* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Competitors and competition
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
16/11/16 25E52000 Market Entry Strategies for Entrepreneurial Business Lecture 3 Competitors and Competition Based on Chapter 5 in Besanko et al. (2013). Economics of Strategy. Sixth Edition. Wiley. Learning Objectives Learn to identify competitors and analyse market structures Principal concepts ¡ ¡ ¡ ¡ ¡ ¡ ¡ ¡ ¡ ¡ Bertrand price competition model Cournot quantity competition model Direct and indirect competitors Monopoly Monopolistic competition Oligopoly Perfect competition (Cross-)Price elasticity of demand Real options Stackelberg sequential move competition model 1 16/11/16 Identifying Competitors Competitors If one firm's strategic choice adversely affects the performance of another they are competitors Competition can be either direct or indirect ¡ Direct: similar products and services for the same customer group ÷ ¡ Example: Audi and BMW Indirect: different products and services that satisfy the same need with the same group of customers ÷ Example: Audi and BMW versus public transport In practice anyone who produces a substitute product is a competitor Measure of degree of substitution: cross-price elasticity of demand 2 16/11/16 Price Elasticity of Demand (PED) PED = responsiveness of demand after a change in price = % change in quantity demanded / % change in price Uber’s Use of Price Elasticity of Demand Uber uses dynamic pricing At peak times, demand is less price elastic When there is more demand (customers) than supply (drivers), Uber raises the average fare 3 16/11/16 Cross-Price Elasticity of Demand How price change in product B affects demand of product A? Market Structures 4 16/11/16 Market Structures Perfect Competition Many sellers who sell a homogenous good Many well informed buyers Consumers can costlessly shop around Sellers can enter and exit costlessly Each firm faces infinitely elastic demand Economic profits go to zero 5 16/11/16 Monopoly A monopolist faces little or no competition ¡ No close substitutes: buy it or do without ¡ Significant barriers to entry ‘Price maker’ Inefficient allocation of resources ¡ Being a ‘price maker’ leads to higher prices than in perfect competition ¡ Lower quantities of product sold in the market Monopoly vs. Perfect Competition Perfect competition ¡ ¡ Price takers P=AR=MR=MC Monopoly ¡ ¡ ¡ ¡ ¡ ¡ Price maker Downward sloping demand curve Lowering price the only way to increase demand Maximises profits when quantity is set where MR=MC MR < P > MC Compared to perfect competition ÷ ÷ Price is higher Quantity is lower 6 16/11/16 Monopolistic Competition Many sellers selling similar but not identical products ¡ ¡ Vertical differentiation: unambiguous performance/ quality differences Horizontal differentiation: certain product characteristics appeal to different customer groups Demand is elastic ¡ ¡ Products are differentiated so not perfect substitutes But still close substitutes such that if one firm raises its price too high, many customers switch to products made by other firms Monopolistic Competition Short-run: supernormal profits are possible ¡ Incumbent can behave like a monopolist ÷ ÷ ¡ Demand can be increased only by lowering prices, affecting the price of all units sold Thus, MR < P > MC Example: the first fine-dining restaurant in town Long-run equilibrium: normal profits ¡ Low barriers to entry attract competitors ¡ Competition drives prices down (shifts demand curve) ¡ Competitors enter until each firm’s economic profit is zero ¡ Highly differentiated products: if entry does not lower prices, entrants take away market share from the incumbents Innovation is a way from long-run back to short-run! 7 16/11/16 Oligopoly Small number of firms dominate ¡ Pricing and output decisions by each firm affect the price and output in the industry ¡ Each firm’s decisions influence the profits of the other firms ¡ Examples: McDonalds & Burger King; Airbus & Boeing; Elisa, DNA & Sonera Similar product: differentiation may or may not exist Significant barriers to entry Oligopoly Models 8 16/11/16 Oligopoly Models Oligopoly models focus on how firms react to each other’s moves ¡ ¡ Cournot (1835): each firm chooses the quantity to produce and the resulting total quantity determines the market price Bertrand (1883): each firm selects a price and stands ready to meet all the demand for its product at that price If the output cannot be increased quickly (capacity decision is made ahead of actual production) Cournot competition is the result o o o Antoine Augustin Cournot (1801-1877) Applicable for long-run decisions Homogeneous products Market price results from total supply If the firms can adjust the output quickly, Bertrand type competition will ensue o o Applicable for short-run decisions Firms satisfy all the demand (no capacity constraints) Joseph Bertrand (1822-1900) Cournot Duopoly Cournot (Nash) equilibrium is a pair of outputs Q*1 and Q*2 and a market price P* that satisfy three conditions: ¡ ¡ ¡ P* is the price that clears the market: P* = 100 – Q*1 – Q*2 Q*1 maximises firm 1’s profits if it guesses Q*2 correctly Q*2 maximises firm 2’s profits if it guesses Q*1 correctly Each firm expects its rival to choose the Cournot equilibrium output ¡ ¡ If one of the firms is off the equilibrium, both firms will have to adjust their outputs Equilibrium is the point where adjustments will not be needed 9 16/11/16 Cournot Duopoly Paul and Jane compete in the local craft beer market ¡ ¡ ¡ ¡ Both have constant marginal cost of €10 Both have total cost equal to 10Q Market demand: P = 100 – QPaul – QJane Price decreases for each unit of additional (total) output Both decide their production quantity at the same time Both are willing to lower the price until all their beer is sold Paul chooses QPaul to maximise profits taking QJane as given ¡ ¡ Paul ‘guesses’ how much Jane will produce – we assume Paul can guess correctly Paul’s output level is the best response to what he expects Jane to produce Jane’s and Paul’s firms are identical, so the Cournot equilibrium is to split the market 50-50 ¡ at a level of QPaul = QJane that maximises both Jane’s and Paul’s profits Cournot Duopoly Paul maximises his profits (Jane’s function is a mirror image of Paul’s) ¡ ΠPaul = Revenue – Total cost = P*QPaul – TCPaul = ¡ (100 – QPaul – QJane)QPaul – 10QPaul = 100QPaul – QPaul2 – QPaul*QJane – 10QPaul ∂ΠPaul/∂QPaul = 100 – 2QPaul – QJane – 10 = 90 – 2QPaul – QJane ¡ Profit maximising QPaul: 90 – 2QPaul – QJane = 0; -2QPaul = -90 + QJane; QPaul = 45 – 0.5QJane ¡ ¡ Paul’s reaction function: QPaul = 45 – 0.5QJane ¡ ¡ ¡ If Paul thinks Jane will increase production, he will produce less in order to maximise his profits Jane’s problem is a mirror image of Paul’s Solving both firms’ reaction functions simultaneously gives the best responses of Paul to Jane (Q*Paul) and Jane to Paul (Q*Jane) ÷ ÷ ¡ Thus, Q*Paul=Q*Jane=30 P*=100-30-30=€40 Both Paul and Jane make a profit of €900 ÷ P*Q – MC*Q = ([€40*30]-[€10*30]) = €900 10 16/11/16 Bertrand Duopoly Firms have sufficient capacity to produce any amount they can sell ¡ ¡ Their task is to choose the profit-maximising price While holding the rival’s price as fixed (based on their best guess) If products are homogeneous ¡ The Bertrand model results in P=MC ¡ Because firms think that they can capture the whole market by undercutting the rival’s price If products are differentiated ¡ A price cut does not steal the whole market but only some of the rival’s customers ¡ This discourages cut-throat price competition such as in the case of identical products Bertrand Duopoly Customers view Paul and Jane’s beers as perfect substitutes ¡ ¡ Cournot equilibrium price was €40 Bertrand equilibrium price would be €10 If Paul sets his price at €39, he captures the whole market So Jane has to match that price and has