* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Does the difference in valuation between domestic and foreign
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2010) 2886–2896 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Banking & Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf Does the difference in valuation between domestic and foreign investors help explain their distinct holdings of domestic stocks? Hyung Cheol Kang a, Dong Wook Lee b,*, Kyung Suh Park b a b Department of Business Administration, The University of Seoul, Seoul 130-743, Republic of Korea Korea University Business School, Seoul 130-701, Republic of Korea a r t i c l e i n f o Article history: Received 14 July 2009 Accepted 13 November 2009 Available online 22 November 2009 JEL classification: G11 G12 G15 Keywords: Investor heterogeneity Foreign investors Valuation difference Domestic stock holdings a b s t r a c t This paper proposes an investor heterogeneity approach to the different domestic stock holdings between domestic and foreign investors. Specifically, we hypothesize that domestic and foreign investors evaluate domestic stocks via different models and thus arrive at different valuations for them; consequently, the two investor groups are attracted to different sets of domestic stocks. Using panel data from Korea, we find strong support for our hypothesis. More precisely, we find that the foreign ownership of a stock increases with foreigners’ valuation for the stock in excess of that of domestic investors. As we control for various firm characteristics known to be correlated with foreign ownership, our results indicate that the valuation difference between domestic and foreign investors can help explain the allocation of domestic stocks between the two groups over and above the existing explanations. Ó 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction The conventional approach to the coexistence of domestic and foreign investors in a domestic market is based on information asymmetries, in which foreign investors are typically depicted as being informationally disadvantaged (e.g., Kang and Stulz, 1997; Brennan and Cao, 1997). In this framework, the two investor groups are predicted to become similar, since the assumed information asymmetries should shrink as the information of the better-informed is revealed through their trades. However, the stock holdings pattern of foreigners in a domestic market shows a continued difference from that of domestic investors, thereby raising concerns over this asymmetric information view (e.g., Karolyi and Stulz, 2003). In this paper, we propose an alternative approach to the different domestic stock holdings between domestic and foreign investors. Specifically, we adopt an investor heterogeneity perspective. This alternative approach is well motivated, since it allows for differences among investors to persist over time.1 Moreover, the usual * Corresponding author. Tel.: +82 2 3290 2820; fax: +82 2 3290 1307. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (H.C. Kang), [email protected] (D.W. Lee), [email protected] (K.S. Park). 1 See, e.g., Harrison and Kreps (1978), Varian (1985), Harris and Raviv (1993), Kandel and Pearson (1995), Allen and Gale (1999), Basak (2000), Coval and Thakor (2005), or Boot et al. (2006). 0378-4266/$ - see front matter Ó 2009 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.11.020 problems associated with investor heterogeneity—i.e., its measurability and the aggregability into a ‘‘composite” individual (see, e.g., Anderson et al., 2005)—are less of an issue in the context of locals vs. foreigners. It is because distinguishing between the two investor groups is fairly straightforward and the imperfect risk-sharing between them—often known as the home bias—suggests that the domestic market is incomplete and thus aggregating the two groups into a representative investor is not appropriate.2 The key to implementing this alternative approach is to identify and model an inherent difference between domestic and foreign investors. We do so by building on two stylized facts in international finance. One is that foreign investors are a return-chaser across countries3 and the other is that domestic investors prefer home-country stocks to overseas ones.4 Given that foreigners in a domestic market are international investors who invest in multiple countries and thus their performances are likely to be assessed in a global context, the former empirical regularity implies that for- 2 For the home bias, see, e.g., Lewis (1999) or Karolyi and Stulz (2003). For the aggregation of individual investors in relation to market completeness, see, e.g., Rubinstein (1974), Constantidies, 1982, Ingersoll (1987), or Cochrane (2001). 3 See, e.g., Bohn and Tesar (1996), Brennan and Cao (1997), Choe et al., 1999, 2005, Grinblatt and Keloharju (2000), Froot et al. (2001), or Froot and Ramadorai (2008). 