Download Public support for creating a market economy in Eastern Europe

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Free-market anarchism wikipedia , lookup

Embedded liberalism wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
www.elsevier.com/locate/jce
Public support for creating a market economy
in Eastern Europe
Bernd Hayo
Philipps-University Marburg, Department of Economics (FB 02), D-35032 Marburg, Germany
ZEI, University of Bonn, Germany
Received 11 September 2002; revised 22 July 2004
Hayo, Bernd—Public support for creating a market economy in Eastern Europe
Employing two large databases, we analyze the determinants of public support for the creation
of a market economy in Eastern Europe. From a macroeconomic perspective inflation, unemployment, privatization, and enterprise restructuring reduce this support; alternatively, democratization,
the creation of working financial markets, and foreign aid per capita increase support for the market.
Across countries, higher inequality undermines market support. From a microeconomic perspective,
labor market status, both the objective and the subjective economic situations of a person, political
orientation, and the socio-demographic background of the respondent affect support for the market
economy. For example, unemployed, relatively poor, older, female, and less-educated respondents
living in rural areas are less inclined to favor the creation of a market economy. Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (4) (2004) 720–744. Philipps-University Marburg, Department of Economics (FB
02), D-35032 Marburg, Germany; ZEI, University of Bonn, Germany.
 2004 Association for Comparative Economic Studies. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
JEL classification: P1; P2; O52
Keywords: Economic transition; Market economy; Eastern Europe; Public support
E-mail address: [email protected].
0147-5967/$ – see front matter  2004 Association for Comparative Economic Studies. Published by Elsevier
Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jce.2004.07.003
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
721
1. Introduction
Public support for the creation of a market economy is key to a successful transformation program. Williamson (1994) identifies strong political support for the reformer as one
of the three most important ingredients.1 Although not a sufficient condition, public support appears to increase the chance that reforms will be feasible and successful (Stokes,
1996). Assessments of the actual progress in the Eastern European economic transitions,
e.g. EBRD (1999) or IMF (2000), do not provide much information on determinants of
public support for a market economy. On the theoretical side, Rodrik (1996), Drazen (2000)
and Roland (2002) survey the growing body of work on economic policy reform, in which
public support for the reforms, either directly or indirectly, is crucial. However, most theoretical models simply assume that certain variables, especially unemployment and per
capita income, are important determinants of public support for reforms, without providing the empirical evidence to support these assertions.
Our analysis investigates the determinants of public attitudes towards creating a market
economy by employing survey data collected in Eastern European countries, which are in
the process of transforming their centrally planned economies into Western-style market
economies. While no general theory of transition is available, Blanchard (1997) presents a
partial equilibrium model of economic transformation. His model consists of a transition
economy in which decision-makers have perfect foresight to capture the stylized fact of
a U-shaped evolution of output and employment in most Eastern European economies.
The author assumes that public support for economic reforms is also U-shaped. Blanchard
provides survey evidence from Poland regarding the determinants of the perception of both
the current and the expected economic situations of people and shows that unemployment
and output do affect attitudes. However, if the democratic political process were to be
endogenized, Blanchard (1996) demonstrates that the chosen reform path might not be
achievable.
Fidrmuc (2000) investigates public support for the market in Eastern Europe empirically, but indirectly. He uses election results from four countries to analyze political support
by explaining voting shares for reform and non-reform parties using various regressors,
e.g., unemployment, entrepreneurial activity, and demographic factors. Actual votes may
indicate true revealed preferences rather than only the intentions reported by respondents
in surveys. However, voting for a party cannot be attributed easily to only one policy issue.
Therefore, it is not clear whether voters prefer a party because of its stance on economic
reform or because of its position on maintaining order, improving democracy, or national
defense. Warner (2001) investigates the relationship between the intensity of market reforms and electoral support for reform parties in Russian regions from 1990 to 1995. He
finds that reform parties garnered more support in the 1995 parliamentary elections in those
regions where greater progress was made in structural reforms.
In principle, public attitudes towards creating a market economy can be measured directly from opinion polls. Early attempts by Shiller et al. (1991, 1992) to compare Eastern
European attitudes with those of Western countries are interesting but limited to studying
1 The other two listed conditions for successful reforms are a visionary leadership and a coherent economic
team.
722
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
whether Eastern European opinions during times of transformation contain an attitudinal
legacy from Communist times.2 Concentrating on the labor market and taking into account a time dimension, Blanchflower abd Freeman (1997) compare the market attitudes
of respondents in Eastern and Western Europe using the large International Social Survey Programme (ISSP) database. In contrast to Shiller et al., these authors find evidence
of an attitudinal legacy from the Communist times.3 In comparing the development in
Poland and Russia, Shleifer (1997) incorporates possible differences in trust and participation in civic activities, which he computes using the World Values Survey. In his view,
the emerging differences in social capital are not a key determinant of differences in economic performance. Eble and Koeva (2002) investigate attitudes towards market reforms
in Russia after the crisis in 1998 using survey data.4 They find that individual attitudes
towards reforms are affected by the personal experiences of the respondents during the
transition process. In addition, groups that are distinguished by education and age appear
to be more flexible in adjusting to new situations. Finally, these authors conclude that respondents from Russian regions in which a high percentage of workers have received no
wage payments within the last month are not supportive of market reforms.
Our paper investigates public support for creating a market economy empirically using two representative survey databases, namely the Central and Eastern Eurobarometers
(CEEB) and the New Democracy Barometers (NDB). Both surveys ask about the respondent’s attitude towards the creation of the market but not about particular reform strategies
that will lead to a market system. We employ static and dynamic panel data methods in the
macroeconomic level analysis and cross-section regressions in the microeconomic level
analysis. The paper is structured as follows. In Section 2, the database and econometric
methodology are described. Theoretical reasons for an aggregate analysis of support for a
market economy are summarized in Section 3 and the corresponding empirical results are
shown in Section 4. Section 5 presents microeconomic level analyses using the NDB and
CEEB data. The final section concludes with policy implications.
2. The databases
The Central and Eastern Eurobarometers (CEEB) database, which is collected on behalf
of the European Commission, is used for macroeconomic analysis because the number of
countries and the collection of repeated cross-sections over time make it possible to construct a panel data set using average national values. In general, about 1000 people in
each country were selected randomly for a personal interview in the autumn of the respective year. The first surveys in 1990 were undertaken only in Czechoslovakia, Hungary and
Poland, while the most extensive survey from 1996 provides data on twenty countries.5
2 This idea is related to the importance of initial economic and political conditions to the success of the
transformation (de Melo et al., 2001).
3 Frentzel-Zagorska and Zagorski (1993) provide survey evidence from Poland on this issue.
4 Finifter and Mickiewicz (1992) document survey evidence from the former USSR.
5 The primary data are available from the Zentralarchiv für Empirische Sozialforschung (ZA) in Cologne
(http://www.za.uni-koeln.de/index-e.htm). This survey project ended in 1997.
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
723
Single CEEB surveys have been aggregated to cover the time period from 1990 to 1997
and include data on 21 countries.6 Hence, the aggregated data base contains responses from
about 120,000 people.
Using the CEEB data, Kim and Pirttilä (2003) find evidence that countries showing
greater public support for market reforms also achieve higher growth rates eventually. To
control for possible endogeneity, we use the general method of moment (GMM) estimation
technique. The CEEB data have problems concerning the consistent and regular coverage
of important questions across different surveys because many interesting questions are
eliminated over time. In addition, only a few demographic variables are collected over
time and some countries are also eliminated.
The New Democracy Barometers (NDB) database, which was initiated by the Centre
for Public Policy at Strathclyde University in Glasgow, is used for microeconomic analysis
of a cross-section in 1995. Because it contains a rich set of individual-level questions, we
can control explicitly for several potentially important factors. On the downside, the NDB
covers only seven countries, namely the Czech Republic, the Slovak Republic, Slovenia,
Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Bulgaria, and contains only one relevant round of surveys
in 1995 for our question of interest. The NDB is based on personal interviews and designed
to be a random sample of the population (Rose and Haerpfer, 1993).7 Although limited
in terms of available variables, the CEEB database can also be used in microeconomic
analysis to investigate the robustness of the results from the NBD. However, we must be
confident that we are measuring similar things in the two databases.