an incentive to cut her price further to €38 to capture the whole market ÷ It follows that in the end, both set their price equal to MC = €10 ÷ ÷ Customers view Paul’s and Jane’s beers as horizontally differentiated ¡ ¡ ¡ Some customers like Jane’s beers more, others prefer Paul’s If Jane cut her price, she could attract some of Paul’s customers but not all of them, and vice versa So price cuts are not as attractive a strategy as in the case of the beers being perfect substitutes 11 16/11/16 Bertrand Duopoly PPaul Jane’s reaction function Paul’s reaction function €18 €11 €19 €23 PJane Stackelberg Model Turns the simultaneous move game in Cournot duopoly Into a sequential move game where one party commits to its quantity decision first This constitutes a strategic commitment Strategic commitments ¡ have long run impact ¡ are hard to reverse ¡ can affect choices made by rivals by altering their expectations 12 16/11/16 Stackelberg Model Modify the Paul and Jane Cournot duopoly model by allowing Paul to decide his quantity first How does Paul’s commitment change the outcome? ¡ Jane’s reaction function: QJane = 45 – 0.5QPaul ¡ If Paul decides first, Jane doesn’t have to guess Paul’s quantity – she knows it ¡ Having the same reaction function, Paul knows Jane’s ¡ So Paul knows exactly how much Jane will produce, in response to any QPaul ¡ Paul’s choice of QPaul thus determines total quantity and market price ¡ Paul can maximise his profits by choosing QPaul = 45 ¡ This changes the profits such that instead of each earning €900 as in the Cournot case ÷ ÷ Paul earns €1012.50 Jane earns €506.25 By committing to produce 45 instead of 30 units, Paul forces Jane to cut back her production to 22.5 units – and increases his profits Stackelberg Model Paul can maximise his profits by choosing QPaul = 45 based on the following information ¡ Price: P = 55 – 0.5QPaul ÷ ¡ P = 100 – (QPaul + QJane) = 100 – [QPaul + (45 – 0.5QPaul)] = 100 – 45 – QPaul + 0.5QPaul = 55 – 0.5QPaul Profit: ΠPaul = P(QPaul) – 10QPaul = (55 – 0.5QPaul)QPaul – 10QPaul ÷ Setting the derivative of the profit function with respect to QPaul equal to zero gives the profit maximising QPaul = 45 Jane’s response: QJane = 45 – 0.5(45) = 22.5 Market price: P = 100 – QPaul – QJane = 100 – 45 – 22.5 = €32.50 Profits: ¡ Paul: P(QPaul) – 10QPaul = 32.5(45) – 10(45) = €1012.50 ¡ Jane: P(QJane) – 10QJane = 32.5(22.5) – 10(22.5) = €506.25 13 16/11/16 Real Options The value of commitments lies in creating inflexibility However, when there is uncertainty ¡ Flexibility is valuable since future options are kept open ¡ Commitments can sacrifice the value of the options A real option exists if future information can be used to tailor decisions ¡ Better information about demand can be utilised by delaying implementation of projects ¡ Value of real options may be limited by the risk of preemption Real Options: Example Jane wants to expand the availability of her beers to another city In order to do that, she needs to invest €100K to production capacity She forecasts two equally likely scenarios for the net present value (NPV) of cash flows from the investment ¡ ¡ Wide product acceptance: €300K Low product acceptance: €50K If Jane invested now, the expected NPV of the investment would be ¡ 0.5(300) + 0.5(50) – 100 = €75K 14 16/11/16 Real Options: Example By waiting one year, Jane would know which scenario arises ¡ Assume NPV of alternative investment is 0 ¡ The discount rate for waiting a year is 10% Wide product acceptance ¡ During the year, a competitor has taken some of the market and the NPV of the investment has reduced to €200K ¡ Even if Jane could anticipate it, she should still wait and invest a year later ¡ Because her NPV of €91K is higher than the NPV of immediate investment (€75K) ÷ [0.5(200) + 0.5(0)]/(1.10) = €91K Low product acceptance ¡ Jane would not invest at all ¡ So she would avoid a potential loss by waiting IT’S QUIZ TIME! (IF WE HAVE TIME) 15