4 See, e.g., French and Poterba (1991), Tesar and Werner (1995), or Lewis (1995, 1999). H.C. Kang et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2010) 2886–2896 eigners are attracted to domestic stocks when those stocks outperform stocks outside the domestic market. In other words, foreigners evaluate domestic stocks via a global benchmark. In contrast, the latter stylized fact suggests that domestic investors use a local benchmark to evaluate domestic stocks. While some domestic institutions may be investing abroad as well as at home, they are oftentimes an agent of domestic individuals and thus are compelled to pay attention to the domestic market. Consequently, we hypothesize that, due to the benchmark difference, the two investor groups have different valuations for domestic stocks and thus are attracted to different sets of domestic stocks. We test this hypothesis using data from Korea. This country has several features that qualify it as an instructive experimental setting. First, the preference of domestic investors for their home-country stocks is known to be more pronounced in emerging markets than in developed markets (e.g., Chan et al., 2005). As an emerging market that has been frequently examined by prior studies (e.g., Choe et al., 1999, 2005), Korea thus makes a good setting. Second, this market became fully open to foreigners following the 1997 financial crisis. Consequently, by focusing on the post-crisis period, we can ensure that the results are not driven by any formal barriers to foreigners investing in the market. Third, Korea uniquely offers insider ownership information for a large number of stocks and thus allows us to measure float-based foreign ownership. This data availability is not trivial, since shares held by insiders are not available to foreign investors and thus mechanically affect their stock holdings pattern (Dahlquist et al., 2003; Kho et al., 2006). Using the panel data from 2000 to 2004, we find strong support for our hypothesis. Specifically, we find that the valuation difference—foreign minus domestic—for a domestic stock is significantly and positively related to its foreign ownership. This means that foreigners hold the stocks for which their valuation is higher than that of domestic investors. In obtaining this result, we explicitly control for the valuation level, so that our finding can be correctly attributed to the valuation differential. To obtain a more instructive result, we cross-sectionally orthogonalize the foreign valuation to the domestic valuation (and vice versa). The resultant orthogonalized valuation measure is effectively the valuation difference that is unrelated to the cross-sectional pattern common to both valuation levels. Consistent with the earlier valuation difference result, we find that the orthogonalized foreign valuation is positively related to foreign ownership, whereas the orthogonalized domestic valuation has a negative relation to foreign ownership. In sum, the results clearly support our hypothesis that the allocation of domestic stocks between domestic and foreign investors is affected by their valuation difference. Before proceeding further, we stress that our goal is not to rule out any existing explanations but to ‘‘rule in” a new explanation for the distinct stock holdings between domestic and foreign investors in a domestic market.5 For this reason, we employ a large set of control variables and demonstrate that the valuation difference explains the allocation of domestic stocks over and above the existing explanations. More precisely, what is unique to our explanation is its emphasis on the interaction between domestic and foreign investors, in particular, the manner in which foreign investors as global returnchasers interact with domestic investors who are biased toward their home-country stocks. Of course, our analysis does not explain those trading and holdings patterns per se. As they persist over time, however, we hope to contribute to the literature by putting such persistent behavior of the two investor groups into the investor heterogeneity framework and clarifying its consequences for domestic stock allocation. In fact, it is conceivable—and even likely—that the hypothesized benchmark/valuation difference feeds back and reinforces the global return-chasing behavior and the preference for home-country stocks. Such a feedback channel definitely merits further investigation but seems to be beyond the scope of our paper. We believe that the focus of our paper—namely, the stock allocation among investors—is itself a crucial topic and our results serve as an important step toward other broader issues. Our results are also consistent with a recent theoretical work by David (2008) in which agents with heterogeneous beliefs employ different valuation models and compete with each other. Such competition makes risk-sharing imperfect and gives rise to a risk factor that commands a risk premium independent of the traditional market risk premium. In this regard, our results suggest that the country of residence is one useful dimension of heterogeneity that can help better understand the risk-sharing capacity of a market, especially that of an emerging market.6 This paper proceeds as follows. In the next section, we develop the testing hypotheses. Section 3 describes the sample and data, and Section 4 reports the empirical results. Section 5 concludes the paper. 