* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Understanding structural change in the Brunei Darussalam
Survey
Document related concepts
Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup
Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup
Economic growth wikipedia , lookup
Chinese economic reform wikipedia , lookup
Post–World War II economic expansion wikipedia , lookup
Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup
Transcript
Understanding structural change in the Brunei Darussalam Economy, 2005 - 2011 Tsue Ing Yap and Janine Dixon Centre of Policy Studies, Victoria University Abstract This paper describes the historical simulation of the Brunei Darussalam (hereafter Brunei) economy using BRUGEM, a recursive dynamic, computable general equilibrium (CGE) model based on ORANIG-RD. The simulation covers the period from 2005 to 2011. We estimate typically unobservable variables that describe the structural features of the economy such as the technology and household taste or preference changes. The estimates for these structural variables can help in explaining the observable features of the Brunei economy over the period under study. Findings from the historical simulation indicate that the Brunei economy is characterised by declining per-capita real economic growth, low capital growth, low investment by share of gross domestic product (GDP), but high growth in public and private consumption, high real wage, high imports and declining exports with real appreciation of Brunei’s currency and an improvement in the terms of trade attributable to high oil and gas prices. Real currency appreciation has eroded the competitiveness of the economy and in the face of declining hydrocarbon exports, this has placed Brunei in a challenging position in its preparation for the post-hydrocarbon era. DRAFT – NOT FOR QUOTATION 1 1. Introduction Brunei is a small and open economy that has been dependent on its hydrocarbon sectors for many decades. Brunei derived most of its revenues (93.1% of total government revenues in the 2011/2012 fiscal year) from the exports of oil and gas which made up nearly 90% of total exports in 2011 (DEPD 2011a). Like most mineral resources, oil and gas are finite. The BP Statistical Review of World Energy June 2013 report, ceteris paribus, stated that based on the 2012 figures for existing proven reserves and reserve-to-production ratios, oil will last 18.2 years while gas will last 22.9 years. This implied that without new oil and gas finds or improvement in technology to extract more out of maturing fields, at the current reserves level and extraction rate, Brunei will run out of hydrocarbons by the year 2035. Diversification efforts in Brunei have shown slow progress despite the various National Development Plans (NDP) and development initiatives in place (Tisdell 1998, Bhaskaran 2010, Lawrey 2010). There are numerous articles on the topic of diversification of Brunei’s economy highlighting the barriers to diversification with some authors (Crosby 2007, Bhaskaran 2007) and past studies (major past studies are listed in Bhaskaran 2007, p. 9) suggesting the areas Brunei could diversify into. Most of the studies are of qualitative nature and there are limited empirical studies on how these strategies can be carried out and what the economy-wide impacts would be if such policies were implemented. Before appropriate strategies can be formulated, it is useful to have an overall snapshot of the underlying economic structure of the economy through a quantitative method. To achieve this objective, this paper aims to identify and quantify the key features of the Brunei economy for the period 2005 to 2011 using the Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Modelling approach. A CGE model is an economy-wide model that depicts the inter-linkages between the different sectors in the real economy within the macroeconomic framework of a small country. It is able to capture the effects through changes in relative prices of inputs and outputs, brought about by shocks from either supply or demand sides of the economy and identify the tradeoffs amongst the different economic agents and the sectors. CGE modelling has been at the forefront of economic analysis in Australia for forty years, providing policymakers with 2 insights that can be clearly attributed to policy levers and other underlying structural change. This can be done at both macroeconomic and sectoral levels. Based on the ORANIG-RD model built by Horridge (2002) of the Centre of Policy Studies, we have developed a CGE model of Brunei’s economy called BRUGEM with dynamic features. Using the official input-output (IO) data published in 2011 for the base year 2005, and the macro statistics for 2011, the most recent complete set available, an historical simulation is implemented to uncover some underlying structural changes that can help cast some light moving forward while examining the factors that can contribute to Brunei’s successful diversification. 2. Modelling approach 2.1 Overview of the BRUGEM model BRUGEM is the core model used in this paper. BRUGEM retains not only the key features of the well-documented comparative static ORANI-G model (Dixon et al. 1982, Horridge 2003), it also extends to include additional equations to produce a Recursive Dynamic model, which is similar to a simplified version of the MONASH model which is the successor of the ORANI-G model as described in Dixon and Rimmer (2002). A recursive dynamic model is a multi-period CGE model that is solved sequentially on year-to-year basis over a number of years. For each year, the starting data is utilising the end-of-period results updated by previous simulation. Therefore each model solution represents the changes between one year and the next. Under the recursive dynamic setting, it is assumed that the economic agents’ behaviours only depend on the past and current states of the economy; they are not aware of future values of the variables in the model. In this aspect, a recursive dynamic model is different to a fully inter-temporal model where all periods are solved simultaneously and agents take into consideration their expectations of the future. BRUGEM features detailed sectoral disaggregation and the model used in this paper features 73 industries and 73 commodities. The main departures from the original 74 sectors IO table are the incorporation of an additional sector to represent the ownership of dwellings, the aggregation of three tiny industries into one, and the attribution of some value added in the oil and gas sectors to natural resources which are treated as a fixed factor. 