The CEEB database focuses on one issue, namely a person’s opinion about the creation
of a market economy. The specific question is:
Do you personally feel that the creation of a free market economy, that is one largely
free from state control, is right or wrong for (our country’s) future?
The answers to that question are coded into three categories, namely ‘wrong’ (−1),
‘don’t know’ (0), and ‘right’ (1), to form the dependent variable called SUPPORTCEEB.
To get aggregate values, we compute the mean values of SUPPORTCEEB for every country at each point in time.8 In the case of NDB, we create a variable measuring market
support that may be advantageous methodologically because it measures the concepts of
interest directly. The notion of a market economy is not defined easily so that capturing it
by asking one specific question is problematic. The NDB uses four variables related to core
aspects of a market economy. The questions investigate whether people prefer differential
or equal incomes, private or state property, high pay but job risk or a secure job, and many
goods but high prices or price controls. Considering more than one indicator increases the
6 Observations from Albania, Armenia, Belarus, Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Georgia,
Hungary, Kazakhstan, Latvia, Lithuania, Macedonia, Moldova, Poland, Romania, Russia, Slovakia, Slovenia,
Ukraine, Yugoslavia are included.
7 The primary data for the NDB are not accessible for researchers who are not members of the Citizens in
Transition Network (CITNET).
8 Keeping the ‘don’t know’ responses is highly desirable for maintaining representativeness of the sample.
However, forming a dichotomous dependent variable by dropping the ‘don’t know’ category yields similar results.
724
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
chances that we are measuring actual attitudes towards the market in general and not just
perceptions about a single aspect of the market economy.
Taking into account these considerations, we condense the information from the NDB
through factor analysis. As Appendix Table 1 in the reports, exactly one factor can be
extracted and all of the factor loadings are larger than the usual threshold of 0.5. We interpret the factor extracted from the four questions as indicating public support for the market
economy and denote it SUPPORTNDB. Moreover, this factor is valid not only at the aggregate level but also at the national level. The Spearman rank correlation coefficient between
the averages of SUPPORTCEEB and SUPPORTNDB based on the ten countries covered in
the NDB in 1995 is 0.72, which is significant at a 5% level. Hence, we find strong support
that the two variables from different data sources measure a similar concept.
Figure 1 plots public support for the market economy over time using averages of SUPPORTCEEB for the countries in the sample. These values can be interpreted as the share
Fig. 1. Public support for the market economy across countries: mean values for SUPPORTCEEB.
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
725
Fig. 2. The aggregate evolution of support for the market economy.
of net supporters, i.e. supporters minus opponents in relation to all respondents, of the creation of a market economy.9 In the next section, the apparent differences across countries
are investigated statistically, conditional on the influence of other explanatory variables.
To generate information about the overall time trend for market support in Eastern Europe,
two regressions are run to analyze market support first by year dummies only and then
by year and country dummies. The resulting coefficients for the year dummies are plotted
in Fig. 2; both series indicate that support was at a minimum in 1994. Although the coefficients obtained from the regression having only year dummies are consistent with the
prediction of Blanchard (1997) that support for the market is U-shaped over time, the series
based on the regression including year and country dummies is multi-peaked.10
3. Theoretical determinants of support for the market at the aggregate level
The relevant variables for investigating public support at the aggregate level are listed in
Table 1 with descriptive statistics and expected effects included. These variables are chosen
based on the literature and divided into categories of indicators, namely, macroeconomic
indicators, standard of living, fiscal policy, transition progress, external influences, political
institutions, and political business cycles. Lipton and Sachs (1990) claim that fundamental
economic reform involves three core elements, namely, macroeconomic stabilization, economic liberalization, and privatization of state enterprises. Williamson (1994) provides a
similar list, denoting it as the Washington Consensus. In addition, Drazen (2000) stresses
the importance of political institutions and processes in economic policymaking to justify
the inclusion of political institution and indicators of the political business cycle.
9 Standard deviations to measure dispersion are also computed to investigate the consensus of opinion within
society. The average of SUPPORTCEEB and its standard deviation are negatively correlated with a coefficient of
−0.60 that is significant at a 1% level. Hence, the lower is the degree of support for market reforms, the larger is
the disagreement in society on this issue.
10 Because not all Eastern European countries started economic reforms at the same time, it may be more
meaningful to include a proxy for transformation or stabilization time. Therefore, we constructed transformation
time trends that count years since the start of economic stabilization programs (Fischer et al., 1998). However,
a transformation trend variable and its square are both less significant than the year dummies (Hayo, 1999b).
726
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
Table 1
Aggregate variables: sources, descriptive statistics, and priors
Variable name
Definition
Dependent variable
SUPPORTCEEB
Country average of individual
level attitudes towards creating
a market economy
Macroeconomic indicators
DGDP
GDP growth, in %
UNEMP
Unemployment rate, in %
INFLAT
Inflation rate, in % p.a.
FXRATE
Change in log of exchange rate
against SDR, in %
Standard of living indicators
GDPCAP
GDP per capita, in constant
US dollars (base: 1995)
RADIOS
Number of radios in the
country (per 1000 people)
LIFEEXP
Life expectancy
GINI1
Gini coefficient
GINI2
Gini coefficient (adding WDI
Gini coefficients of countries
not in GINI1)
Fiscal policy indicators
GOVGDP
Ratio of government
expenditure to GDP, in %
GOVDEF
Ratio of government surplus to
GDP, in % (deficit = negative
value)
Transition indicators
ENTERPRISE
Average of large-scale
privatization, small scale
privatization, and enterprise
restructuring
MARKETS
Average of price liberalization,
trade and foreign exchange
system, and competition policy
FINANCE
Average of banking reform and
interest rate liberalization, and
securities markets and
non-bank financial institutions
External indicators
OPENNESS
Ratio of trade in goods and
services to GDP, in %
AIDGNP
Foreign aid in relation to GNI,
in %
AIDCAP
Foreign aid per capita, in US
dollars
FDICAP
Net foreign direct investment
per capita, in US dollars
Source
Mean
Std. dev.
Expected
sign
CEEB
0.12
0.28
EBRD
EBRD
EBRD
IMF
−0.22
10.14
260.20
192.65
7.69
5.18
780.14
676.00
+
−
?
?
WDI
2830.30
2157.90
+
WDI
473.75
178.68
+
WDI
Milanovic
Milanovic,
WDI
70.08
34.36
32.35
2.47
11.07
8.26
+
−
−
EBRD
41.67
8.59
?
EBRD
−4.95
6.95
?
EBRD
2.68
0.76
+
EBRD
2.84
0.47
+
EBRD
2.16
0.63
+
WDI
92.39
34.33
−
WDI
2.04
3.59
+
WDI
26.30
20.87
+
571.00
833.08
?
EBRD
(continued on next page)
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
727
Table 1 (continued)
Variable name
IMFSUPPORT
Definition
Dummy variable: IMF
program running at the time of
the survey
Political institutions indicators
EXREC
Executive recruitment
EXCONST
Executive constraints
POLCOMP
Political competition
POLCONV
Number of independent
branches of government with
veto power over policy change
including the judiciary and
sub-federal units
Political business cycle indicators
ELECTYEAR
Dummy variable, taking the
value 1 if an election occurs in
that particular year
Source
Mean
Std. dev.
Expected
sign
IMF
0.38
0.49
+
Polity
Polity
Polity
Henisz
7.45
5.95
8.04
0.54
1.25
1.48
1.88
0.29
+
+
+
−
Fidrmuc
0.39
0.49
+
Notes. Only 78 observations are used to compute the descriptive statistics that correspond to those employed in
the analysis in Table 2.
Sources. CEEB: Central and Eastern Eurobarometers survey database. EBRD: Transition Report. IMF:
International Financial Statistics. IMF program constructed using information from http://www.imf.org/
external/country/. WDI: World Bank Development Indicators CD-Rom 2002. Milanovic: Branco Milanovic’s estimates http://www.worldbank.org/research/transition/house.htm). Polity: Polity IV database (http://www.cidcm.
umd.edu/inscr/polity/). Henisz: Henisz (2000). Fidrmuc: We extend special thanks to Jan Fidrmuc for providing
these data.
For macroeconomic indicators, we take inflation, exchange rates, unemployment, and
GDP growth. Typically, the IMF proposes stabilization programs to reduce high rates
of inflation. Moreover, in survey data, people often express serious concern about inflation (Di Tella et al., 2001; Fischer and Huizinga, 1982; Hayo, 1998a, and Rose, 1998).