2. Hypothesis 2.1. Background It is standard among economists to explain any difference in behavior or belief among investors using different information (e.g., Morris, 1995). It is thus natural to explain the observed difference in domestic stock holdings between domestic and foreign investors by their difference in the information set. The conventional approach in this spirit is the asymmetric information view, in which the information set of one investor group encompasses that of the other. One immediate implication of this approach is that such an informational (dis)advantage should shrink over time as the information of the better-informed is revealed, albeit imperfectly, through their trades. However, even after the massive financial integration that occurred in the 1980s and 1990s and the resultant reduction in barriers to information acquisition across countries, the difference in stock holdings between locals and foreigners persists (e.g., Karolyi and Stulz, 2003). What’s worse, empirical evidence regarding the information asymmetry between domestic and foreign investors is quite mixed (Grinblatt and Keloharju, 2000; Seasholes, 2000; Froot et al., 2001; Choe et al., 2005; Froot and Ramadorai, 2008; Kalev et al., 2008; Chang et al., 2009; Chen et al., 2009). Hence, an alternative approach is definitely warranted. One viable alternative is the investor heterogeneity perspective in which investors with the same information endowment behave differently because of their focus on different aspects of the common information. Specifically, this alternative approach postulates that investors either have different priors or employ different models to process information.7 This approach seems to be particularly promising in international finance, since many of the differences between locals and foreigners are in fact exogenous and thus make the two groups behave differently over a long time. It is thus worth asking whether domestic and foreign investors hold different domestic stock portfolios because they use information differently, not because their information endowments are different. To make this ap6 A recent study by Jung et al. (2009) is one such attempt. Earlier writers adopting this approach include Harrison and Kreps (1978), Varian (1985), Harris and Raviv (1993), Kandel and Pearson (1995), Allen and Gale (1999), Basak (2000), Coval and Thakor (2005), and Boot et al. (2006). 7 5 We borrow the expression ‘‘rule in” from Baker et al. (2009). 2887 2888 H.C. Kang et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2010) 2886–2896 proach operational, we need to specify the manner in which investors on an equal informational footing agree to disagree. The next section explains our specification.8 the accumulation of daily ownership changes occurring in response to the daily valuations. Specifically, we summarize the valuation during a given ownership updating interval by estimating the following equation: 2.2. Hypothesis development Ri;t ¼ ai þ bi RB;t þ ei;t ; 2.2.1. Idea To specify an inherent difference between domestic and foreign investors, we use two stylized facts in international finance, one of which concerns foreign investors and the other concerns domestic investors. First, foreign investors are known to be a return-chaser across countries. Given that they are international investors who also invest in other markets and thus their performances are likely to be assessed in a global context, their global return-chasing behavior suggests that foreign investors are attracted to domestic stocks when those stocks outperform stocks outside the domestic market. This notion leads us to postulate that foreign investors evaluate domestic stocks using a global benchmark. The other empirical regularity we use is that domestic investors have a strong preference for their home-country stocks. Such a preference is also known to be more pronounced in emerging markets than in developed markets.9 It thus follows that, unlike foreign investors, domestic investors—especially those in an emerging market—employ a local benchmark to evaluate local stocks. Of course, some of the domestic institutions may also be investing in overseas stocks. However, to the extent that domestic institutions