3 In terms of the underlying theory which is largely based on Dixon and Rimmer (2002), BRUGEM is a Johansen-style model where the key behaviour assumptions of the economic agents identified in the model (producers, investors, household consumers, importers, exporters and government) are drawn from the neoclassical microeconomic theory. Producers and households are assumed to make decisions based on their maximising behaviours. Each representative industry is assumed to operate under the condition of cost minimisation subject to its constant returns to scale production function and given input prices. Households maximise their utility subject to their budget constraints and their demands are modelled via a representative household in the economy using the Klein-Rubin utility maximisation function or the linear expenditure system (LES). Investors will allocate new capital to industries on the basis of the expected rates of return where the capital stock will grow in relation to the equilibrium expected rate of return and is limited by the logistic capital supply function as described in Dixon and Rimmer (2002, p. 190-192). Imported and domestic varieties of each commodity demanded are assumed to be imperfect substitutes and are modelled using the Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) assumption of Armington as the approach adopted (Dixon et. al 1982, p. 69). Therefore at the sourcing nest level, the units of given inputs are differentiated by source and are combined such that the total cost is minimised to provide a unit of composite commodity demanded by producers. The capital creators will demand inputs to investment by choosing the cost-minimising input mix from domestically produced or imported commodities subject to a constant CES capitalcreation function. There is no primary factor being used directly as inputs to this capital creation process. The demand for domestically produced commodity by foreigners is assumed to be inversely related to the export price denominated in foreign currency. The higher is the export price, the lesser is the demand for exports of the domestic commodity. Unlike other agents, the government is not an optimiser in this model. Its consumption and investment are modelled in such a way that they can be set as exogenous or assumed to change via a simple relationship with other relevant variable with the use of swaps in the model closure. Typical assumptions used are such that government consumption is proportional to private consumption in a welfare-enhancing policy change (Dixon and Rimmer 2002, p. 151) and industry-specific government investment is proportional to total investment in each industry. 4 Relative prices play an active role in the determination of economic outcomes in this type of model (Parmenter and Meagher 1985). There are different valuation of prices for the domestically produced goods and services: basic prices, producers’ prices and purchasers’ prices. Basic prices are the prices received by the sellers rather than the prices paid by the users. They are the basic values of domestically produced goods received by producers. The basic price of an import is the landed-duty-paid price and for domestic products it is the factory-door price. Basic prices are assumed to be uniform across producing industries and across users, and also importers in the case of imported goods. Producer prices are prices that include the indirect sales taxes but exclude markups (Dixon et. al 1992, p.31). Markups are margin flows representing quantities of retail and wholesale services or transport needed to deliver each basic flow of good to the user. The difference between the basic prices and purchasers’ prices is due to sales taxes and margin flows such as wholesale, retail and transport costs. In general, markets are assumed to be competitive with no pure profits in any economic activity and markets will clear with demand equals to the supply for all domestically produced goods and services. All agents will take input and output prices as given for their decision-making. Under the dynamic setting of the BRUGEM model, time paths can also be produced under different scenarios for a large number of economic variables. This feature of the model is useful in implementing simulations to either track the past history for better understanding or to forecast the future, using available data and dynamic relationships of the equations within the model. The recursive dynamic model has forecasting component utilising 3 mechanisms: (i) the stock-flow relation between investment and capital stock with one year gestation lag assumed; (ii) a positive relation between investment and rate of profit; and (iii) a relation between wage growth and employment. This dynamic component can be used to construct a plausible base forecast for the next ten years or more. Additional data such as the capital stocks, exogenous predictions about the future directions of technological change, employment, import prices and position of export demand curves are required to produce such forecasts (Horridge, 2002). Predictions can be either based on assumptions, say uniform growth rates, or can be obtained from detailed forecasts made by government and private agencies or even international organisations such as International Monetary Fund (IMF). A second forecast can be 5 constructed to examine a perturbed scenario whereby some variables are shocked to different values from the base scenario to simulate the policy impact, say, more investment in agriculture industry. The difference between these two scenarios can then be interpreted as the effect of the policy change. BRUGEM is a large model system consisting of a wide variety of equations with many in