However, neither theoretical nor empirical evidence of negative economic effects of moderate inflation is compelling, as Driffil et al. (1990) and Bruno and Easterly (1998) attest.
Nonetheless, inflation rates in excess of 1000 percent per year have been observed in some
of the transition countries, e.g., Armenia, Belarus, and Kazakhstan. Thus, we conjecture
that inflation may influence public support for the creation of a market economy in a nonlinear fashion.
For transition countries, Fischer et al. (1996a, 1996b) argue that eliminating high inflation is a requirement for economic growth. Yavlinsky and Braguinsky (1994) think that
alternative policies, e.g., de-monopolization, should be addressed before monetary policy
is tightened. Finally, Mondino et al. (1996) present a model of an inflation cycle, in which
inflation goes down rapidly after the adoption of a stabilization program but increases
again when the reform is abandoned. In their model, the inflation rate drives public support
for reforms and, as soon as the inflation rate is reduced significantly, support for the program collapses. Thus, evidence of the actual effects of inflation on public opinion towards
economic reforms may contribute to an assessment of these conflicting hypotheses. For
robustness, we consider the exchange rate as another indicator of inflationary conditions.
728
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
Hence, we designate an ambiguous expected sign for inflation and the exchange rate in
Table 1.
Unemployment is included to capture the labor market situation, following the theoretical models of Blanchard (1997), Fidrmuc (1999), and Rodrik (1995). However, measuring
unemployment in transition countries may be unreliable (UN, 1997, p. 114f).11 Nonetheless, we expect higher unemployment to lead to less support for reforms so we report a
negative expected sign for this variable in Table 1. In addition, we consider GDP growth
because it contains information about the dynamic effects of income evolution in the respective economies. Typically, living standard is proxied by income per capita, which is an
important component in many theoretical models of public support for reforms. Alternative indicators to national accounts data for measuring the standard of living, namely life
expectancy and the number of radios in a country, are included to assess the robustness of
our findings. The growth of GDP and the three standard of living indicators are expected
to have a positive effect on support for reforms. In addition Drazen (2000) argues that the
distributional consequences of economic reforms may lead to strong opposition to the creation of the market. Thus, we include the Gini index as a measure of income inequality and
expect the sign of the coefficient to be negative.
Although IMF programs emphasize a reduction in both the share of government expenditures in GDP and budget deficits, East European countries may find it beneficial to incur
some fiscal debt during the transition period. Fernandez and Rodrik (1991) show that the
existence of ex ante uncertainty about winners and losers from the reforms may prevent
the implementation of efficiency-enhancing reforms, even though people would have supported the reforms ex post. Hence, if people can be assured that they will benefit from the
reforms, even if they turn out to be losers according to the previous distribution of income,
the likelihood of public support for the reform will be higher. Alesina and Drazen (1991)
make a similar argument based on a war of attrition. Since fiscal budgets are dominated
by social spending, a large share of government expenditures with a resulting high budget deficit mitigates the adverse distributional consequences of the transformation. Due
to countervailing tendencies, we report ambiguous signs for the fiscal policy indicators in
Table 1.
The EBRD computes indices to reflect the extent of small-scale and large-scale privatization, enterprise restructuring, and price liberalization. In addition, progress in liberalizing
trade and foreign exchange, the development of competition policy, and the reform of banks
and other financial institutions are measured. Stiglitz (1999) argues that privatization has
not been successful in most East European countries because the problems encountered in
this process have a negative impact on public support for market reforms. Nevertheless, we
expect improvements measured by the three aggregate EBRD transition indicators to have
a positive impact on support for reforms as Table 1 records.
Regarding external influences, Krueger (1993) shows that certain trade policies may
have asymmetric effects on different groups within an economy and, thus, affect the balance of political power. Furthermore, some groups may link economic problems to foreign
11 In an earlier working paper, we used employment rather than unemployment and the corresponding esti-
mation results were not significant. In addition, several problems arise when computing real GDP per capita but
using an index instead of an actual value did not yield very different results (Hayo, 1999b).
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
729
capital or international trade, as La Ferrara (1996) asserts. Although foreign direct investment (FDI) can be a catalyst in modernizing the transition economies, a high share of FDI
may indicate that foreigners have an unwelcome position of power. For these reasons, we
consider the degree of openness of the economy to have a negative impact and FDI to have
an ambiguous effect on public attitude to reform. On the other hand, foreign economic
aid may facilitate the creation of a market if it comes from market economies. Hence, we
expect foreign aid to have a positive impact on support for reforms as Table 1 reports. The
IMF plays a prominent role in Eastern Europe not only by providing guidance on macroeconomic policies and structural reforms but also by providing extensive credit programs.
Since its intervention is not always viewed as beneficial as Stiglitz (2003) argues, whether
or not the existence of such an active credit program affects public support for market reforms in a country is an open question but we expect these programs to have a positive
effect on balance.
With respect to political institutions, empirical evidence indicates that the introduction
of economic reforms is influenced by initial conditions and by changes in the political system (de Melo et al., 2001; Falcetti et al., 2002; EBRD, 1999). In addition, Hayo (2001)
claims that economic developments affect public perceptions of the progress in political
reforms towards democracy. To capture the impact of political institutions, we consider
the effects of the impartiality of executive recruitment practices, the constraints facing the
executive, and the degree of political competition. The latter variable characterizes constraints to political participation and the expression of alternative preferences for policy
and leadership. These three variables are taken from the Polity IV database, which contains
information on regime and authority characteristics for all independent states and covers
years from 1800 to 2002. Our working hypothesis is that, if these measures are close to
those in Western-style democratic political systems, the probability of establishing a market economy will be higher so that we record positive expected signs for their coefficients
in Table 1. Data are also available in Henisz (2000) on the degree of veto power within
the political system, which affects the ability of the political system to implement market
reforms. We expect this variable to have a negative influence on public support for reforms.
Finally, we consider the effect of a political business cycle by including a dummy variable
if an election occurs in the current year. We expect elections to have a positive impact on
public support for market reforms because politicians will try to improve the performance
of the economy so as to increase their chances of re-election.
4. The estimation results at the aggregate level
Initially, we investigate net support for market reforms at an aggregate level using an
unbalanced panel across countries and years. To avoid problems caused by missing data,
the sample starts in 1991 and excludes Moldova and Yugoslavia. In the empirical analysis,
we take into account all potentially important variables in a single model because the inclusion of variables one by one, or in groups, may lead to spurious results. However, having
730
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
a large model containing many insignificant variables is not desirable.12 Under these circumstances, Hendry (1993) advocates a modeling strategy moving from general to specific
to ensure that the inferences drawn are statistically valid throughout the reduction process.
Since statistical inference may be path-dependent, the final parsimonious model might not
be an encompassing one. Based on the examination of the vices and virtues of data mining by Hoover and Perez (1999), Hendry and Krolzig (1999) develop a model reduction
algorithm, denoted GETS, that is surprisingly powerful in recovering the underlying data
generating process. Moreover, GETS ensures that a favorable diagnostic test result for the
general model is preserved during the reduction process. Applying this empirical approach
has its drawbacks. First, the number of variables that can be analyzed consistently is limited by the available degrees of freedom. As is often done in similar studies, analyzing
blocks of variables in separate models allows us to consider many more variables. Second, the outcome of the reduction process depends on the general model. Including some
variables but not others may affect significantly the resulting parsimonious model. Finally,
generating a data set that contains no missing values for all the relevant variables reduces
our sample size from 101 to 78. The statistical validity of the general model is crucial to
the GETS algorithm.13
We encounter some problems with the normality assumption caused by two outliers;
these are neutralized by including dummy variables for the Czech Republic in 1996 and
Romania in 1991. Model 1 in Table 2 reports the outcome of the reduction process using all the explanatory variables listed in Table 1, except for the Gini coefficients, and
including dummies for years, countries, and outliers. The F -test for testing down in the
next-to-last row indicates that the model presented is an admissible reduction of the general
model. With regard to the diagnostic tests, we cannot reject normality or homoscedasticity;
inaddition, we find no evidence of autocorrelation or of misspecification using a first-order
RESET test (Ramsey, 1969). Since the White (1980) test may not pick up heteroscedasticity within the panel structure of the data, we also report heteroscedastic-consistent standard
errors (HCSE) in an added column.
