment 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 SOE 1650.4 50.14% 1760.7 47.31% 1887.7 43.40% 2166.1 38.98% 2502.8 35.51% 2966.7 33.42% Collective 489.6 14.87% 537.3 14.44% 612.6 14.08% 819.8 14.75% 1018.3 14.45% 1219.9 13.74% Mixed 406.2 12.34% 566.4 15.22% 832.9 19.15% 1273.4 22.92% 1769.8 25.11% 2353.6 26.51% Private 470.9 14.31% 542.9 14.59% 651.9 14.99% 772.0 13.89% 988.1 14.02% 1389.1 15.65% HK/TW 129.3 3.93% 158.3 4.25% 176.5 4.06% 237.5 4.27% 311.4 4.42% 376.7 4.24% Foreign 131.3 3.99% 141.5 3.80% 168.5 3.87% 253.4 4.56% 385.4 5.47% 465.7 5.25% 19.8 0.46% 4349.9 100% 34.6 0.62% 5556.7 100% 72.1 1.02% 7047.7 100% 105.7 1.19% 8877.4 100% Others 13.9 14.2 0.42% 0.38% Total 3291.8 3721.3 100% 100% Source: China Statistical Yearbook Unit: RMB billion The least productive part of the economy (the state sector) obtains the most financing and makes most investment. This causes widespread inefficiency in the financial system and the economy. Figure 1.11 illustrates the deadweight loss in the bank lending market for SOEs. By the end of 2005, the total value of financial assets in the Chinese banking sector is RMB 34.14 trillion, 35 percent of which have been allocated to the SOEs, while SOEs only contribute to 25 percent of industrial output in China (sources: PBOC; and Farrell et al. 2006). Since the interest rates have been regulated throughout China's reform era, let assume that the interest rate applied to SOEs is set to be at r, which is lower than market rate, r*. Instead of accepting the market rate, the state sector can borrow money at r, which has been intentionally designated to them at a lower level. Their excess demand for bank lending by the state sector thus is given by K*-K. The deadweight loss is given by area A in Figure 1.11, which can be computed as: deadweight loss= 1/2(K*-K) (r*-r). Using the above approach, Liu and Siu (2007) compute the size of deadweight loss. They find that the deadweight loss in the banking market for SOEs due to the mis-allocation of capital to be RMB 186.4 billion in 2005. The total deadweight loss in the financial system amounts to 4 percent of China’s GDP in 2005, which might have been greatly underestimated since it does not account for the financial distortion in the service sectors and opportunity costs. 30 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Figure 1.11 The Welfare Loss Due to Distorted Lending Decision in China’s State Sector Price, r r* A Deadweight Loss r K K* Quantity, K India The situation in India is similar to that in China. The private corporate sector, as the most productive part of the economy, is not receiving financial support from India’s financial system due to various institutional deficiencies. Most of the funding goes to the government and to investments it designates as priorities. Private corporations receive just 43 percent of the country’s total commercial credit and that level has not increased since 1999 (Farrell and Lund, 2005). The rest goes to SOEs, agriculture, and the tiny businesses in the unorganized sector. This pattern of capital allocation impedes growth because SOEs in India, as China’s, are, on average, only half as productive as private ones and require twice as much investment to achieve the same additional output. Productivity in the agricultural and unorganized sectors is only one-tenth as high as it is in India’s modern private sector, and their investment efficiency is commensurately low. The Indian government’s tight control of the financial system explains its poor allocation of capital. Regulations oblige banks and other intermediaries to direct a high proportion of their funding to the government and its priority investments. Banks must hold 25 percent of their assets in government bonds. Government policies require banks to direct 36 percent of their loans to agriculture, household businesses, and other priority sectors, Directed loans have relatively high default rates and are costly to administer because of their small size. Besides diverting credit from the more productive private sector, these policies reduce the overall level of lending, since the unprofitable directed loans of banks must expand in proportion to their discretionary loans. Banks therefore lend just 60 percent of their deposits, compared with 83 percent for Thai, 90 percent for South Korean, and 130 percent for Chinese banks (also shown in Figure 1.9). Similar policies require 90 percent of the assets of provident funds (essentially pension funds) and 50 percent of all life insurance assets to be held in government bonds and related securities. As a result, these policies have allowed India’s government and SOEs to absorb 70 percent of the savings that Indian households and foreign investors have channeled into the financial system since 2000 (Farrell and Lund, 2005). The government’s tight control of the financial system lowers its efficiency and raises the cost of financial intermediation. India now has one of the highest levels of state ownership of 31 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) banks in any major economies. The prevalence of state-owned banks means that they experience little competitive pressure to improve the way they operate, which leads to lower profitability, less sophisticated business models, and potentials for higher levels of NPLs. Based on McKinsey’s estimates, an integrated program to reform the financial system could substantially raise India’s growth rate. If the system improved its allocation of capital, captured more savings, and reduced its operating inefficiencies, India’s real GDP could expand by 9.4 percent a year (Farrell and Lund, 2005). 