non-linear functional forms. Adopting similar approach to developed model like MONASH, BRUGEM is solved using the Euler solution method for linear approximation, described in more details by Dixon and Rimmer (2002). The simulation is run in 50 steps for a high degree of accuracy. Briefly, if we can represent the BRUGEM model as a system of equations describing the economic activities at year t in vector form shown in Equation (E.1), F[V (t )] 0 (E.1) where F is a vector of length m of differentiable functions and V (t ) is a vector of length n of prices, quantities, household tastes and other variables for year t . Since n m , we need to define a closure or to specify the combination of values for n m exogenous variables in order to solve for the remaining m endogenous variables. Dixon and Rimmer (2002) described the four basic choices in choosing the sets of n m exogenous variables: historical, decomposition, forecasting and policy closures. For the purpose of this paper, the “historical closure” is used and will be described in the next section. Under the computation method used by GEMPACK1 (Harrison & Pearson 1996), the nonlinear equations (E.1) are converted into a system of linear equations by taking the total differentials of each equation and then expressed them in percentage change form: A(V (t ))v(t ) 0 (E.2) where A(V (t )) is a m x n matrix of coefficients such as cost and sale shares, evaluated at an initial solution V of (E.1) and v is the vector of deviations in the model’s variables away from V . From the IO published data, we have the initial solution for year t 0 where 1 GEMPACK is a suite of software application developed by the Centre of Policy Studies to solve general equilibrium models. 6 F[V ] 0 . Using initial solution for year t , the first computation will create a solution for the year t+1 via movement of the exogenous variables from initial (year t ) values to the required values in year t+1. This solution for year t+1 will in turn become the initial solution for a computation that moves exogenous variables from their values at year t+1 to t+2 and so on. For the period under study, the chosen initial year is 2005 being the base year used for the sole published IO tables available. Since there are no published IO tables after that, the data after 2005 is subsequently updated in a sequence of period-to-period simulations until the year 2011 where there are latest published statistics available. Using a step-by-step approach, the baseline is developed for the years 2005-2011 with the use of BRUGEM model where historical data is available for the macroeconomic and some price variables of the Brunei economy obtained from the Department of Statistics (DEPD 2011a). 2.2 The historical closure in a stylised “back-of-the-envelope” model To achieve the aim of this paper, simulations need to be run using BRUGEM with the appropriate closure. We use a stylised back-of-the-envelope (BOTE) model to illustrate the development of a historical closure, from the starting point of a “natural” long run closure. The system of equations used in the BOTE model (Dixon and Rimmer 2002, Giesecke 2004) is shown in Table 1. BOTE model is useful to support the interpretation of macro results by identifying the main mechanisms and the data items underlying certain results. This is especially important as a tool to explain to policymakers who may not be familiar with the large CGE model. As a CGE model integrates detailed structural and dynamic information, it can reveal useful theoretical insights supported by calculations. BOTE calculations can be used to conduct sensitivity analysis under alternative assumptions and parameter values, and can also be used to check for any errors in coding and data handling. The 8-equation BOTE illustrated in Table 1 requires 8 endogenous variables. In the “natural” long run closure, Y, C, I, G, X, M, K and TOT are the endogenous variables while the structural variables driving economic activity (L, ROR, A, APC, Γ, Ψ, V and T) are exogenous. It is not simple to trace causality through the BOTE, but if Equations (2) and (8) 7 are considered to explain Y and K (ignoring TOT), then Equation (3) explains C, Equation (4) explains G, Equation (5) explains M and Equation (7) explains I. With Y, C, I, G and M explained, Equation (1) explains X, and finally Equation (6) explains TOT. The point is that this distilled version of the full CGE model illustrates how the structural variables such as employment (linked to population in the long run), productivity, and the conditions in the world economy are the determinants of economic growth and structural change in the full model. The historical closure in the right hand panel has the same 8 equations, but a different set of 8 unknowns. The exogenous variables are now observed macroeconomic indicators. The equations can be solved for the endogenous structural variables. By setting Y, C, G, X and M exogenously, I can be determined in Equation (1). APC can be solved from Equation (3). T can be determined from Equation (5) and V, can be determined from Equation (6). With two Equations (2) and (8) with two unknowns K and A, these can be solved simultaneously. With variable K known, Ψ can be determined. Table 1: Natural and historical closures of the BOTE model “Natural” long run closure Historical Closure (1) Y=C+I+G+X−M (1) Y=C+I+G+X−M (2) Y=(1/A)*F(K,L) (2) Y=(1/A)*F(K,L) (3) C=B(APC,Y,TOT) (3) C= B(APC,Y,TOT) (4) C/G=Γ (4) C/G=Γ (5) M=H(Y,TOT,T) (5) M=H(Y,TOT,T) (6) TOT = J(X,V) (6) TOT = J(X,V) (7) I/K=Ψ (7) I/K=Ψ (8) K/L=N(ROR,A,TOT) (8) K/L=N(ROR,A,TOT) Bold = exogenous variables, the rest are endogenous Key: K – capital stock V – demand-shift variable Y – GDP TOT – terms of trade C – private consumption L – labour I – investment ROR – rate of return Γ- ratio of private to public spending Ψ – investment to capital ratio T – import preference variable G – government expenditure X – exports M - imports 8 A – primary-factor augmenting technology APC – average propensity to consume 3. Historical simulation The historical simulation reveals variables that describe the structural features of the economy such as the technology and taste or