manage funds on behalf of domestic individuals, the performance of those institutions will be evaluated against a local benchmark. Consequently, an instructive contrast can be made between domestic and foreign investors in terms of their benchmarks. Specifically, our idea is that domestic and foreign investors evaluate domestic stocks via different benchmarks and thus arrive at different valuations for domestic stocks. This implies that the two investor groups may be attracted to different sets of domestic stocks even though both groups have the same information endowment. We thus hypothesize that the allocation of domestic stocks between domestic and foreign investors is affected by their valuation difference. Below we discuss how we detect the hypothesized valuation differential and its impact on the allocation of domestic stocks between the two investor groups. 2.2.2. Setup for empirical predictions While the hypothesized valuation differential is likely to occur on a continual basis, its consequences—i.e., the allocation of domestic stocks between domestic and foreign investors—are in fact observed at a much lower frequency. For this reason, an empiricist cannot perfectly reconstruct the valuation process. As an alternative, we use a summary of these valuations, which is the average over the stock ownership updating interval. For example, suppose that investors evaluate domestic stocks on a daily basis but the ownership information is updated only annually. In such a case, we first obtain the average daily measure of foreigners’ valuation (relative to the local valuation) during a certain year and then associate it with the ownership information at the year-end, which is 8 Some prior studies note the cross-country differences in uncertainty with regard to consumption opportunities, inflation, or non-traded assets. Consequently, they correctly raise the possibility that locals and foreigners hold different stock portfolios because they use stocks to hedge against different types of uncertainty (e.g., Cooper and Kaplanis, 1994; Baxter and Jermann, 1997; Glassman and Riddick, 2001). However, none of these studies attempt to address the difference between locals and foreigners from the investor heterogeneity perspective. Moreover, these studies are focused exclusively on the overall underweighting of domestic stocks by foreigners, not the difference in stock selection between domestic and foreign investors. 9 For example, Chan et al. (2005) report that none of their sample mutual funds in emerging markets invest in overseas stocks (p. 1501). ð1Þ where Ri,t and RB,t are the returns on stock i and on benchmark portfolio B, respectively, and are both in excess of the risk-free rate. Here, the return measurement interval is the frequency at which investors evaluate the stock relative to the benchmark. This statistical model is well suited for our purpose, since it sep i;t Þ into the one that arates the average performance of a stock ðR B;t Þ and ^i R was actually replicable with the benchmark portfolio ðb ^ the one that was not ðai Þ. To account for the estimation precision, we scale the estimated alpha with the volatility of the residuals ðei;t Þ. The resultant scaled alpha is an ex-post look at how much the stock could have contributed to a higher Sharpe ratio over and above what could have been achieved by the benchmark portfolio alone (e.g., Treynor and Black, 1973; Gibbons et al., 1989; Pontiff, 2006; Bodie et al., 2008). Before deriving empirical predictions from this setup, we emphasize two things. One is that Eq. (1) is not introduced as an asset pricing model. As mentioned above, this is a statistical model that helps us understand the return on a stock that is not related to its benchmark. The other is that we do not argue that investors estimate Eq. (1) and change their position in the stock in accordance with the alpha estimate. Rather, our view is that investors constantly evaluate the stock in relation to the benchmark and the scaled alpha from Eq. (1) is an ex-post summary of those evaluations occurring during each of the return measurement intervals. Put simply, we estimate Eq. (1) to summarize the valuations to which investors continually responded over our estimation period. 