1.3.2 Adverse changes in the demographics/savings dynamics Asia’s development model, as mentioned earlier, is largely based on two important pillars – high savings rate and availability of a large number of low-income young workers. Although Japan and the four East Asian tigers have successfully transformed their economies and are gradually migrating to high profit-margin products and services, a large part of Asia still relies on labour-intensive export manufacturing sectors. Even for economies like China and India, which are less export-dependent, labour-intensive manufacturing or services sectors are still their pillar industries. Figure 1.12 The Aging Asia % of population above 60 US$ billion 2000 2005 2050 30.2 22.6 20.5 20.0 13.0 11.2 7.2 East Asia Southeast Asia 18.0 11.5 11.0 7.1 7.0 South Central Asia West Asia Source : United Nations. Throughout Asia, the demand for labour comes from every front – from the large foreignowned companies and joint ventures to domestic firms of all sizes. However, demographics might not be in Asia’s favour anymore – Asian’s population is aging and gets grayer. The problem is pressing now in Japan as the percentage of population aged above 65 has exceeded 20 percent. In other parts of Asia, aging is also becoming an issue, even though it might not be as urgent as that in Japan. The United Nations estimated the aging situation in Asia (Figure 1.12). As to 2005, the percentage of population over 60 in East Asia has reached 20.5 percent. 8 The percentage is a bit lower in Southeast Asia (13 percent), South Central Asia (11.5 percent), and West Asia (11 percent). However, the estimates show that by 2050 the percentage of population over 60 years in 8 The official retirement age in most Asian economies is 60 years old. 32 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) East Asia, Southeast Asia, South Central Asia, and West Asia will be respectively 30.2, 22.6, 20, and 18 percent. The implication is obvious – Asia will be short of workers if it continues to focus on labour-intensive sectors. Aging will also bring lots of other social problems, which are beyond the scope of this book. But one consequence that is particularly relevant in Asia is that an aging society might undermine another pillar of Asian model of development – high savings rate. Due to improvements in health care and living conditions, average life expectancy has increased dramatically around the world. As the elderly come to make up a larger share of the population, as we are seeing in most of the developed countries and will see in majority of Asian economies in the future, the total amount of savings available for investment and wealth accumulation will dwindle – for an average person, the prime earning years are roughly from age 30 to 50; thereafter savings rate falls. In Asia, the issue becomes more complicated as the younger generation do not save as much as their parents and grandparents did – due to a tendency to rely more on inheritance; the good fortune to avoid the economic hardships that prompted earlier generations to be more frugal; and the availability of consumer credit and mortgages. As a consequence, the household financial wealth will decline as the population gets older. Once the financial wealth declines or fails to growth as fast as they used to be, the high-investment driven Asian economies will be seriously challenged especially given that financial intermediation in Asia has always been inefficient. However, how to fill the coming gap between investment and availability of financial wealth remains an uneasy task. Potentially a few approaches are available to solve the problem: (1) increasing birth rate; (2) increasing immigration, which may solve the problem in a small economy but not the problem in a larger economy like Japan or China; (3) increasing the retirement age by 5 to 10 year, which may delay the outburst of the aging problem but cannot solve it; and (4) increasing savings by current young generation. All these approaches only have limit impact. The best approach, as suggested in Farrell, Ghai, and Shavers (2005), is to boost the appreciation of financial assets, in other words, to improve the average rate of financial asset return. To make this approach work requires an economy’s financial system to be sophisticated enough – providing a wide range of financial products; greater skills in managing risks involved; mobilizing resources and handling all types of mismatches (e.g., quantity, maturity, risk profiles) through better financial innovations. Does Asia have an answer? 1.3.3 Unfavourable changes in macroeconomic and policy environment Asian governments have been adopting a set of fiscal, monetary and exchange rate policies that promote exports and investment. As discussed in Chapter 1.2, these policies have been quite successful in terms of providing a stable and favourable environment to develop economies. However, the good times have led to a build-up of imbalances as well. The build-up of those imbalances may eventually make certain major adjustments – note that we are quite careful and do not use the term “crisis” here – inevitable. Trade imbalance The exports-led strategy promotes trade imbalance, which increases Asian countries’ reliance on the US economy or the European economies. As old saying goes, “When the US sneezes, Asian catches a cold!” As the Asian economies become more complex and integrated with the world trade and financial system, they become more exposed to shocks, which may 33 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) come from