Regarding the deterministic components, none of the yearly dummies survives the
testing-down process. Compared to the Czech Republic and conditional on the influence
of the other variables in Model 1, market support is significantly lower in the Ukraine
and Russia, similar in Armenia, Belarus, Georgia, Kazakhstan and Slovenia, and higher
in the rest of the countries listed in Table 2. Of the macroeconomic variables, only inflation and unemployment survive reduction. An increase in the inflation rate of 100 percent
per annum decreases the share of net support for the market economy by one percentage
point, which is equivalent to saying that 10 respondents out of 1000 who were undecided
before the increase in inflation would not support the creation of a market economy after the change. To assess the economic significance of the analyzed variables in contrast
to their statistical significance, we evaluate their impact on public support at their means
across countries given in Table 1. This table also contains the standard deviations of the
12 Hayo (1998b) presents some methodological remarks regarding the advantages of simple models.
13 Constructing average country values based on ordinal individual observations is problematic. However, Hayo
(1999b) shows that many of these results hold if an ordered logit model that adjusts the standard errors of the
macroeconomic variables is estimated at the individual level.
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
731
respective variables to indicate how representative the mean is for a particular country.
Evaluating the effect of the inflation rate at its mean, which is about 260 percent, shows a
reduction in the share of net support by 2.6 percentage points. This effect has a noticeable
impact on public support in countries with high inflation rates, e.g., Armenia, Belarus, and
Kazakhstan, while it has little relevance for most other countries. Hayo (1999b) does not
find a non-linear relationship between inflation and support for reforms when he includes
inflation in logs or adds squared values. Hence, we conclude that people react to inflation
in these countries by reducing their support for reforms in an approximately linear way,
especially in high inflation countries.
Table 2
Aggregate level estimation: testing-down procedure
Model:
1
Estimator:
OLS
Variables
Coefficients
SE
HCSE
Coefficients
ASE
−0.0001***
−0.016***
0.002**
0.104**
−0.171***
0.037***
0.00002
0.004
0.001
0.043
0.037
0.009
0.00002
0.004
0.001
0.052
0.050
0.012
−0.057
−0.0001***
−0.007
0.002**
0.128**
−0.158**
0.039**
0.177
0.00002
0.006
0.001
0.063
0.061
0.018
0.549***
−0.746***
0.112
0.116
0.045
0.044
0.738***
0.304***
0.403***
0.225***
0.178***
0.281***
0.449***
0.506***
−0.319***
0.218***
−0.392***
0.083
0.056
0.062
0.054
0.066
0.060
0.056
0.053
0.070
0.068
0.073
0.102
0.076
0.070
0.048
0.058
0.065
0.057
0.042
0.040
0.051
0.068
Substantial variables
SUPPORTCEEBt-1
INFLAT
UNEMP
AIDCAP
FINANCE
Enterprise
Polcomp
Outliers
Czech Republic, 1996
Romania, 1991
Country dummies
Albania
Bulgaria
Estonia
Hungary
Latvia
Lithuania
Poland
Romania
Russia
Slovak Republic
Ukraine
No. of obs.
SE of regression
Pseudo-R 2
F -test, all variables
F -test, substantial
Variables
Autocorrelation
Heteroscedast.
Normality
2
Panel GMM
78
0.104
0.90
F (19, 59) = 32.2***
F (6, 59) = 15.3***
45
0.175
0.65
χ 2 (7) = 82.3***
χ 2 (6) = 75.6***
N (0, 1) = −1.30
F (25, 33) = 0.96
χ 2 (2) = 0.81
N (0, 1) = 0.68
(continued on next page)
732
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
Table 2 (continued)
Model:
1
2
Estimator:
OLS
Panel GMM
Variables
Coefficients
RESET
Testing down
Sargan test
F (1, 58) = 0.03
F (28, 31) = 0.89
SE
HCSE
Coefficients
ASE
χ 2 (91) = 38.5
Notes. 1. The sample period is 1991 to 1997. 2. Moldova and Yugoslavia are excluded due to missing observations.
3. Model 1 results from a GETS testing-down process based on a model that contains a full set of country dummies (base: Czech Republic) and year dummies (base: 1991), a constant, dummies for Czech Republic in 1996
and Romania in 1991, and the variables DGDP, UNEMP, INFLATION, FXRate, GDPCAP, RADIOS, LIFEEXPECT, GOVGDP, GOVDEF, ENTERPRISES, MARKETS, FINANCE, OPENNESS, AIDGDP, AIDCAP,
FDICAP, IMFSUPPORT, EXREC, EXCONST, POLCOMP, POLCONV, and ELECTIONYEAR. 4. Autocorrelation is a panel data test for autocorrelated residuals of order two; heteroscedasticity is the White (1980) test
using squares of the regressors; heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors (HCSE) are based on White (1980).
Normality is the Jarque and Bera (1987) test with a small-sample correction and RESET is a misspecification test
developed by Ramsey (1969). The Sargan test relates to the orthogonality condition between instruments and error term. 5. The Pseudo-R 2 statistics are based on the correlation between the original series and the fitted series.
6. Model 2 uses the GMM Arellano–Bond (Arellano and Bond, 1991) one-step estimator in first differences. The
robust standard errors (ASE) are computed according to Arellano (1987). The level instruments are lags 2 to 5 of
the variables UNEMP, INFLATION, ENTERPRISES, FINANCE, AIDCAP, and POLCOMP.
** Significance at the 5% level.
*** Idem., 1%.
We find that increasing the unemployment rate by one percent reduces the share of net
support for the market by 1.6 percentage points. However, this estimate is not very robust
as it depends upon the particular specification of the model (Hayo, 1999b). Evaluating the
effect of the unemployment variable at its mean, which is about 10%, unemployment reduces the share of net support by about 16 percentage points. Thus, unemployment has
the expected negative effect and its quantitative effect is moderate. Nonetheless, the labor
market experiences of Eastern Europeans can be considered as only one determinant of
public support for the reforms. In a similar exercise, Valev (2004) finds that the power of
unemployment in explaining voting for reform parties in Bulgaria is limited. None of the
indicators for the standard of living or for the fiscal policy stance survives the testing-down
procedure. However, two EBRD transition progress indicators are significant.14 First, improvements in financial deregulation and the establishment of functioning financial markets
increase support for reforms. The economic impact of this variable, measured at its sample
mean, on the net share of support is 23 percentage points. Second, the variable capturing
privatization and enterprise restructuring is negative and significant in most East European
countries, which is consistent with the view that privatization has not been a major success. Moreover, the quantitative effect at its mean on the net share of support for reforms at
46 percentage points is twice as large as that of the financial progress indicator. Using this
14 Krueger and Ciolko (1998) argue that the liberalization indices overemphasize the role of policy because
they are partially endogenous with regard to the outcomes.
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
733
method of quantification, privatization also has a much larger negative impact on public
support for reforms than does unemployment.
Regarding the external influences, foreign aid per capita has a significantly positive effect on public support for the market. At its mean value of 26.3, the economic impact of
this variable on the net share of market support is small at 5 percentage points. To keep net
market support constant when unemployment increases by one percentage point, annual
foreign aid would have to rise by about 300 dollars per capita. Such an increase is more
than ten times the average annual foreign aid actually paid over the sample period. Of the
political institution indicators, only political competition has a significant impact on public
support for market reforms. At its sample mean of 8.04, political competition increases the
share of net support by 30 percentage points, which is a sizeable effect. Since the upper
limit of this indicator is 10, further progress in democratization will raise the share of public
support for the market by a maximum of 7 percentage points only. Nonetheless, increasing
the degree of democratization affects support for the market economy positively. The transition in Eastern Europe is viewed by the populace as comprising both the introduction of
a market economy and the creation of a democratic political system (Hayo, 2001). Hence,
the Asian strategy of separating economic and political reform is not relevant for Eastern
Europe. Finally, we find no evidence of a significant influence of the political business
cycle on public support for the market economy.
To check the robustness of our findings, we investigate reverse causality, i.e. the possibility that public support affects the explanatory variables. The graphs in Fig. 1 indicate
some persistence in the support variables, which necessitates the inclusion of a lagged dependent variable as a regressor. Thus, we re-estimate Model 1 using a general method of
moments estimator (GMM) with a lagged dependent variable (Arellano and Bond, 1991).