preference changes of the Brunei economy. In the historical simulation, the observed variables are exogenised and shocked with the calculated shock values to ensure that the output data for the year 2011 is consistent with the statistical data. Variables related to primary-factor-saving technical change, preference for imported goods relative to domestic goods, average propensity to consume, shifts in export demand curve are endogenised in order to hit these targets. We informed the model the observed real growth rates in GDP, private consumption, government consumption, exports, imports, oil and gas export volume and corresponding purchasers’ export prices, import prices, terms of trade, the number of households and employment. Aggregate capital stock is predetermined by the investment last year and the model will solve for next year’s capital stock, capital rental, primary factor augmented technical change, preference in favour of imports and other endogenous variables. Dixon and Rimmer (2002) and several other authors (Giesecke 2004, Dixon and Rimmer 2003, Tran and Giesecke 2008 just to name a few) have outlined the theories and steps undertaken to conduct historical simulation. In our simulations, phi, the exchange rate defined as Brunei dollar to the world currency is used as the numeraire. This reflects the current situation whereby the Brunei dollar is fixed at par to the Singapore dollar. The general features of the macroeconomy in BRUGEM are as illustrated in the BOTE model in Table 1. With the historical simulation, we found out some characteristics of the Brunei economy which will give the context for forecast to address question like what would happen if these features continue into the future period when oil and gas have run out. Starting with the natural closure, the historical closure is developed in seven steps (Step 1 through Step 7) cumulatively based on the available macroeconomic data where each step consists of the previous step plus a small number of swaps between endogenous and exogenous variables, maintaining a valid closure throughout. By Step 7, the full historical closure is implemented. Results are then compared over subsequent successive historical simulations showing the effects of the additional data introduced at each step. The BRUGEM 9 results from this step-by-step approach for the period 2005 to 2011 are shown in Table 2. The difference between the columns shows the effects of introducing the new shock in the subsequent step. Step 7 will show the results of the entire historical simulation when observed data have been incorporated. The final column shows the average annual percentage change and the figures in bold indicate the average annual shocked values. Step 1 : Number of households, aggregate employment and homotopy variable The number of households, aggregate employment and the homotopy variable which activates the capital accumulation equation in the model are shocked. The shock to the number of households only has an impact on the composition of household expenditure. In the model there is no explicit link between households and labour supply. For this reason, employment is also shocked in this step. Aggregate nominal household expenditure in the model is determined by nominal incomes and the average propensity to consume, and the number of households has no direct impact. However, the allocation of the household budget by commodity is determined by the linear expenditure system (LES) for which there is a subsistence component of consumption on each commodity. The subsistence component is fixed per household, so an increase in the number of households leads to an increase in subsistence expenditure, and for a given budget, a decrease in supernumerary expenditure. In the absence of technical change but with small positive growth in employment, the real GDP (row 1) grows by 9.42% in six years as the economy expands from the supply side in Equation (2) of Table 1. Without any change in technology and the rate of return, the capitalto-labour ratio is expected to remain unchanged according to Equation (8) in the right hand side column of Table 1. Therefore the capital stock (row 14) must increase to maintain this ratio. The slight increase in the capital stock relative to employment is explained by the increase in investment (row 2). The shock to aggregate employment is accommodated in the model by endogenising the wage. As expected, an increase in employment with no corresponding shift in demand schedules leads the economy to produce more than it consumes domestically, and the result is a real devaluation of the currency (row 15) in order to accommodate an increase in net exports. 10 Given the large real devaluation, the result for net exports is rather small. Imports (row 5) are expected to increase as real GDP grows via Equation (5) which is also brought about by the increase in private consumption via Equation (3). Exports from Brunei consist almost entirely of oil and gas, both heavily capital intensive activities with limited scope to take advantage of the increased employment. Indeed, although the currency devalues by 9.12%, the export prices of both oil and gas only fall by around 1%, effectively limiting the fall in the terms of trade to 1.33%. Nominal aggregate household expenditure is linked to nominal income, but aggregate real household expenditure increases by slightly less than GDP. This reflects the slight decrease in the terms of trade, making imports, an important component of household expenditure, more expensive. We find an increase in investment expenditure more than double the increase in GDP. This reflects not only the modest increase in household expenditure and net exports, but also the exogeneity of government expenditure in this step. Step 2 : Real gross domestic product (GDP) The observed real GDP growth is in fact lower than the result shown in Step 1 (row 1). In order to implement the available real GDP growth data in Step 2, we endogenise primaryfactor technical change uniformly over all industries. The real GDP growth is shocked by 0.92% per annum and with this growth rate being lower than the employment growth, regressive technical change of 3.32% in aggregate (row 25) is observed over the period 2005 to 2011. The link between the decline in productivity and that the growth rate of the economy is in Equation (2). Compared to Step 1, the effect of declining real wage is slightly dampened as the increase in employment in Step 1 did not produce as much economic output as expected due to reduced productivity (row 25). Regressive technical change affects the capital-to-labour ratio and subsequently the real wage which is expected to fall via Equation (8) leading to the decline in capital stock (row 14) and also investment (row 2). The decrease in real GDP growth rate is also reflected in the fall in private consumption (row 3) via Equation (3). With less economic activities, imports will fall (row 5) via Equation (5) and also the exports (row 6) via Equation (1) leading to an improvement in terms of trade (row 16). 