2.2.3. Empirical predictions We summarize the valuation of foreign investors by estimating the following equation: Ri;t ¼ aFi þ bFi RF;t þ eFi;t ; ð2Þ where RF,t is the return on a global benchmark portfolio. Similarly, we estimate the following equation to summarize the valuation of domestic investors: Ri;t ¼ aDi þ bDi RD;t þ eDi;t ; ð3Þ where RD,t is the return on a domestic benchmark portfolio. Our hypothesis is that the allocation of domestic stocks between domestic and foreign investors is determined by their valuation difference. More precisely, a stock is held by whoever has a higher valuation for that stock. Since the estimated scaled alpha represents such a valuation averaged over our estimation period, we predict the following:H1: The scaled alpha difference (scaled foreign alpha – scaled domestic alpha) is positively related to foreign ownership. When testing H1, we control for the valuation level by including the domestic or foreign alpha along with the alpha difference. Otherwise, we cannot guarantee that the result is indeed driven by the valuation differential. Another way of ensuring such an attribution is to use a difference measure that is unrelated to the valuation level. To this end, we cross-sectionally orthogonalize one scaled alpha to the other. This procedure purges the common cross-sectional variation in the alpha level from the orthogonalized alpha, and thus allows us to examine the role of the alpha difference independent of the effect of the alpha level. Specifically, we have the following prediction: 2889 H.C. Kang et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2010) 2886–2896 H2: The orthogonalized foreign alpha—i.e., the foreign alpha unrelated to the common alpha level—is positively related to foreign ownership. The orthogonalized domestic alpha—i.e., the domestic alpha unrelated to the common alpha level—is negatively related to foreign ownership. Table 1 A rundown of sample. This table reports the run-down of our sample. Our sample includes all non-financial Korean companies listed on the Korean Stock Exchange (KSE) whose foreign ownership, accounting information, and daily stock return data are available. Foreign ownership information is compiled by the KSE, while accounting data are obtained from TS2000, a database maintained by the Korea Listed Companies Association. Stock return data are from the Korea Securities Research Institute. 3. Sample and data Our sample includes all non-financial Korean companies listed on the Korean Stock Exchange (KSE) for which foreign ownership, accounting information, and daily stock return data are available. Foreign ownership information is compiled by the KSE, while the accounting data are from TS200, a database maintained by the Korea Listed Companies Association. Stock return data are from the Korea Securities Research Institute. We focus on a period during which the country’s stock market is fully open to foreign investors—namely, the period from 2000 to 2004. Together with the preceding data requirements, this sample period provides us with 2798 firm-year observations.10 Table 1 shows that our sample is fairly complete, including more than 70% of the KSE-listed companies. In measuring foreign ownership, we use the public float rather than the total number of shares outstanding. This is motivated by the fact that shares held by insiders are not available to foreign investors, nor to other outside investors (e.g., Dahlquist et al., 2003; Kho et al., 2006). Given that corporate ownership is concentrated in most countries except for the US and the UK (La Porta et al., 1999), it is crucial to control for insider ownership in analyzing the stock selection by foreign investors. Otherwise, foreign ownership would be biased downwards with its cross-section potentially distorted as well. As the KSE provides only the outstanding sharebased foreign ownership, the float-based foreign ownership is calculated by dividing the original foreign ownership by (1 – insider ownership), wherein the insider ownership is the number of shares held by controlling shareholders, related parties, and treasury stock, divided by the total number of shares outstanding. The first line of Table 2 reports the summary statistics of foreign ownership. On average, approximately 11% of the public float is held by foreign investors in the Korean stock market. However, the distribution seems to be positively skewed, as the median is at a much lower level of 1%. Not surprisingly, some stocks have no foreign investors while other stocks are held virtually entirely by them. These two patterns together—i.e., foreigners’ overweighting of some domestic stocks and their simultaneous underweighting of other domestic stocks—are often called the foreign bias, as opposed to the domestic bias that refers to the preference of domestic investors for domestic stocks (Chan et al., 2005). 4. Empirical results 4.1. Scaled alphas The variable of our interest is the scaled alpha. The scaled foreign alpha is obtained by estimating Eq. (2) in which the MSCI World Index is the benchmark portfolio.11 A minimum of 200 US dollar-denominated daily returns in excess of the Eurodollar deposit rate are used for this estimation. We conduct this estimation every year because foreign ownership data are updated annually. The 10 These are the observations after we eliminate the top and bottom 0.5 percentiles of the initial sample by the book-to-market ratios (28 observations). Without this truncation, the ratio ranges between 347.95 and +97.71, thereby posing a serious outlier problem. An earlier version of the paper contained some of those extreme values and found virtually the same results as those reported in this paper. 