In Model 2 of Table 2, the lagged dependent variable is not significant; in addition, the
signs, and even the sizes, of most coefficients with the exception of unemployment are
almost unchanged. Since endogeneity does not appear to bias the coefficients in the ordinary least squares regression (OLS), we conclude that the results from the static panel
data model are robust. Given that we would expect lags in the impact of public support for
economic reforms on actual performance, this result is not surprising.
Finally, we consider the effect of inequality as measured by the Gini coefficient and
report our results in Table 3. Due to missing values, the relevant sample is small and the
statistical tests lose much of their power. However, all models in Table 3 pass the diagnostic
tests listed in Table 2. In Model 3, we restrict the analysis to a bivariate framework using the
Gini coefficients computed by Milanovic, which are comparable across countries. We find
negative and significant effects of inequality on public support for reforms at a 10% level
of significance. To analyze the robustness of this result, we extend the inequality series by
adding the Gini coefficients as computed by the World Bank, although full comparability
across countries is no longer ensured. We estimate the impact of inequality on market
support by including year dummies to control for trend or cycle effects in Model 4. The
coefficient on the Gini variable is smaller in magnitude than that in Model 3 but it is now
significant at the 5% level. Then, we include country but not year dummies as controls in
a model with this Gini coefficient in Model 5. The addition of country dummies causes
the Gini coefficient to lose its statistical significance. Hence, the Gini coefficient explains
734
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
Table 3
Aggregate level estimation: inequality
Model:
3
4
Estimator:
OLS
OLS
Variables
Coeff.
SE
HCSE
GINI1
GINI2
CONSTANT
Year dummies
Country dummies
No. of obs.
R2
F -test
−0.02*
0.008
0.005
0.71**
0.28
no
no
11
0.315
F (1, 9) = 4.1*
0.26
Coeff.
−0.012**
0.60***
5
OLS
SE
0.006
0.18
yes
no
37
0.302
F (7, 29) = 1.8
HCSE
Coeff.
0.006
0.19
0.004
0.13
SE
HCSE
0.011
0.009
0.27
0.23
no
yes
37
0.750
F (15, 21) = 4.2***
Notes. 1. The sample period is 1991 to 1997. 2. The estimated equations pass all of the diagnostic tests listed in
Table 2 for Model 1. 3. GINI1 is the inequality measure computed by Milanovic, while GINI2 combines GINI1
with data from the WDI. 4. The data contain observations that are not included in Model 1 of Table 2 to increase
the degrees of freedom.
* Significance at the 10% level.
** Idem., 5%.
*** Idem., 1%.
differences in public support for market reforms across countries to some extent but it has
no explanatory power across time within countries.
To summarize the results from the aggregate analysis, we find that lower values of the
inflation rate, the rate of unemployment, and the degree of privatization increase public
support for the creation of a market economy. Public support also rises as a consequence
of higher values of foreign aid per capita, the degree of restructuring of the financial system,
and democratization. In the theoretical literature on economic reforms, the unemployment
rate is assumed to be of particular importance. We find noticeable economic effects of this
variable but, among this group of statistically significant determinants of market support,
the EBRD indicator for privatization progress has the biggest influence.
5. Determinants of support for the market at the individual level
In this section, we switch focus from the macroeconomic perspective to the microeconomic view by using SUPPORTNDB as the dependent variable in regressions investigating
people’s individual opinions of market creation. Because the sample is relatively large, we
use a significance level of 1%, which makes the tests very sensitive to a violation of the null
hypothesis (Leamer, 1983). By extracting the factor that describes support for the market
economy, we create a variable with a pseudo-cardinal scale. Hence, the regression analysis
is relatively straightforward and we can use OLS. The first two columns of Table 4 report coefficient estimates for a regression that includes all the variables, while the last two
columns contain only those variables that remain after a consistent testing-down process.
The White (1980) test for heteroscedasticity is significant so that we compute robust standard errors to ensure valid inference. The large sample size makes the use of these standard
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
735
Table 4
Public support for the market economy at the individual level
Estimator:
General economic situation
Economic system evaluation
Socialist system good
Current system good
Privatization speed
Right speed
Too slow
Personal employment situation
Type of employer
State enterprise
Privatized enterprise
Private enterprise
Co-operative farmer
Independent farmer
Type of employment
Part-time employment
Apprentice
Unemployed
Pensioner
Allowance
Housewife, student
Most important personal economy
House repairs
Paid for favors
Help of friends
Currency
Second job
Paying tips
First job
Pensions, benefits
Job benefits
Objective economic situation
Income
Lower-middle quartile
Upper-middle quartile
Highest quartile
Financial situation
Got by
Spent savings
Borrowed money
Spent & borrowed
Living conditions
Never without food
Never without heating
Never without needed clothes
OLS
OLS
Coefficients
HCSE
Coefficients
HCSE
−0.293***
0.093***
0.023
0.022
-0.294***
0.093***
0.022
0.021
0.145***
0.215***
0.034
0.027
0.136***
0.227***
0.033
0.027
−0.078***
0.046
0.067
−0.036
0.106
0.030
0.044
0.041
0.068
0.128
−0.086***
0.024
−0.025
0.135
−0.106**
−0.098**
−0.042
0.010
0.049
0.133
0.052
0.049
0.059
0.050
−0.147***
−0.133***
0.044
0.037
−0.021
−0.284**
−0.058
0.500***
0.159
−0.124
0.028
−0.060
−0.064
0.054
0.135
0.072
0.152
0.065
0.079
0.031
0.036
0.154
0.516***
0.158***
0.148
0.060
−0.001
0.118***
0.192***
0.028
0.031
0.033
0.129***
0.210***
0.025
0.027
−0.104***
−0.064
−0.162***
−0.088
0.036
0.042
0.047
0.056
−0.075***
0.022
-0.132***
0.034
0.062**
0.031
0.071***
0.025
0.025
0.024
0.077***
0.024
0.079***
0.024
(continued on next page)
736
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
Table 4 (continued)
Estimator:
Subjective economic situation
Personal economics situation
Was better 5 years ago: Yes
Will be better in 5 years time: Yes
Economic situation satisfactory: Yes
Regular job income sufficient: Yes
Political orientation
Type of democrats
Anxious democrat
Dejected authoritarian
Hopeful authoritarian
Socio-demographic variables
Age
Age
Age squared
Gender effect
Female
Family size
Number of children
Education
Vocational training
Secondary School
University
Community size
5001–20000 inhabitants
20001–100000 inhabitants
> 100000 inhabitants
Church attendance
Seldom
Several times a year
Once a month
Every week
Religion
Protestant
Orthodox
Muslim
Other
Nonbeliever
No answer
Constant
Valid cases
F -test
Adjusted R 2
Maximum Cook’s distance
Heteroscedasticity test
OLS
OLS
Coefficients
HCSE
Coefficients
HCSE
−0.070***
0.096***
0.094***
0.086***
0.022
0.020
0.025
0.030
−0.078***
0.103***
0.108***
0.067**
0.021
0.020
0.024
0.027
−0.059**
−0.150***
−0.255***
0.030
0.033
0.029
−0.130***
−0.232***
0.032
0.028
−0.012***
0.00003
0.004
0.00004
−0.009***
0.001
−0.121***
0.020
−0.117***
0.020
0.011
0.013
0.121***
0.247***
0.433***
0.030
0.029
0.036
0.123***
0.251***
0.441***
0.029
0.028
0.035
0.012
0.092***
0.164***
0.030
0.027
0.030
0.081***
0.157***
0.023
0.026
0.060
0.084**
0.117***
0.081**
0.033
0.035
0.043
0.040
0.053**
0.085***
0.024
0.033
−0.027
−0.010
−0.087
0.027
0.010
−0.029
0.096
0.048
0.040
0.080
0.058
0.040
0.063
0.117
0.114
0.067
8321
F (69, 8251) = 57***
0.27
0.005
F (71, 8179) = 1.93***
8321
F (34, 8286) = 111***
0.27
0.008
F (35, 8250) = 1.92***
(continued on next page)
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
737
Table 4 (continued)
Estimator:
OLS
Coefficients
RESET Test (fourth order)
Test for excluding variables
F (3, 8248) = 3.79**
OLS
HCSE
Coefficients
HCSE
F (3, 8283) = 3.52**
F (35, 8251) = 1.62**
Notes. 1. The sample period is 1995. 2. Country dummies for Czech Republic, Bulgaria, Slovakia, Hungary,
Poland, Romania, Slovenia, Belarus, and Ukraine are included in the regressions. 3. The reference categories
are: Privatization speed (too fast), Type of employer (public agency), Type of employment (full-time employment), Most important personal economy (growing food), Income quartiles (lowest quartile), Financial situation
(saved money), Type of democrats (confident democrat), Education (primary school), Community size (< 5000
inhabitants), Church attendance (never goes to church), and Religion (Catholic).