11 Step 3 : Real private consumption The fall in private consumption anticipated in Step 2 is however not observed in the historical data. In Step 3, private consumption is given a positive shock of 4.28% per annum. In order to implement this shock, we endogenise the ratio of nominal consumption to nominal GDP (f3tot) or the average propensity to consume out of GDP. Since aggregate private consumption grows much faster than GDP and hence incomes, the average propensity to consume increases by 31.47% (row 29) from 2005-2011. With no change in GDP at this step, the increase in private consumption crowds out other types of expenditure, leading to a reduction in investment and net exports and real appreciation of the currency compared to Step 2. As the share of imports in household consumption is high relative to the share of imports in other sectors, we might expect a large increase in imports as a result of the increase in consumption as a share of GDP. In this context, the increase in imports appears quite modest, well below the increase in consumption. For a given value of net exports, further expansion of imports requires further expansion of exports. The major export sectors, oil and gas have limited capacity for expansion due to their use of natural resources (a fixed factor). Recalling the national accounting identity, X-M = S-I, the expected negative effect on investment (I) of a reduction in domestic saving (S) is dampened by the fall in net exports (XM). The large fall in the value of net exports accounts for almost all of the reduction in savings, and investment continues to increase by more than GDP, albeit at a lesser rate than after Step 2. Step 4 : Real public consumption With the statistical data available for government expenditure, the aggregate public consumption variable is shocked by 6.58% per annum in Step 4, making it the fastest growing component of expenditure on GDP. Since there is no change of GDP from supply side and the private consumption is fixed by previous step, the increase in public consumption must lead to the decrease in other expenditure items on the demand side to maintain the GDP identity. There is a marked decline in both the investment (row 2) and net exports (rows 5 and 6). 12 Public consumption is the most labour intensive component of expenditure on GDP, accounting for 24% of GDP, over 50% of employment and just 5% of capital in the base year. The large increase in expenditure on Public Administration, Education and Health Services draws a further 20% of the labour force into these activities, leading to a reduction labour and output in almost all other activities. This is facilitated by a very large increase in the real wage (row 17). The increase in consumption introduced in Step 4 now must be satisfied by a large increase in imports (row 5). The large increase in domestic expenditure, far in excess of the increase in GDP, is accompanied by a significant loss in competitiveness, shown in the large real appreciation of the currency (row 15). An interesting feature of the result in Step 4 is that although aggregate investment declines (row 2), there is a slight increase in aggregate capital stock (row 14). This is a compositional effect. These aggregates are value-weighted sums of investment and capital stock by industry. In each industry, the increase in investment is commensurate with the increase in capital stock. However, in the three government industries (Public Administration, Education and Health Services), the labour to capital ratio is so large and rapidly increasing, that the increase in the rate of return on capital far exceeds the national average. As a result, the value-weights of capital stock for these industries increase, while the value-weights of investment (reflecting the cost of capital creation) do not change. Thus the increase in capital stock in these industries is afforded more importance in the calculation of aggregate capital stock, while the increase in investment is outweighed by the decline in investment in all other industries in the calculation of aggregate investment. This step has the largest impact on the distribution of expenditure in the economy, taking the value share of government expenditure in GDP from 24% in the base year 2005 to 52% in 2011. The increase is attributed to both volume and price increases. As a major employer, the labour constraint (growth of just 1.6% per annum compared with government expenditure growth of 6.6% per annum) has a significant impact on wages and therefore costs. With consumption already fixed in Step 3, the expansion in the government sector has a deleterious effect on the other sectors of the economy, that is, net exports and investment. 