11 Alternatively, we used the MSCI All Country Index and found results similar to those reported in this paper. The results are available from the authors upon request. Year-by-year Total 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 Companies listed on the Korean Stock Exchange (Financial companies) (Non-financial companies with insufficient data) 704 689 683 684 683 3443 (76) (101) (65) (82) (63) (55) (61) (34) (56) (52) (321) (324) Final sample 527 542 565 589 575 2798 Fraction of the total (%) 74.9 78.7 82.7 86.1 84.2 81.3 scaled domestic alpha is estimated every year via Eq. (3) using a minimum of 200 daily returns and with the Korea Composite Stock Price Index (KOSPI) as the benchmark. For the latter estimation, we use the Korean Won-denominated return in excess of the domestic risk-free rate (daily yield on the Monetary Stabilization Bond). Both scaled alphas are estimated over a certain calendar year, and then are associated with float-based foreign ownership at the end of that year. Note that the use of the dollar return for Eq. (2) amounts to assuming that foreign investors are not perfectly hedged against domestic currency movements. This may also imply that the uncertainty associated with domestic currency (e.g., currency risk premium) is one reason for foreigners to invest in the domestic market. In a later robustness check, we replace the dollar-denominated return with the domestic-currency return, an approach that assumes that foreign investors are perfectly hedged against domestic currency movements and thus they take a given domestic-currency return as is.12 We estimate Eqs. (2) and (3) using daily data. As detailed in Section 2.2.2, this means that the resultant alpha estimate is the average daily return on the stock unrelated to the benchmark, or in the context of our analysis, the average daily valuation in response to which investors change their position in the stock. This approach is justified by the finding in the literature that foreigners’ returnchasing behavior is evident at daily frequency. Interestingly, this behavior is known to be short-lived. For example, Griffin et al. (2004) show that the domestic return-foreign equity capital flow relationship disappears at weekly frequency. Other studies, such as Froot and Ramadorai (2008), confirm the absence of the return-flow relationship at weekly frequency in the Korean market. The later robustness check thus examines weekly data as well. Other things being equal, the weekly data are expected to produce a weaker or no result. Table 2 provides the summary statistics of the estimated raw (i.e., unscaled) alphas. As they are estimated with daily stock returns, the magnitude is quite small: the domestic and foreign scaled alphas are, respectively, 0.04% and 0.05%. The summary statistics of the residual volatilities, the scaled alphas, and the scaled alpha difference are also provided in the table. Finally, we report the orthogonalized alphas, which are the residuals from the yearby-year cross-sectional regression of one scaled alpha on the other. 12 In a world in which the uncovered interest rate parity holds, the currency of denomination would not be much of an issue. It is because (Ri,D rf,D) (Ri,F rf,F) (Ri,D rf,D) (Ri,D fx rf,F) = fx (rf,D rf,F) = 0, where Ri,D is a stock’s domestic-currency return, Ri,F is its foreign-currency return, rf,D is the domestic risk-free rate, rf,F is the foreign risk-free rate, and fx is the change in the domestic-currency price for one unit of foreign currency. 2890 H.C. Kang et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2010) 2886–2896 Table 2 Summary statistics of float-based foreign ownership and explanatory variables. This table reports the summary statistics of float-based foreign ownership and its explanatory variables. Alphas (a), betas (b), and residual volatilities (r) are estimated through Eqs. (2) and (3). EBITDA represents the earnings before interests, taxes, depreciations, and amortizations. BM is the book-to-market ratio and DivYld stands for dividend yield. Turnover is the total number of shares traded during the year, divided by the number of shares outstanding. Liquidity is the ratio of current assets to current liabilities. Export is the fraction of export in total sales. Variable n Standard deviation Min Foreign ownership aD aF r(eD) r(eF) aD/r(eD) aF/r(eF) 2798 2798 2798 2798 2798 2798 2798 Mean 0.112 0.00039 0.00054 0.037 0.039 0.009 0.016 Median 0.009 0.00028 0.00052 0.034 0.037 0.008 0.016 0.192 0.00216 0.00232 0.015 0.015 0.053 0.053 0.000 0.01453 0.01684 0.009 0.010 0.193 0.189 Max 0.992 0.01107 0.01164 0.099 0.100 