** Significance at the 5% level, using White’s heteroscedasticity-consistent standard errors (HCSE).
*** Idem., 1%.
errors less problematic. A RESET test for misspecification of order four is not significant
at a 1% level; hence, we conclude that the model is an adequate description of the data. The
maximum value of Cook’s distance is very small, indicating that leaving out even the most
influential observation will not alter the estimated coefficients substantially. An analysis of
variance, which is not reported, shows high collinearity only for age and age squared.
The explanatory variables are grouped according to categories, namely, the respondent’s
evaluation of the general economy, indicators of the person’s employment situation, objective indicators of the person’s economic situation, subjective indicators of the economic
situation based on the respondent’s characterization, the political orientation of the respondents, and socio-demographic variables. In our interpretation of the results, we focus on the
variables that remain after the testing-down process. Starting with the overall economic situation, we find that people who are in favor of the socialist system do not support a market
economy. Although this may seem obvious, the variable that characterizes the system evaluation did not load on the same factor as the ones that were combined into the dependent
variable SUPPORTNDB. Similarly, people who are in favor of the current system also support the market but the magnitude of this effect is not as large as the previous one. Hence,
the current system in 1995 is not seen, and correctly so, as a full-fledged market economy
by the respondents. Respondents who believe that the speed of privatization is adequate
are more in favor of the market economy than those who think it is too fast; however, those
who consider the speed to be too slow are even more supportive of market reforms.15
Regarding the respondent’s employment situation, we find that those working for a state
enterprise are least in favor of reforms because they are most likely to lose in a market
economy. Analyzing the type of employment reveals that unemployed people are skeptical about market reforms, which is consistent with our findings at the aggregate level. In
transition countries, pensions are not adjusted fully for inflation. Fidrmuc (2000) expresses
surprise that he finds no straightforward evidence that a high share of pensioners vote
against reform parties. In our data set, pensioners have significantly more critical attitudes
toward the market economy than do full time employees. This result may explain partially
15 Hayo (1997) provides a more detailed analysis of attitudes toward privatization in Eastern Europe using
CEEB data.
738
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
the significant effect of the inflation rate in the macroeconomic analysis. Working in the
regular job market is only one way to make a living, especially during a period of transition
in which people have other sources of income. Those respondents who can get a second
job or who obtain additional income by dealing with currencies tend to support the market
reforms. Both of these activities were not permitted legally under the Communist rule so
that they may be considered to be black market gains.
Investigating the objective economic situation of the respondents, we find that those in
the upper-middle and highest quartiles are more in favor of the market economy compared
with the relatively poorer respondents. Apparently, this group has taken advantage of the
new economic opportunities. In addition, relatively rich people are not exposed to the economic hardship resulting from greater income disparity that evolved in the transition years,
as Cornelius and Weder (1996) and Milanovic (1999) discuss. Compared to those who are
able to save some money, other groups are more negative about the market economy; the
least support comes from those who have to borrow money to survive. The indicators for
living conditions show that those not lacking food and clothes support the market more
than the omitted group who face shortages of essentials. Although we do not find evidence
of the impact of income and wealth in public opinion situation in the macroeconomiclevel analysis, we do find robust effects at the microeconomic level. This difference may
be due to problems with official statistics in providing reliable information about living
conditions, at least during the early stages of transformation (Hayo and Seifert, 2003). The
subjective economic situation of the respondent also plays a role in determining attitudes
towards the market economy. A person who felt better off in the past is less likely to favor
market reforms, while a person who expects to be better off in the future will be more supportive of reforms. If today’s economic situation is considered satisfactory, the respondent
indicates support. Finally, if the income from one’s regular job is considered sufficient,
market support also increases.
The political orientation of respondents is analyzed using a typology of democrats derived by Rose et al. (1998). We find that respondents with less democratic attitudes are
less likely to support a market economy. A person who is hopeful that an authoritarian regime can run the economy successfully is less in favor of reforms than a person
who considers an authoritarian regime to be only the better of two bad alternatives.
This result is consistent with the empirical literature on economic and political transition in Eastern Europe that show people who support democracy will also support the
market and vice versa, as Rose et al. (1998) and Hayo (2001) demonstrate. This result may also help to explain the significance of a political variable, i.e., the degree
of political competition, in the aggregate analysis. Finally, we find that some sociodemographic variables also explain attitudes towards the market. The age of a person
is an important consideration in the literature on modernization; we find a negative
sign for this variable indicating that older persons are less in favor of reforms in accord with the views of Apter (1965) and Huntington (1968). In addition, women are
less supportive of market reforms than men, which is consistent with results for Western Europe indicating skepticism about economic reforms among women (Gabriel, 1992;
Hayo, 1999a). A possible explanation for this skepticism is the labor market barriers created for women as a result of reduced spending on child care opportunities and a change in
equal employment practices. Furthermore, since women are less involved in the political
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
739
and economic decision-making process, they may think that they cannot shape the changes
in their countries. Experimental studies show that women tend to be more risk averse than
men (Basow, 1986 and Sorrentino et al., 1992). Thus, women may be more reluctant to
support major political or economic reforms, the outcome of which is uncertain.
With regard to education, we find that people having more advanced degrees support
market reforms, most likely because they can expect higher future returns from their education than would have been the case in a centrally planned economic system. Empirical
evidence, e.g. Brainerd’s (1998) for Russia, Vecernik’s (1995) for the Czech Republic,
Orazem and Vodopivec’s (1995) for Slovenia, and Rutkowski’s (1996) for Poland, indicates
that persons with higher education fare relatively better under the new market system.16
Regarding the size of the community in which the respondent lives, we find that people
who live in larger communities are more likely to support market reforms perhaps because
more market opportunities are available in larger cities. Church attendance has a significant influence on public opinion; people who go to church moderately often but regularly
tend to favor the market. Many political reform movements during the Communist era in
Eastern Europe were linked closely to the church, especially in Poland; hence, people in
these congregations are likely to view the market positively.
In summary, we compare the microeconomic results derived from the NDB with those
from the CEEB database. Table 5 reports the results of an ordered logit analysis with public support for market reforms measured by SUPPORTCEEB as the dependent variable.
Differences between the significance of the coefficients for income and education and the
ones from Table 4 are found for the second categories of income quartiles and education
only. Regarding age, the CEEB data show a U-shaped effect compared with the linear relationship found using NDB data. However, the minimum effect of age on public support
of reforms calculated from Table 5 is 66 years, while the age effect becomes positive at the
irrelevant age of 132. Thus, non-linearity is not really relevant for realistic age spans. Overall, the microeconomic results are similar across the two data sets, which lends credibility
to their interpretation.
6. Summary and conclusion
In this paper, we investigate public support for the creation of a market economy using
two large survey data sets. The questions in the surveys are directed towards the outcome
of the reform process, i.e., a market economy, rather than the actual reform process itself.
However, stronger support for the outcome makes the implementation of reform strategies
easier for policy makers. If a fast-track approach produces high inflation, falling per capita
income, and higher unemployment, combined with expectations of a medium-run recovery
based on a fully re-structured economy, public support for market-oriented reforms may be
dissipated before the process reaches a critical point (Bresser Pereira et al., 1993, and Dewatripont and Roland, 1992a, 1992b). Alternatively, if people do not attach much weight
16 Moreover, Ham et al. (1998) attribute the superior labor market performance of the Czech Republic as
compared to the Slovak Republic to the absorption of low-skilled workers, indicating that education is a good
insurance against unemployment.