13 Step 5 : Total imports and foreign currency import prices In Step 5, the import volume variable is exogenised and a change of 7.62% per annum is introduced. At this stage, GDP and all its expenditure side components except exports and investment are exogenous. The variable chosen to accommodate imports is the investment slack variable (invslack), effectively introducing a shift in the required rate of return schedule uniformly over all industries. The exogenous CIF foreign currency import price variable (pf0cif) is also uniformly shocked by -0.67% per annum. As price data was not available by commodity, the average price movement was assigned to all commodities. The decrease in import prices is directly reflected in further real currency appreciation (row 15), which has a negative impact on exports (row 6). The increase in imports also releases some domestic capacity, dampening the decline in investment. However, the main effect of this is to shift even more workers into the government sector. The compositional effect described in Step 4 is further exacerbated with another large increase in aggregate capital stocks (row 14) accompanied by only a small increase in investment (row 2). The decline in import prices leads to further improvement in terms of trade (row 16) which in turn increases the capital-to-labour ratio via Equation (8) and hence the real wage (row 17). With the aggregate employment fixed in Step 1, the aggregate capital stock must increase (row 14) and also investment (row 2) via Equation (7). Step 6: Total exports and changes to sectoral oil and gas export volumes and prices The large decline in total exports volume at Step 5 is not observed from the data published by the Brunei’s Department of Statistics. Therefore the overall export volume variable is increased by shocking it with the observed value of -0.6% per annum, which is accommodated by endogenising the general shifter on export demand curves (a uniform shift for all commodities). The large shift in the export demand curve (row 32) facilitates this increase in exports due to favourable changes in foreign preference for Brunei goods. Given the dominance of oil and gas in Brunei’s economy, data on the oil and gas export volumes and purchaser’s prices of exports are introduced together with the aggregate export shock. For the period under study, the Brunei’s Department of Statistics is able to provide data on the changes in export volume and export prices for oil and gas commodities. The 14 volumes of oil and gas exports are shocked by -3.58% and 0.13% per annum respectively by endogenising the positions of the export demand schedules for the two commodities, oil and gas. To reflect both the demand and supply conditions of the hydrocarbons market, the positive shocks of 7.31% and 14.12% per annum are also included for the oil and gas prices respectively. Observations of quantity and price of oil and gas are accommodated by endogenising the positions of both the supply and demand schedules. The shift in the demand schedule is achieved simply by endogenising the position of the export demand schedule. The shift in the supply schedule is more complex. We exogenise the investment paths of oil and gas sectors based on reasonable estimates of capital accumulation over the period. The remaining movement required in the supply schedule is accommodated via endogenous technical change. The export markets for oil and gas are illustrated respectively in the following Figures 1 and 2. For the oil market, although the price of crude oil has increased, the export volume declined. This is illustrated in Figure 1 where the supply curve has shifted to the left indicating a fall in the supply of crude oil for exports despite an upward shift of demand schedule (row 33), resulting in a higher price. The decline in supply is brought about by the fall in capital stocks (row 35) and the adverse all-factor augmenting technical change (row 26) for the oil sector. Figure 1: Changes to demand and supply for exports of oil Export price S Px1 Px0 B A D Export quantity 15 In Figure 2, both the price and volume of exports increase for natural gas, but the increase in volume is not commensurate with the large observed increase in price. Therefore we see the supply curve shifted leftwards with a very large shift of the demand schedule (row 34). The level of capital stocks was high previously due to earlier high investment in the gas sector but it has subsequently declined (row 36). Figure 2: Changes to demand and supply for exports of gas Export price S B Px1 Px0 A D Export quantity An implication of this approach is the productivity decline observed in the earlier steps is reduced and redistributed (row 25). With the relative large productivity decline estimated for oil (row 26), the remaining sectors must experience an improvement in productivity to maintain the average estimated in earlier step. However, our estimate of the average productivity decline has also reduced. This is because we have now estimated a smaller capital stock in oil and gas (rows 35 and 36), and oil and gas account for around 70% of Brunei’s total capital stock. Less capital stock for a given set of shocks to GDP and employment implies a productivity gain, and the productivity loss observed up to Step 5 is now reduced (row 28). The contribution of technical change to GDP is now -3.15%. The decline in the capital to labour ratio also has the impact of dampening the increase in real wages (row 17). 16 An interesting implication of the shocks is that the effective increase in exports (as compared to the result in the previous step) is accompanied by an increase in investment (row 2). With GDP and its other expenditure components all tied down, the increase in both of the remaining components of expenditure is counterintuitive. This is a compositional effect. The change in real GDP is the value-weighted sum of the changes in its real expenditure components. The very large increase in prices for oil and gas (rows 9 and 10) means that the value share of exports in GDP increases from just 20% in the final year of Step 5 to 48% in the final year of Step 6. Furthermore, the decrease in real wages reduces the price of activities related to government expenditure, which tend to be labour intensive. These factors lead to a downward adjustment in the value share of government expenditure from 57% after Step 5 to just 39%. This has the effect of reducing the share-weighted contribution to GDP of the very large increase in real government expenditure. Step 7: Terms of trade In the final step, to target the terms of trade change based on historical data, this variable is exogenised by swapping with the variable determining local preferences for imported varieties. The shock