0.186 0.209 aF/r(eF) aD/r(eD) aD/r(eD)ORTH aF/r(eF)ORTH 2798 2798 2798 0.008 0.000 0.000 0.013 0.000 0.000 0.024 0.011 0.011 0.106 0.075 0.077 0.105 0.072 0.058 ln(mktcap) EBITDA BM Leverage DivYld Turnover Liquidity Export 2798 2798 2798 2798 2798 2798 2798 2798 17.644 0.051 0.845 0.501 0.030 5.458 1.296 0.285 17.331 0.055 0.850 0.496 0.023 2.634 0.947 0.179 1.615 0.095 0.839 0.205 0.038 8.306 1.387 0.305 12.196 2.084 7.676 0.031 0.000 0.001 0.036 0.000 24.951 0.458 7.963 0.999 0.668 87.926 31.725 1.000 Table 3 Correlation coefficients between float-based foreign ownership and explanatory variables. This table reports the correlation coefficients between float-based foreign ownership (FO) and its explanatory variables. The variables are defined in Table 2. Numbers in parentheses are p-values. (1) aD/r(eD) (2) aF/r(eF) F F D D (3) a /r(e ) a /r(e ) (4) aD/r(eD)ORTH (5) aF/r(eF)ORTH (6) ln(mktcap) (7) EBITDA (8) BM (9) Leverage (10) DivYld (11) Turnover (12) Liquidity (13) Export FO (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) 0.178 (0.000) 0.202 (0.000) 0.053 (0.006) 0.029 (0.120) 0.057 (0.003) 0.669 (0.000) 0.278 (0.000) 0.118 (0.000) 0.168 (0.000) 0.010 (0.599) 0.217 (0.000) 0.040 (0.033) 0.057 (0.003) 0.895 (0.000) 0.228 (0.000) 0.217 (0.000) 0.000 (1.000) 0.210 (0.000) 0.263 (0.000) 0.069 (0.000) 0.022 (0.250) 0.080 (0.000) 0.020 (0.297) 0.010 (0.604) 0.074 (0.000) 0.230 (0.000) 0.000 (1.000) 0.205 (0.000) 0.232 (0.000) 0.249 (0.000) 0.072 (0.000) 0.084 (0.000) 0.063 (0.001) 0.056 (0.003) 0.016 (0.397) 0.081 (0.000) 0.475 (0.000) 0.448 (0.000) 0.048 (0.011) 0.032 (0.090) 0.005 (0.783) 0.135 (0.000) 0.036 (0.058) 0.080 (0.000) 0.056 (0.003) 0.016 (0.400) 0.970 (0.000) 0.015 (0.434) 0.054 (0.004) 0.015 (0.441) 0.099 (0.000) 0.099 (0.000) 0.167 (0.000) 0.038 (0.044) 0.000 (0.998) 0.035 (0.067) 0.105 (0.000) 0.002 (0.900) 0.105 (0.000) 0.114 (0.000) 0.165 (0.000) 0.043 (0.025) 0.028 (0.136) 0.316 (0.000) 0.175 (0.000) 0.159 (0.000) 0.004 (0.829) 0.210 (0.000) 0.023 (0.216) 0.081 (0.000) 0.061 (0.001) 0.183 (0.000) 0.223 (0.000) 0.312 (0.000) 0.086 (0.000) 0.124 (0.000) 0.003 (0.859) 0.025 (0.184) 0.021 (0.268) 0.065 (0.001) 0.008 (0.682) 0.229 (0.000) 0.193 (0.000) 0.401 (0.000) 0.029 (0.131) 0.222 (0.000) 0.003 (0.861) 0.088 (0.000) 0.044 (0.019) 0.038 (0.047) 0.059 (0.002) Table 3 shows the correlation coefficient between these variables. The scaled domestic and foreign alphas are highly correlated (q = 0.895), thereby warranting the use of the orthogonalized alphas when both are to be in one regression. As mentioned in Section 2.2.3, the orthogonalized alpha is effectively the alpha difference: the alpha difference (foreign minus domestic) has a correlation coefficient with the orthogonalized foreign alpha of 0.449 (p-value less than 0.0001), while its correlation coefficient with the orthogonalized domestic alpha is 0.475 (p-value less than 0.0001). The orthogonalized alpha is instructive, since it contains the information of the original alpha while being unrelated to the other alpha. For example, the orthogonalized foreign alpha is reliably correlated with the original foreign alpha (q = 0.205 with a p-value less than 0.0001) but it is unrelated to the scaled domestic alpha by construction. 4.2. Control variables A variety of firm characteristics have been identified to affect foreign ownership (e.g., Kang and Stulz, 1997; Dahlquist and Robertsson, 2001). We thus employ a large set of control variables to correctly attribute our results to the scaled alpha difference. (Note that corporate insider ownership is already controlled by the use of the float-based foreign ownership.) Specifically, we use firm size, 2891 H.C. Kang et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2010) 2886–2896 profitability, book-to-market ratio, leverage, dividend yield, stock turnover, asset liquidity, and export-to-sales ratio. Like the scaled alphas, all the control variables are measured at the end of a given year and then are associated with foreign ownership at the end of that year. The summary statistics of those control variables are reported in Table 2 and their correlation coefficients appear in Table 3. Table 3 is particularly useful in confirming their known relationship with foreign ownership univariately. Market value of equity is the most widely accepted firm characteristic that explains foreign ownership, and its positive relationship with foreign ownership is confirmed in our data. Corporate profitability, as measured by the earnings before interests, taxes, depreciations, and amortizations (EBITDA), also has a positive relation to foreign ownership. Book-to-market ratio (BM) is generally known to be negatively related to foreign ownership, since foreigners tend to hold growth stocks; this relationship is confirmed in our data. Leverage is the ratio of total debt to total