740
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
Table 5
Explaining support for the market economy using SUPPORTCEEB (ordered
logit)
Variables
Income
Lowest income quartile
Lower-middle quartile
Upper-middle quartile
Highest income quartile
Education
Primary school
Vocational training
Secondary school
University
Age
Age in years
Age in years squared
Gender
Female
Valid cases
Log likelihood
χ 2 -test
Pseudo R 2
Coefficients
Std. err.
Reference group
0.1266***
0.2404***
0.4979***
0.0178
0.0189
0.0197
Reference group
0.0266
0.3357***
0.6712***
0.0208
0.0195
0.0245
−0.0409***
0.00031***
0.0020
0.00002
−0.1969***
0.0131
93723
−88940.3
χ 2 (36) = 13074***
0.069
Notes. 1. The estimates for country dummies, time dummies, and constant
terms are omitted from the table. 2. The reference categories are: Income (lowest quartile) and Education (primary school).
*** Significance at the 1% level.
to macroeconomic indicators when they choose to support market reforms, a rapid transition would be preferable. Blanchard (1997) predicts that the path of support for reforms
will be U-shaped because, if one endogenizes political decisions, reforms may be delayed
considerably. However, we find little evidence to support this conjecture.
Our macroeconomic analysis suggests that the IMF’s focus on lowering inflation is consistent with maintaining support for market reforms. However, the magnitude of the impact
of moderate inflation rates on public support is relatively small so that a critical level of
support for the reforms cannot be achieved simply by keeping inflation relatively low.
A higher unemployment rate has a negative effect on market support but its magnitude is
also too small to consider the labor market as the main explanation for market support, as
do many theoretical models. The negative relationship between unemployment and market
support at the aggregate level is supported by robust evidence at the microeconomic level.
Our results also show that fast privatization reduces support for the reforms, which reflects
problems with the privatization process in many East European countries. Alternatively,
progress in establishing working financial markets leads to more market support, although
the net effect of these two indicators of structural reform on public support is negative.
In addition, we find that higher per capita foreign aid is associated with stronger support
for reforms, indicating the possibility of supporting the creation of market economies from
outside even though the purchasing power of an additional dollar of foreign aid is relatively
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
741
small. A higher degree of political competition fosters support for the market, which reflects the interdependencies between economic and political transformation in Eastern Europe. Finally, income inequality may have a negative impact on market support. However,
the predictive power of the Gini coefficient explains only differences across countries but
not differences within one country across time. Nonetheless, economic policies that generate increased inequality along with other positive outcomes must be considered carefully.
With respect to the microeconomic-level results, we note that making policy recommendations based on the individual characteristics of people is problematic. An obvious policy
concern is the support of the more disadvantaged groups in society, e.g., the unemployed
and pensioners. Regarding the personal economic situation of people, providing resources
to satisfy basic human needs such as food and clothes may also have a positive effect on
support for market reforms. Raising the level of education will increase public support for
the market eventually but this policy will not have an immediate impact; thus, it will not
be able to boost support for reforms during the critical early phase of transition. Finally,
incorporating the interest of women in the design of transformation policies will broaden
the political base for support.
Since we do not identify one overwhelming determinant of public support for market
reforms, a package of policies is the most effective strategy for creating a market economy. A useful starting point for East European governments is to keep inflation down
and to provide basic support for those citizens who lack food and shelter. Industrial countries could support these transition polices by raising the level of foreign aid per capita.
Although economic transition without unemployment is impossible, and increasing unemployment lowers public support for the reforms, the magnitude of this effect is not dramatic
in the early stages of transformation. The citizens in Eastern Europe seem to understand
that unemployment must increase during economic restructuring. However, overly quick
privatization and enterprise restructuring should be avoided, while the establishment of
functioning financial markets should be promoted as quickly as possible. Hence, the debate
over shock therapy and gradualism is mainly academic because our empirical results suggest that a specific combination of rapid and gradual measures will succeed in maintaining
public support for the reforms. Finally, we conclude that economic and political transition
are perceived to be two parts of the same package by the populace in Eastern Europe because transforming the political system to ensure free political competition raises support
for market reforms. Such interdependence argues against an Asian strategy in which the
creation of a market precedes the establishment of a democracy.
Acknowledgments
Special thanks to John Bonin for outstanding editorial input, and three anonymous referees, Jörg Breitung, Jan Fidrmuc, Michael Funke, Arik Levinson, Bernd Lucke, Robert
MacCulloch, Dieter Nautz, Birgit Uhlenbrock, Jürgen von Hagen, Christian Weller, Jürgen
Wolters, participants of the Eastern Economic Association Annual Conference in Crystal
City, European Public Choice Society Annual Meeting in Siena and of Research Seminars
at Humboldt-University Berlin, University of Bonn, Essen University, Georgetown University, University of Hamburg, and the Center for European Integration Studies for helpful
comments. The usual disclaimer applies.
742
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
Appendix Table 1
Factor analysis of market economy indicators
Factor 1
Explained variance, in %
Factor loadings
Respondent prefers: differential incomes vs. equal
Respondent prefers: private property vs. state
Respondent prefers: high pay and risk vs. secure job
Respondent prefers: lots of goods, higher prices vs. price controls
41
0.70
0.72
0.58
0.56
Notes. 1. The number of cases is 9782. 2. One factor is extracted by applying the usual criterion of taking factors
with eigenvalues larger than 1.
References
Apter, David E., 1965. The Politics of Modernization. Prentice Hall, NJ.
Alesina, Alberto, Drazen, Allan, 1991. Why are stabilizations delayed? American Economic Review 81, 1170–
1188.
Arellano, Manuel, 1987. Computing robust standard errors for within-groups estimators. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 49, 431–434.
Arellano, Manuel, Bond, Stephen, 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data. Review of Economic Studies 58, 277–297.
Basow, Susan A., 1986. Gender Stereotypes: Traditions and Alternatives. Brooks/Cole, Monterey.
Blanchard, Olivier, 1996. Lecture 3: Putting things together. Clarendon lectures. Mimeo.
Blanchard, Olivier, 1997. Clarendon Lectures: The Economics of Transition in Eastern Europe. Oxford Univ.
Press, Oxford.
Blanchflower, David, Freeman, Richard, 1997. The legacy of Communist labor relations. Industrial and Labor
Relations Review 50, 438–459.
Brainerd, Elizabth, 1998. Winners and losers in Russia’s economic transition. American Economic Review 88,
1094–1116.
Bresser Pereira, Luiz C., Maravall, Jose M., Przeworski, Adam, 1993. Economic Reforms in New Democracies:
A Social-Democratic Approach. Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge.
Bruno, Michael, Easterly, William, 1998. Inflation crises and long-run growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 41, 3–26.
Cornelius, Peter K., Weder, Beatrice S., 1996. Economic transformation and income distribution—some evidence
from the Baltic countries. IMF Staff Papers 43, 587–604.
De Melo, Martha, Denizer, Cevdet, Gelb, Alan, Tenev, Stoyan, 2001. Circumstance and choice: The role of initial
conditions and policies in transition economies. World Bank Economic Review 13, 1–32.
Dewatripont, Mathias, Roland, Gerard, 1992a. The virtues of gradualism and legitimacy in the transition to a
market economy. Economic Journal 102, 291–300.
Dewatripont, Mathias, Roland, Gerard, 1992b. Economic reform and dynamic political constraints. Review of
Economic Studies 59, 703–730.
Di Tella, Raphael, MacCulloch, Robert, Oswald, Andrew, 2001. Preferences over inflation and unemployment:
Evidence from surveys of happiness. American Economic Review 91, 335–341.
Drazen, Allan, 2000. Political Economy in Macroeconomics. Princeton Univ. Press, Princeton.
Driffil, John, Mizon, Grayham E., Ulph, Alistair, 1990. Costs of inflation. In: Friedman, Benjamin, Hahn, Frank
(Eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 1013–1066.
Eble, Stephanie, Koeva, Petya, 2002. What determines individual preferences over reform? Microeconomic evidence from Russia. IMF Staff Papers 49, 87–110.
European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD), 1999. various issues. Transition Report. EBRD,
London.
Falcetti, Elisabeth, Raiser, Martin, Sanfey, Peter, 2002. Defying the odds: Initial conditions, reforms, and growth
in the first decade of transition. Journal of Comparative Economics 30, 229–250.