many sources – a collapse of external demand, U.S. trade sanctions, competition for cheap input factors, regional political tensions over sensitive political issues (e.g., Iran, North Korea, Taiwan, etc.). Internally, over-reliance on trade could lead to some internal imbalances as well. Since the financial system in most Asian economies in still in poor shape and has distorted domestic demand, the patterns of investment financing could lead to the surge of nonperforming loans (NPLs) by fuelling a build-up of excess capacity in some industries especially the exports industries. Another potential problem associated with the strategy of promoting the exports sectors and piling up trade surplus is that it may repress other sectors in the economy. In many Asian economies, even including China, export sectors are largely driven by foreign direct investment, which are attracted by preferential policies such as tax breaks, free land use rights, easy and cheap access to financing, and so on. Those policies however do not necessarily apply to domestic firms. It is believed that over-reliance on exports sectors represses the domestic firms and nonexports sectors (see Huang 2003 for study on China). It may constrain the development of financial system as well. The financial system in the export-led economies can make easy and safe profits by over-allocating financing to the exports sectors, which limits the access to capital by other sectors in the economies. In addition, the financial intermediaries in those economies lack incentives to develop a wide range of financial products/services to enlarge their reach. Quick accumulation of foreign exchange reserves Figure 1.13 Accumulation of Foreign Reserves in Asia Unit: US$ billion China 1200 India Japan Others* 1000 800 600 400 200 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 * Others include Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, Taiwan, Thailand (Indonesia, Malaysia and Philippines start in 2000 as previous years’ data are missing). Source : CEIC; authors’ calculations. One prominent change in the Asian economies in recent years is that Asia has seen an unprecedented flood of foreign exchange liquidity rushing into domestic economies through official foreign exchange reserve accumulation, thanks to recovering exports on the part of Asia and relatively weak domestic demand. As shown in Figure 1.13, foreign exchange reserves in 34 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) China, Japan, and other parts of Asia started to take off since the beginning of this decade. China over-took Japan sometime in 2005 to become the country with the largest foreign exchange reserves in the world. The total amount of foreign exchange reserves, by the end of 2005, had reached US$ 1 trillion in China. For the same period, Japan and other Asian economies (Taiwan, Singapore, Hong Kong, South Korea, Thailand, Indonesia and Philippines) continue to accumulate large amounts of foreign exchange reserves. Notably, India, which used to be economically inward, is piling up its foreign exchange reserves as well. The cumulative official holdings of foreign exchange reached US$ 3 trillion in Asia as of December 2006, two thirds of which were accumulated since 2000. One direct consequence of the rush of foreign exchange inflows is that the government has to interfere in the foreign exchange markets – central banks have to buy them from commercial banks. When the central banks do so, they create an offsetting amount of domestic liquidity, which is credited to commercial banks’ reserve accounts, as a result of the transaction. For example, for every US dollar the People’ s Bank of China (PBOC, China’s central bank) purchases from commercial banks such as the Bank of China, PBOC places about RMB 7.7 Yuan to Bank of China’s reserve account with PBOC. Bank of China then will have additional based money (RMB 7.8 Yuan) to lend, which eventually lead to more money supply in the economy. That is, when central banks buy dollars they also automatically print money at home. Thus, when Asian central banks have bought up unprecedented amounts of foreign exchange, they have also been creating domestic liquidity in equally unprecedented amounts – reserve accumulation has been a very large part of existing money stock in Asia. For countries that run a fixed exchange rate system, they essentially give up control of domestic monetary policy (e.g., the case of Hong Kong). And if the currency is undervalued such as China’s currency Renminbi, high liquidity inflows may lead to low real interest rates, strong credit growth, higher inflation and finally asset bubbles. To deal with the above problems, the governments have to aggressively sterilize (see Box 1.2), just like what Taiwan, Malaysia, Singapore, Korea, China and India are doing now. However, there are costs associated with central banks’ sterilization. When central banks issue short-term debt instruments to the commercial banks, they generally have to pay a market rate of interest to attract the funds. In fact, the only method that does not involve a market cost for the central banks is hiking reserve requirements to tighten credits. Of course, central banks can also making money by sterilizing because they can invest their large amounts of foreign exchange reserves in the global financial markets. As a matter a fact, almost every single central bank in Asia is earning a positive return on total foreign exchange operations – either because the costs of sterilization are low, or else because banks do not engage in sterilization in those cases (e.g., Indonesia and