to the terms of trade 9.75% per annum represents a downward adjustment from the terms of trade result in Step 6. To achieve this requires an increase in preferences for imported varieties which devalues the currency (row 15) and reduces real wages (row 17). The change in investment from Step 6 to Step 7 is again counterintuitive, when we consider that none of the real macro expenditure aggregates or GDP has changed. Again, the explanation is in the value shares. The devaluation makes imports more expensive when measured in domestic currency, increasing their negative share in GDP as compared to Step 6. The reduction in real wages decreases the value share of government expenditure. Reductions in these shares reduce the contribution of the large real increases in imports and government expenditure to GDP, thereby allocating a larger residual to investment. With all observed major macro aggregates now in place, we have a complete picture of economic growth in Brunei from 2005 to 2011. The final result for investment, which has remained endogenous throughout the simulation, did not accord as closely with official statistics in the national accounts and was lower than expected. There are several factors contributing to this. The national accounts contain statistical discrepancy in the GDP 17 expenditure approach as a reconciliation item to match the GDP by production approach (DEPD 2011a, p. 60). In the computation of the real shocks in percentage change for the simulation, GDP in constant prices are used and this statistical discrepancy is distributed by share of the expenditure aggregates. There are also differences between the expenditure aggregates shares in GDP in the national accounts and the IO database for the base year 2005 as pointed out in a report (DEPD 2011b, p. 36). The published input-output table for 2005 with lower investment to GDP ratio than the national accounts is however accepted, since better sources of information were utilised and therefore is used as the starting point to build a more detailed and updated database for the period 2005-2011. Investment or capital formation growth rate is determined as a residual by putting in the growth rates of other expenditure aggregates and real GDP in this simulation. Step 7 completes the historical simulation whereby it is observed that the Brunei economy is characterised by low real economic growth, low capital growth, low investment by share of GDP, high consumption, high imports and declining exports, high real wage, real currency appreciation, improvement in terms of trade and a small technological improvement of 5.87% over the period of 2005 to 2011 or an average rate of 1% per year as shown in the last column in Table 2. 18 Table 2: Step-wise development of the historical simulation for 2005-2011 Description Step 1 Step 2 Step 3 Step 4 Step 5 Step 6 Step 7 Av. Annual Observed economic variables Percentage changes between 2005 and 2011 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 Real GDP Real investment Real private consumption Real public consumption Real imports Real exports Oil export volume Gas export volume Oil export price Gas export price Import price c.i.f. Number of households Aggregate employment 9.42 22.41 8.86 0.00 8.40 10.26 9.09 9.20 -0.80 -1.23 0.00 12.95 9.86 5.65 17.67 4.93 0.00 5.40 5.81 5.01 5.08 -0.45 -0.69 0.00 12.95 9.86 5.65 10.79 28.59 0.00 15.79 0.62 3.03 2.96 -0.27 -0.41 0.00 12.95 9.86 5.65 -22.38 28.59 46.57 45.85 -18.58 -6.35 -6.14 0.60 0.90 0.00 12.95 9.86 5.65 -19.89 28.59 46.57 55.37 -20.36 -7.88 -7.51 0.76 1.10 -3.95 12.95 9.86 5.65 -16.06 28.59 46.57 55.37 -3.55 -19.65 0.78 52.70 120.89 -3.95 12.95 9.86 5.65 1.19 28.59 46.57 55.37 -3.55 -19.65 0.78 52.70 120.89 -3.95 12.95 9.86 0.92 0.20 4.28 6.58 7.62 -0.60 -3.58 0.13 7.31 14.12 -0.67 2.05 1.58 14 15 16 Other macroeconomic indicators Aggregate capital stock Real devaluation Terms of trade 10.94 9.12 -1.33 10.52 5.75 -0.79 10.25 -7.64 0.19 11.45 -63.65 4.16 20.42 -69.49 8.80 11.46 -58.59 79.83 11.05 -49.61 74.75 1.76 -10.79 9.75 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 Price ratios Labour to CPI (real wage) Capital to investment (rate of return) Cost of capital Investment price to GNE price Consumption price to GNE price Govt consum. price to GNE price GDP to primary factors -17.67 2.90 2.34 3.73 5.00 -7.69 0.16 -14.89 -2.34 0.72 2.46 3.53 -5.26 3.49 -7.99 -8.97 -2.28 -1.68 3.68 -3.74 4.80 182.58 -43.85 -42.37 -17.39 -35.91 43.94 -1.25 237.02 -52.48 -50.56 -18.04 -41.99 52.25 0.62 172.84 -10.58 -26.81 -11.64 -31.58 37.10 -3.14 144.70 1.71 -20.63 -8.14 -26.92 31.19 -3.28 16.08 0.28 -3.78 -1.41 -5.09 4.63 -0.55 -17.67 0.00 -14.89 3.32 -7.99 3.30 182.58 2.65 237.02 6.05 172.84 -4.19 144.70 -5.87 16.08 -1.00 0.00 3.32 3.30 2.65 6.05 19.24 20.98 3.22 0.00 3.32 3.30 2.65 6.05 2.24 2.91 0.48 0.00 -2.74 -2.70 -2.24 -5.10 -3.15 -3.17 -0.53 0.00 0.00 31.47 -1.83 -10.91 -20.34 -21.84 -4.02 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 11.13 11.10 25.94 25.60 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 10.58 10.57 19.29 19.10 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 8.98 8.91 0.76 0.02 0.00 46.57 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 4.76 4.63 -50.50 -51.86 0.00 46.57 38.77 0.00 0.00 0.00 9.31 9.08 -49.98 -51.60 0.00 46.57 64.59 799.40 778.59 2972.76 -0.82 5.90 -69.60 -21.72 0.00 46.57 123.74 299.94 1871.34 6771.72 -0.83 5.90 -69.60 -21.72 93.32 6.58 14.36 25.99 64.36 102.39 -0.14 0.96 -18.00 -4.00 11.61 24 25 26 Structural variables 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 19 Corresponding variables Overall wage shifter All factor augmenting tech change (non-mining sectors) All factor augmenting tech change in oil sector All factor augmenting tech change in gas sector Contribution of technical change to GDP Average propensity to consume out of GDP Overall govt demand shifter Investment slack variable General exports shifter Quantity shifter in oil export demand Quantity shifter in gas export demand Capital stock in oil sector Capital stock in gas sector Investment in oil sector Investment in gas sector Uniform import/domestic twist 4. Conclusions Using a step-by-step approach to an