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
743
Fernandez, Raquel, Rodrik, Dani, 1991. Resistance to reform: Status quo bias in the presence of individualspecific uncertainty. American Economic Review 81, 1146–1155.
Fidrmuc, Jan, 1999. Unemployment and the dynamics of political support for economic reforms. Journal of Policy
Reform 3, 139–159.
Fidrmuc, Jan, 2000. Political support for reforms: Economics of voting in transition countries. European Economic Review 44, 1491–1513.
Finifter, Ada W., Mickiewicz, Ellen, 1992. Redefining the political system of the USSR: Mass support for political
change. American Political Science Review 86, 857–874.
Fischer, Stanley, Huizinga, John, 1982. Inflation, unemployment and public opinion polls. Journal of Money,
Credit, and Banking 14, 39–51.
Fischer, Stanley, Sahay, Ratna, Végh, Carlos A., 1996a. Economies in transition: the beginnings of growth.
American Economic Review 86, 229–233.
Fischer, Stanley, Sahay, Ratna, Végh, Carlos A., 1996b. Stabilization and growth in transition economies: the
early experience. Journal of Economic Perspectives 10, 45–66.
Fischer, Stanley, Sahay, Ratna, Végh, Carlos A., 1998. From transition to market: evidence and growth prospects.
Working paper No. 98/52. International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Frentzel-Zagorska, Janina, Zagorski, Krzysztof, 1993. Polish public opinion on privatisation and state intervention. Europe–Asia Studies 45, 705–728.
Gabriel, Oskar W., 1992. Die EG-Staaten im Vergleich. Westdeutscher Verlag, Opladen.
Ham, John C., Svejnar, Jan, Terrell, Katherine, 1998. Unemployment and the social safety net during transitions
to a market economy: evidence from the Czech and Slovak Republics. American Economic Review 88, 1117–
1142.
Hayo, Bernd, 1997. Eastern European public opinion on economic issues: privatization and transformation. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 56, 85–102.
Hayo, Bernd, 1998a. Inflation culture, central bank independence and price stability. European Journal of Political
Economy 14, 241–263.
Hayo, Bernd, 1998b. Simplicity in econometric modelling: some methodological considerations. Journal of Economic Methodology 5, 247–261.
Hayo, Bernd, 1999a. Knowledge and attitude towards European Monetary Union. Journal of Policy Modeling 21,
641–651.
Hayo, Bernd, 1999b. Public support for market reforms in Eastern Europe. Studies in Public Policy, No. 321.
Centre for the Study of Public Policy, Glasgow.
Hayo, Bernd, 2001. A note on democratization and economic conditions in Eastern Europe. Journal of SocioEconomics 30, 559–562.
Hayo, Bernd, Seifert, Wolfgang, 2003. Subjective economic wellbeing in Eastern Europe. Journal of Economic
Psychology 24, 329–348.
Hendry, David F., 1993. Econometrics: Alchemy or Science? Blackwell, Oxford.
Hendry, David F., Krolzig, Hans-Martin, 1999. Improving on ‘Data mining reconsidered’ by K.D. Hoover and
S.J. Perez. Econometrics Journal 2, 202–219.
Henisz, Witold J., 2000. The institutional environment for economic growth. Economics and Politics 12, 1–31.
Hoover, Kevin D., Perez, Stephen J., 1999. Data mining reconsidered: encompassing and the general-to-specific
approach to specification search. Econometrics Journal 2, 167–191.
Huntington, Samuel P., 1968. Political Order in Changing Societies. Yale Univ. Press, New Haven.
International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2000. World Economic Outlook. International Monetary Fund, Washington,
DC.
Jarque, Carlos M., Bera, Anil K., 1987. A test for normality of observations and regression residuals. International
Statistical Review 55, 163–172.
Kim, Byung-Yeon, Pirttilä, Jukka, 2003. The political economy of reforms: empirical evidence from postCommunist transition in the 1990s. BOFIT discussion paper No. 4. Bank of Finland, Helsinki.
Krueger, Anne O., 1993. Virtuous and vicious circles in economic development. American Economic Review 83,
351–355.
Krueger, Gary, Ciolko, Marek, 1998. A Note on initial conditions and liberalization during transition. Journal of
Comparative Economics 26, 718–734.
744
B. Hayo / Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (2004) 720–744
La Ferrara, Eliana, 1996. A political equilibrium approach to trade liberalization in developing countries. Journal
of International Trade and Economic Development 5, 287–318.
Leamer, Edward E., 1983. Model choice and specification analysis. In: Griliches, Zvi, Intriligator, Michael D.,
Schmidt, Peter (Eds.), Handbook of Econometrics, vol. 1. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 285–330.
Lipton, David, Sachs, Jeffrey, 1990. Creating a market economy in Eastern Europe: the case of Poland. Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity 1, 75–133.
Milanovic, Branko, 1999. Explaining the increase in inequality during transition. Economics of Transition 7,
299–341.
Mondino, Guillermo, Sturzenegger, Federico, Tommasi, Mariano, 1996. Recurrent high inflation and stabilization: a dynamic game. International Economic Review 37, 1–16.
Orazem, Peter, Vodopivec, Milan, 1995. Winners and losers in transition: Returns to education, experience and
gender in Slovenia. World Bank Economic Review 9, 201–230.
Ramsey, James B., 1969. Tests for specification errors in classical linear regression analysis. Journal of the Royal
Statistical Society, Series B 31, 350–371.
Rodrik, Dani, 1995. The dynamics of political support for reforms in economies in transition. Journal of the
Japanese and International Economies 9, 403–425.
Rodrik, Dani, 1996. Understanding economic policy reform. Journal of Economic Literature 34, 9–41.
Roland, Gerard, 2002. The political economy of transition. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16, 29–50.
Rose, Richard, 1998. What is the demand for price stability in post-communist countries? Problems of PostCommunism 45, 43–50.
Rose, Richard, Haerpfer, Christian, 1993. Adapting to transformation in Eastern Europe: New democracies
barometers II. Studies in public policy, No. 212. University of Strathclyde, Glasgow.
Rose, Richard, Mishler, William T., Haerpfer, Christian, 1998. Democracy and its Alternatives. Understanding
Post-Communist Societies. John Hopkins Univ. Press, Baltimore.
Rutkowski, Jan, 1996. High skills pay off: The changing wage structure during economic transition in Poland.
Economics of Transition 4, 89–112.
Shiller, Robert J., Boycko, Maxim, Korobov, Vladimir, 1991. Popular attitudes toward free markets: the Soviet
Union and the United States compared. American Economic Review 81, 385–400.
Shiller, Robert J., Boycko, Maxim, Korobov, Vladimir, 1992. Hunting for homo sovieticus: Situational versus
attitudinal factors in economic behavior. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 127–181.
Shleifer, Andrew, 1997. Government in transition. European Economic Review 41, 385–410.
Sorrentino, Richard M., Hewitt, Erin C., Raso-Knott, Patricia A., 1992. Risk-taking in games of chance and skill.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 62, 522–533.
Stiglitz, Joseph E., 1999. Whither reform? Paper prepared for the Annual Bank Conference on Development
Economics. World Bank, Washington.
Stiglitz, Joseph E., 2003. Globalization and its Discontents. Penguin, London.
Stokes, Susan C., 1996. Public opinion and market reforms: The limits of economic voting. Comparative Political
Studies 29, 499–519.
United Nations (UN), 1997. Economic Survey of Europe in 1996–1997. Economic Commission for Europe. UN,
New York.
Valev, Neven, 2004. No pain, no gain: Market reform, unemployment, and politics in Bulgaria. Journal of Comparative Economics. September.
Vecernik, Jiri, 1995. Changing earnings distribution in the Czech Republic: survey evidence from 1988–1994.
Economics of Transition 3, 333–353.
Warner, Andrew M., 2001. Is economic reform popular at the polls? Russia 1995. Journal of Comparative Economics 29, 448–465.
White, Halbert, 1980. A heteroscedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroscedasticity. Econometrica 48, 817–838.
Williamson, John (Ed.), 1994. The Political Economy of Policy Reform. Institute for International Economics,
Washington.
Yavlinsky, Grigory, Braguinsky, Serguey, 1994. The inefficiency of laissez-faire in Russia: Hysteresis effects and
the need for policy-led transformation. Journal of Comparative Economics 19, 88–116.