Philippines) where interest rates are high. Box 1.2 Sterilization Sterilization means the monetary authorities attempt to sterilize the capital inflows through offsetting borrowing operations to reduce liquidity. For example, central banks can sell government bonds, issue their own bonds, lock up the money in time deposit, or simply freeze liquidity through administrative measures such as reserve requirements. The purpose of sterilization is to sterilize the effect of foreign exchange purchases on domestic base money by effectively borrowing back the funds. The implications of quick accumulation of foreign exchange reserves and central banks’ sterilizations on the Asian economies are not always favorable. First, Asian economies lose corporate, national, even regional autonomy due to over-reliance on exports and large amounts of 35 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) foreign exchange reserves. For countries practicing pegged exchange rate or quasi-pegged exchange rate systems, it implies the outright loss of the independence of monetary policies or greater limitation in the spectrum of monetary policy instruments the government can adopt. Second, the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves also indicates welfare loss. Due to inefficient financial intermediation, especially lack of alternative investment venues, majority of foreign exchange reserves in Asia flows outside the region again – they are re-directed to the US financial markets or European financial markets – and are not servicing the Asian economies. Third, the accumulation of foreign exchange reserves may also lead to excessive liquidity in domestic economies when sterilizations fail or when the costs of sterilizing outweigh the benefits. As mentioned earlier, excess domestic liquidity may lead to lower real interest rates, strong credit growth, higher inflation and finally asset bubbles. Although the inflationary pressures have not been felt in Asia now mainly because for most Asian economies the domestic demands are still weak and have not fully recovered from the Asian financial crisis, the long term risks are high. Without effective financial intermediation, lower real interest rates and strong credit growth cause over-heating economies, especially over-investment in certain sectors in an economy. Without effective financial intermediation, there is a lack of alternative investments. Excessive liquidity will swarm into available assets such as real estate and equities, leading to asset bubbles, for example, the real estate bubbles in Japan and Hong Kong back in 1990s and arguably the on-going stock market bubble in mainland China. To sum up, the macroeconomic environment and policies that have supported the growth of Asia so far are also constraining the flexibility and potency of macroeconomic tools Asian government can choose to deal with negative shocks that hit the economies. 1.4 Asian Financial Crisis The cause and ensuing contagion of the 1997-1998 Asian financial crisis has been a subject of much debate. Most explanations have focused on macroeconomic factors including underlying vulnerabilities in financial sector and inconsistent macroeconomic policies. In our view, the root causes of the crisis were at the micro-level – Asian companies’ excess leverage and low profitability. Weak policies and loose corporate governance practice related to inadequate bank supervision and implicit guarantees, led to poor credit decisions, and consequent misallocation of resources. 9 The crisis thus epitomized how the holes in the Asian model of development, when encountering a series of exogenous shocks, failed to generate virtuous dynamics between the real economic sector and the financial sector. We discuss the build up of Asian financial crisis and the lessons leaned. We focus on Thailand because the origin of the Thai crisis and the ways it unfolded were surprisingly similar to those of ensuing crises in other parts of Asia including Korea, Malaysia, and Indonesia. Unless otherwise specified, the structure factors we discuss about the Thai crisis can be directly applied to other Asian economies that were contagious in 1997-1998. 1.4.1 Overview of the financial crisis in Thailand The events in 1997 did not happen in a vacuum. They were the culmination of years of lax monetary policies, loose corporate governance, and sluggish corporate sector performance. The Thai crisis began to unfold in 1997 when currency speculators launched a concerted attack on its currency, the Baht. It was triggered when the Thai central bank’s reserves proved 9 Economist Paul Krugman has used the term “crony capitalism” to describe this type of practice. 36 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) inadequate to protect the Baht, forcing Thailand to give up the fixed exchange rate system and to float its currency. The ability of the banking sector to service debts, especially debts denominated in foreign currencies, declined as foreign reserves fell. It however started with problems in real sectors. After the runaway investment in the real estate in earlier 1990s, the asset-bubble bust in late 1996. The bust of the asset bubble greatly weakened the health of the financial intermediaries as a large fraction of lending were directed to the property and related sectors. For example, Finance One, Thailand’s leading finance company was under serious threat of default. In February 1997, Thailand’s prominent property company, Samprasong Land, missed payments due on its foreign debt, kicking offer another round of dramatic fall in the property sector. In the next six