historical simulation, this study has uncovered several interesting characteristics of the Brunei economy for the period 2005 to 2011. The step-wise implementation of the shocks has enabled us to attribute structural shifts in the economy to specific causes. Some examples of these attributions are: high wage growth is attributed mainly to growth in the government sector; modest productivity growth in non-mining sectors is attributed to an increase in non-mining output relative to the capital stock; and the final result for the terms of trade is in fact lower than it would have been based on the increases in oil and gas prices, revealing an increase in preferences for imports. We find that with the large increase in domestic absorption relative to the low growth of GDP, the Brunei economy experienced high real wage (average 16.1% per annum), increased domestic price level (averaging 3.4% per annum) and strong real appreciation in currency (average 10.8% per annum). These factors contributed to the high import growth and declining exports observed as producers faced increased costs from both the primary factors as well as intermediate inputs. The real appreciation of Brunei’s currency had impeded Brunei economy’s competitiveness in exports as a downward export trend was observed over the period under study. With the dwindling oil and gas reserves and therefore limited future hydrocarbon exports, it is important to address the challenge of expanding the exports of other non-oil and gas sectors. The government is managing the production of its oil and gas in order to extend their productive life from the existing fields while exploring for new ones. There remains much uncertainty as to when the production from any new discovery can come online and also the timing when productions are stopped for maintenance. The government is continuing its efforts to broaden its economic base and has identified several industries for development. These include downstream petrochemicals, tourism, Islamic financial services and production of halal products, information and communication technology services (ADB 2013, p. 217). With the limitation of its domestic market size, the government is focusing on exportorientated industries. The findings of this study are in line with the current situation. In aggregate, it appears that Brunei economy has progressive technological change for the period 2005-2011, however the 20 technical regression in the oil and gas sectors cannot be overlooked due to their significant impact on the economy. Clarifying the situation with respect to mining capital stocks is an important area for further investigation. With a small and weak private sector, the government remains the key driver in the economy. Without strong investment growth, government spending will continue to be the source of economic stimulus, crowding out the private sector through high wages and other costs, and the associated loss of competitiveness. This poses a challenge to the growth of the private sector moving forward into the posthydrocarbon era. 5. References Asian Development Bank, ADB (2013). Asian Development Outlook 2013 - Asia's Energy Challenge. Retrieved from http://www.adb.org/publications/asian-development- outlook-2013-asias-energy-challenge Bhaskaran, M. (2007). Economic Diversification in Negara Brunei Darussalam CSPS Report: The Centennial Group. Bhaskaran, M. (2010). Economic Diversification in Brunei Darussalam. CSPS Strategy and Policy Journal, 1, 1-12. BP plc. (2013). BP Statistical Review of World Energy June 2013. Retrieved from www.bp.com/statisticalreview Crosby, M. (2007). Economic Diversification CSPS Report: Melbourne Business School. Department of Statitics, DEPD (2011a). Brunei Darussalam Statistical Yearbook 2011. Brunei Darussalam: Department of Economic Planning and Development (DEPD). Department of Statitics, DEPD (2011b). Brunei Darussalam’s Supply, Use and Input-Output Table. Brunei Darussalam: Department of Economic Planning and Development (DEPD). Dixon, P.B., Parmenter, B.R., Sutton, J. & Vincent, D.P. (1982), ORANI: A Multisectoral Model of the Australian Economy, North-Holland, Amsterdam. 21 Dixon, P.B., Parmenter, B.R., Powell, A.A. & Wilcoxen, P.J. (1992), Notes and Problems in Applied General Equilibrium Economics, North-Holland, Amsterdam. Dixon, P.B. and Rimmer, M.T. (2002), Dynamic General Equilibrium Modelling for Forecasting and Policy: A Practical Guide and Documentation of MONASH, NorthHolland, Amsterdam. Dixon, P. B., & Rimmer, M. T. (2003). The US Economy from 1992-1998 : Historical and Decomposition Simulations with the USAGE Model. Centre of Policy Studies and the IMPACT Project (General Working Paper No. G-143). Giesecke, J. (2004). The Extent and Consequences of Recent Structural Changes in the Australian Economy, 1997-2002 : Results from Historical/Decomposition Simulations with MONASH. Centre of Policy Studies and the IMPACT Project, General Working Paper(G-151). Harrison, W.J. & Pearson, R.K. (1996). Computing Solutions for Large General Equilibrium Models using GEMPACK, Computational Economics, 9:83-127. Horridge, M. (2002). ORANIGRD: a Recursive Dynamic version of ORANIG, document contained in the ORANIGRD package downloadable from www.copsmodels.com/oranig.htm Horridge, M. (2003). ORANI-G: A Generic Single-Country Computable General Equilibrium Model. Training document prepared for the Practical GE Modelling Course, 23-27 June 2003. Centre of Policy Studies and IMPACT Project. Monash University. Lawrey, R. N. (2010). An Economist's Perspective on Economic Diversification in Brunei Darusaalam. CSPS Strategy and Policy Journal, 1, 13-28. Tran, N. H. & Giesecke, J. (2008). Growth and Structural Change in the Vietnamese Economy 1996-2003: A CGE Analysis, Centre of Policy Studies and the IMPACT Project, General Papers (G-171). Parmenter, B., Meagher, G. (1985). Policy Analysis Using a Computable General Equilibrium Model: A Review of Experience at the IMPACT Project The Australian Economic Review, 1st Quarter. 22 Tisell, C. (1998). Brunei's Quest for Sustainable Development : Diversification and Other Strategies. Journal of the Asia-Pacific Economy, 3(3), 388-409. 23