months, the Bank of Thailand (BOT, Thailand’s central bank) lent money to distressed financial intermediaries through its Financial Institutions Development Fund (FIDF). The BOT had committed almost all of its liquid foreign exchange reserves to forward contracts. The concerns continued to mount. The speculators thus correctly guessed that the combination of slow export growth (which implied slow accumulation of foreign reserves) and financial distress would ultimately require a devaluation of the Baht. In May 1997, international speculators launched the second attack on the Baht. In June 1997, the Thai Government reneged on promise to buy $3.9 billion pf bad debt from Finance One, announcing that creditors (including foreign creditors) would incur losses, contrary to previous announcements and market expectations. The shock accelerated the withdrawal of foreign funds and prompted the currency depreciation of nearly 50 percent by late 1997. In turn, the Thai Baht devaluation triggered capital outflows from the rest of East Asia. In June 1997, domestic real interest rate in Thailand further increased. The Thai government started to impose currency control. Foreign investors’ concerns over Thai financial intermediaries’ ability to serve foreign debts continued to grow. By July, Baht was allowed to float… The effect of the crisis on the Thai economy was devastating. Interest rates, which had been approximately 5 percent, rose to nearly 10 percent in 1998. This was done in order to stabilize the currency and to control inflation, but the result was a plummeting of the economy as GDP contracted 8 percent in 1998 according to IMF’ estimate. The un-employment rate increased by about 5 percent from 1997 to 1999. The economic decline led to a severe erosion of the asset quality of banks. The ratio of NPLs jumped to somewhere between 50 –75 percent of banking assets. The nationalized banks, in particular, appeared to suffer from a high level of “strategic NPLs” – borrowers who stopped payments after the government signaled that it would intervene to bail out the banks. These strategic NPLs were made possible by Thailand’s hitherto ineffective bankruptcy laws. 56 finance companies were closed and foreign banks took a controlling share of several domestic banks. The average return on equity (ROEs) for the Thai banks in 1997 was negative 160 percent. The Thai baht lost as much as 55 percent of its value by early 1998, and foreign funding stopped flowing into Thailand. 1.4.2 How did the financial crisis build up? One particularly aspect of the Thai financial crisis was on its over-reliance on foreign bank funding to maintain the integrity of its financial system. The conventional wisdom holds that portfolio investment, held by foreign “speculators,” is particularly volatile, and that these speculators tend to pull their money out at the first sign of trouble. Bank funding, it is often assumed, is more stable. However, the Thai financial crisis showed that it was not the case. The financial crisis in Thailand was driven in large part by the foreign bank funding. Deregulation and liberalization of the financial markets and intermediaries generated a credit boom. Foreign capital flowed into Thailand to grasp booming opportunities in the Thai economy. A large part of foreign funds flowed to riskier sectors, in particular the real estate market. Over time, the banking 37 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) system and the entire integrity of the financial system became reliant on the maintenance of real estate prices. The large inflow of foreign funding, primarily from Japanese banks, meant that more and more funds were chasing fewer and fewer good investments, which fanned the flames of corporate value destruction. Additionally, the government policy of pegging the exchange rate contributed to an overvaluation of the baht. It also led to a currency mismatch. All of these factors led to situation in which the entire Thai financial system was ripe for a major crisis. To understand how financial crisis unfolded in Thailand. We study the build-up of the crisis by beginning with the dynamics of funds taken and directed to real sectors by financial intermediates in Thailand.10 I. Funds dynamics The Thai government gradually deregulated and liberalized the financial sector in 1990s – first, the interest rate ceilings were lifted, followed by the lifting of exchange control; the government then allowed the establishment of offshore banking facilities. Financial deregulation and liberalization fueled a credit boom from 1990 to 1997, with bank liquidity increasing through offshore borrowing. It also led to the emergence of other largely unregulated non-bank intermediaries such as finance companies, which were allowed considerable latitude to borrow from abroad. Finance companies and banks took advantage of extremely low-interest yendenominated loans, borrowing heavily from overseas financial intermediaries (especially, from Japan). As a result, the net foreign liabilities of financial intermediaries rose from 6 percent of domestic deposit liabilities in 1990 to 33 percent by 1996, and net foreign liabilities ballooned from $22 billion in 1993 to $78 billion in 1996 (source: Bank of Thailand). The large inflow of foreign funds drove the credit boom in 1990s. The Bangkok International Banking Facility (BIBF) was a major reason for the inflow of foreign funds. Its design and its special incentives actively encouraged the increase in external debt of the financial intermediaries which in turn shifted the money into the real economy. The overabundance of funds flowing into the country from foreign sources meant that money ultimately was going to fuel more and more speculative investment, particularly in real estate sector. By the end of 1996, the banking system’s exposure to the property sector and related equities stood at 41 percent of total loans, compared with 23 percent for manufacturing. As a result, the health of the banking system became increasingly dependent on the maintenance of property prices, a critical factor in the emergence of the banking crisis. There was a lack of prudent regulations in Thailand as well. Financial policies are designed by entrenched groups in the business sectors, with direct credit granted to politically favored firms and industries and questionable lending allowed within conglomerates. Banks were owned by politically well-connected individuals, who used them to finance the operations of affiliated companies. This “crony capitalism” led to poor credit decisions in the banking system and to the misallocation of resources from potentially high return investments to those with significant risk and relatively low returns. These weaknesses in the financial system were exacerbated by structural weaknesses which were reflected in the following aspects: 10 • Poorly regulated and unsupervised banks protected from international competition • Lack of prudential regulation and supervision of financial intermediaries For a more detailed recount of the financial crisis in Thailand, see Barton, Newell, and Wilson (2003). 38 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) • Loose disclosure requirements • Lack of transparency of public and private financial intermediaries; inadequacy of bankruptcy law and procedures • Bank capital requirements were low or not met in practice • Immature capital markets As a result, the lack of relative balance in the development of the financial markets led to a dependence on the banking sector – Thailand’s financial system was overwhelmingly driven by banks and by bank-funded or controlled finance companies. Outstanding bank loans to non-banks accounted for 89 percent of Thailand’s private sector liabilities in 1997. In comparison, equity market capitalization accounted for only 15 percent of GDP in 1997. Clearly – Thailand followed a “high-debt” growth model before 1997. II. The dynamics in corporate sectors There is a strong link between the financial system and the underlying economy. The capital inflows financed increases in investment activities over 1990-1997. Meanwhile, the pegged currency contributed to the overvaluation of the Baht and thus led to a growing current account deficit. The large capital inflows challenged the economy’s ability to productively deploy them and resulted in the buildup of excess capacity. The investment spending spree contributed to erosion of profit margins and poor financial performance as reflected by declining return on invested capital (ROIC). Thus, credit quality in the private sector eroded, manifested by a fall in interest coverage from 4.6 times in 1992 to 1.9 times in 1996. As shown in Table 1.14, from 1992 to 1996, debt as a percent of equity increased from 71 percent to a high 155 percent. And Thailand was not alone. Similar growth was also evident in Korea, Malaysia, and Indonesia. Leverage ratios for Asian Firms were significantly higher than firms in developed economies. Such a high leverage ratio left the corporate sector vulnerable to shocks. Figure 1.14 Corporate Investment Efficiency: the 1992 –1996 average Return on Capital Employed (RCOE) Hong Kong 20 Indonesia U.S. 3 16 8 Thailand Japan -2 9 7 Singapore -9 9 11 Philippines Germany 12 20 8 Malaysia Economic Value Added* 8 11 Korea France Lending interest rate -9 6 2 7 16 5 -8 8 4 -3 12 5 4 11 -8 1 7 4 * Economic value added (EVA) is defined as (ROCE – Cost of Capital) multiplied by invested capital. In this figure, we only report the gap between ROCE and lending interest rate. Source : World Bank; World Development Indicators, 1998; authors’ calculations. 39 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Lower levels of return on invested capital led to value destruction in most sectors in the economies. Poor corporate governance and the fact that much of the economy was dominated by family-owned conglomerates allowed this value destruction to continue (see Chang (2003) for the cases in South Korea). These conglomerates lacked independent directors and often channeled investment funds into related companies, taking advantage of institutional deficiencies. They also leveraged government and corporate relationships to protect their portfolios to enter new business sectors, to overcome regulatory barriers, and access the advantage credit line. Often, these conglomerates owned their own banks or at least held shares in banks, which allowed them easy access to credit. As a consequence, economic value added (EVA) – a concept defined as the gap between return on invested capital and cost of capital multiplied by total invested capital – was negative for many Asian firms, especially Thai firms. Negative EVA – the fact that the return on investment is smaller than the average cost of raising capital – suggests that firms should have forgone the investment because it destroys value. However, institutional deficiencies such as lack of financial discipline and poor corporate governance encouraged firms’ spending spree. The various Asian economies, especially Thailand, thus witnessed lower levels of investment efficiency. Figure 1.14 presents the average return on capital employed (ROCE), lending interesting rate, and their difference for 11 economies in the world during 1992 – 1996, among which seven are in Asia and four of them (Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, and Thailand) were badly hit during the crisis. The average gap between return on capital and cost of capital, as shown in the last column of Figure 1.14, was -8 percent for Thailand, -9 percent for Indonesia, -2 percent for Korea, and 3 percent for Malaysia. The widespread of investment inefficiency eventually will comprise the integrity of financial intermediaries – as more and more corporates would have difficulty repaying the debts, and non-performing assets therefore pile up among the financial intermediaries. Table 1.14 The corporate leverage ratio (%) * Total debt/equity Hong Kong Indonesia Korea Malaysia Philippines Singapore Taiwan Thailand Latin America France Germany Japan U.S. 12/31/92 26 59 123 31 81 37 71 71 31 141 61 136 106 12/31/93 23 54 129 29 78 34 73 81 35 133 67 139 102 12/31/94 33 58 127 38 50 33 71 103 34 117 61 139 97 12/31/95 36 81 132 45 49 45 67 135 33 112 59 135 94 12/31/96 39 92 n.a. 62 69 58 65 155 31 111 58 138 90 * We do not include China and India as they were relatively insulated during the 1997 Asian crisis. Source: Pomerleano (1998); World Bank. The government’s policy of pegging the exchange rate reduced the perceived currency risk, leading to an overvaluation of the Baht and encouraging cheaper foreign 40 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) borrowing. When cheap capital meets lousy investment decisions, it is not hard to guess what will happen – the underlying economy in Thailand experienced sharp declines in real output. GDP growth fell from 8.9 percent in 1994 to -0.4 percent in 1997. III. Mis-conducted macroeconomic policies The pegged currency adopted by the Thai government before 1997 was also questionable because it led to over-valued baht. The overvaluation of Baht reduced Thai companies’ competitiveness in the global markets, resulted in current account deficits (exports were smaller than imports) and accumulation of foreign debts in the form of short-term foreign currency. The economic growth in Thailand had been largely financed by a rise in the current-account deficit (then the inflows of foreign capital). When the economy was doing well and the firms could make profits, they would not have problem repaying the debts (remember that Thai firms were heavily levered before the crisis, the average debt/equity ratio was 155 percent in 1996). However, by 1996, there was a significant drop in economic activity – import growth slowed from 3 percent in 1995 to just 2 percent in 1996; and even worse, exports actually declined in 1996. As a result, the percent of short-term debts to foreign reserves moved up to 99.7 percent in 1996. In the event of a liquidity crisis, with banks no longer willing to roll over short-term loans, foreign reserves would be insufficient to cover short-term liabilities. IV. Foreign funding dynamic The foreign funding dynamic played a central part in the buildup of imbalances in the Thai economy. Besides leading to current-account deficits by providing access to credit to fund imports, it also supported exchange rate overvaluation. Access to foreign liabilities, backed by domestic assets, also created a currency mismatch. Finally, the credit boom – driven as it was by large amounts of foreign money without adequate underwriting guidelines – encouraged overinvestment both by banks and private corporations in marginal projects. These investments fueled the destruction of corporate value, eventually causing bank loans to default and undermining the banking system itself. V. Asset price bubble Speculative investment in real estate and equity created an asset bubble by 1992, which led to the collapse of the domestic financial system in 1997. Speculative overinvestment in land and real estate was evident in their relationship to stock market prices, which rose more rapidly in the property sector than in the other sectors over 1990-96. When the stock market collapsed in 1997, the percentage drop was much larger in the property sector than in the overall market. Between 1990 and 1993, the Thai stock market rose by 175 percent, compared with 395 percent for the property sector, but then lost 51 percent of its value between 1993 and the end of 1996, compared with 73 percent for the property sector. Because of the above five structural factors, by 1997, Thailand was fully ready for a major crisis to break out. The attack on the Thai currency by international speculators just ensured that it did happen. 1.4.3 Lessons learned The financial crisis in 1997, originating in Thailand and spreading to South Korea and other parts of Asia, yielded many takeaways as follows: 41 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) • Regulating non-bank finance companies. As the Thai government discovered, non-bank finance company problems can infect the banking sector as well. A potential rule of financial regulation should be that all institutions that take deposits and make loans, regardless of what they are called, should be regulated as banks. The challenge for regulatory authorities will be to ensure that financial intermediation, wherever it occurs, is well regulated, but not overregulated. With an improved regulatory environment, governments can realistically expect that financial intermediation will be more likely to absorb, rather than magnify, shocks. • Reducing the incentives for excessive borrowing. One of the root causes of the Thai crisis and the crisis in other parts of Asia was that credit boom led to poorly managed investment, which in turn caused the pile up of non-performing assets. How to remove the incentives to over-borrow and over-investment remains a challenge as it involves deeper institutional development. • Improving governance in the financial corporate sectors. Reducing the governmentdirected credits, increasing capital adequacy ratios, and strengthening regulation of financial intermediation as well as improving bankruptcy laws, accounting and auditing, and disclosure requirements can play important roles in ensuring that capital will be well invested. • Improving corporate governance in corporate sectors. Banks need to develop an arms’length relationship with corporations. Stricter enforcement of limits on lending to connected firms and insiders, the violation of which has contributed to the recent financial crisis and poor intermediation. In those cases where banks and firms are effectively controlled by the same shareholders, increased transparency is required, which could take the form of more disclosure or requirement of a formal ownership relationship, such as through a holding company; the financial intermediaries and agents involved in disciplining firms should be encouraged to enhance their roles. • Developing capital markets. Developed corporate bond markets herald more balanced financial systems that rely less on bank financing, diversify risk, and improve corporate monitoring. • Strengthening regulations. In crisis, the distinction between private and public debt easily blurs. Private external bank debt tends to become socialized to prevent collapse of the banking systems and thus constitutes a huge and implicit public contingent liability. Governments should monitor short-term debt and establish tight prudential regulations limiting exposure of financial institutions to prevent excessive buildup of short-term liabilities. Better disclosure of information would reduce one source of speculation affecting investors’ outlook. • Improving bankruptcy laws and mechanisms for restructuring. Without credible laws and procedures, banks and corporate owners may delay recognizing their losses to prevent losing control of assets to creditors or new investors, causing the financial and operational restructuring to drag on for years. As the crisis has become systemic, the scale of the problems has shown the need to establish a rapid and voluntary mechanism for creditors and potentially viable companies to restructure as an alternative to court ordered bankruptcy and liquidation of assets. First Draft: June 24, 2007 42 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) References Anderson, Jonathan, 2006. The return of Asia, Part I – Investment comes home, UBS global Economics & Strategy Research. Bairoch, P. 1993. Economics and world history: myths and paradoxes. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Barton, D., R. Newell, and G. Wilson, 2003. Dangerous markets: managing in financial crisis, John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Boyreau-Debray, G., S. J. Wei, 2005. Pitfalls of a state dominated financial system: the case of China. NBER working paper. Brandt, L., and H. Li, 2003. Bank discrimination in transition economies: ideology, information, or incentives? Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 31: 387-413. Chang, Sea-Jin, 2003, Financial crisis and transformation of Korean business groups: the rise and fall of chaebols, the Cambridge University Press. Cull, Robert, and Lixin Colin Xu, 2003. Who gets credit? the behavior of bureaucracts and state banks in allocating credit to Chinese state-owned enterprises, Journal of Development Economics, 71(2):533-559. Das, Dilip K., 2005. Asian economy and finance: a post-crisis perspective. Springer. Farrell, Diana, Susan Lund, and Leo Puri, 2005. Reforming India’s financial system. The McKinsey Quarterly, 2005. Farrell, Diana, Antonio Puron, and Jaana K. Remes, 2005. Beyond cheap labor: lessons for developing economies. The McKinsey Quarterly, No.1, 2005. Farrell, Diana, Sacha Ghai, and Tim Shavers, 2005. The coming demographic deficit: how aging popoulations will reduce global savings. The McKinsey Global Institute Report. Hotz, Carsten, 2005. China’s economic growth 1978-2025: what we know today about China’s economic growth tomorrow. Working Paper, HKUST. Huang, Yasheng, 2003. Selling China: foreign direct investment during the reform era. The Cambridge University Press. Kim, J.I. and L. Lau, 1994. The sources of economic growth of the East Asian newly industrialized economies, Journal of Japanese and International Economics, Vol. 8 (3), pp. 253271. Krugman, Paul, 1994. The myth of Asia’s miracle, Foreign Affairs, November, 1994. Lewis, William W, 2004. The power of productivity, The University of Chicago Press. 43 Finance in Asia: Institutions, Market, and Regulation (Qiao Liu, Douglas Arner, and Paul Lejot) Liu, Qiao, and Alan Siu, 2007. Institutions, financial development and corporate investment: evidence from an implied return on capital in China, working paper, University of Hong Kong. Maddison, A. 2001. The world economy: a millennial perspective. Paris: OECD Development Center. Pomerleano, Michael, 1998. The East Asia Crisis and corporate finance: the untold microeconomic story. The Emerging Market Quarterly, Winter 1998. Young, A. 1995. The tyranny of numbers: confronting the statistical relationship of the East Asian growth experience, Quarterly Journal of Economics. Vol. 110 (3). Young, A. 2003. Gold into base metals: productivity growth in the People’s Republic of China during the reform period. Quarterly Journal of Economics. Vol. 111 (6). 44