assets, and we confirm its negative relationship with foreign ownership. Dividend yield (DivYld) can speak to the governance-related preference of foreign investors, because well-governed companies tend to pay their shareholders more (La Porta et al., 2000) and foreigners prefer companies with shareholder-friendly governance (Lins and Warnock, 2006). Viewed this way, dividend yield will be positively related to foreign ownership. However, this prediction may be too naïve, since dividend can serve as a governance proxy only after the growth opportunities are taken into account (e.g., Chae et al., 2009). In our data, dividend yield alone is not significantly related to foreign ownership. To control for investor horizon, turnover (Turnover) is also examined, which is the total number of shares traded during the year divided by the number of shares outstanding; we find that stocks held more by foreigners are traded less frequently. Finally, we use the ratio of current assets to current liabilities (Liquidity) and the fraction of export in total sales (Export), both of which are positively related to foreign ownership. In brief, virtually all of our control variables are highly correlated with foreign ownership, thereby justifying themselves as valid controls. Although dividend yield is not significantly correlated with foreign ownership in this univariate setting, it is correlated with other variables and thus needs to be controlled. While our control variables are also highly correlated with each other, that does not pose a problem so long as they are not highly correlated with the variables of our interest, namely, the alpha difference and the orthogonalized alphas. As Table 3 shows in columns (3)– (5), their correlations are oftentimes statistically significant but the magnitude is never greater than 0.167 in absolute terms. 4.3. Main results – tests of H1 and H2 We now test H1 by estimating the following equation: FOi;t ¼ a0 þ b1 Alphai;t þ b2 AlphaDiffi;t þ K X ck X k;i;t þ fi þ yt k¼1 þ ei;t ; ð4Þ where FOi,t is the float-based foreign ownership of stock i at the end of year t, Alphai,t is the scaled alpha (either domestic or foreign) for stock i estimated during year t, AlphaDiffi,t is the scaled alpha difference (foreign – domestic), and Xk,i,t represents one of the control variables for stock i that are measured at the end of year t. Finally, fi and yt are, respectively, firm and year fixed-effects.13 With firm fixed-effects, our results can reveal the within-firm variation in for13 Our choice of the fixed-effect model over the random-effect model is based on the Hausman (1978) test. eign ownership. Any pattern that is common to all firms and is attributable to a certain year will then be taken out by year fixedeffects. Throughout the paper, we use the Rogers standard errors to control for both heteroscedasticity and the correlation among same-firm observations (see Petersen 2009). We do not use the Tobit regression here, since zero foreign ownership does not necessarily indicate that foreigners wanted to sell the stock short but were unable to do so (see, e.g., Maddala, 1992, p. 342).14 Our view is that zero foreign ownership is simply an indication that foreigners are not interested in the stock. On the upper side, the maximum foreign ownership in our sample is less than one; thus, it is not truncated at all. In a later analysis, however, we employ the Tobit regression to ensure the robustness of our results. Models (1) and (2) in Table 4 show that the alpha difference enters the regression with a significant and positive coefficient, after controlling for the level of the domestic or foreign alpha and other firm characteristics. This finding indicates that stocks that are more valuable to foreigners than to locals are indeed held by foreigners, thereby confirming H1. The positive coefficient on the domestic or foreign alpha itself may reflect the return-chasing behavior of foreigners beyond what the alpha difference captures. However, another possibility is that foreigners prefer stocks with certain characteristics that happen to be correlated with alpha. A third possibility is that foreigners have private information so they have a greater position in stocks that will subsequently rise in value (regardless of the benchmark). Since we control for the alpha level to obtain the alpha difference result, these versions of endogeneity are not much of a concern. In Section 4.4, however, we address endogeneity more carefully. We test H2 by estimating the following equation: DðFÞ FðDÞ FOi;t ¼ a0 þ b1 Alphai;t þ b2 OrthAlphai;t þ K X ck X k;i;t þ fi þ yt þ ei;t ; k¼1 ð5Þ F(D) where OrthAlphai,t is the scaled foreign (domestic) alpha that is orthogonalized each year to the scaled domestic (foreign) alpha. Note that when the scale domestic alpha, AlphaD, is in the regression, it is accompanied by the orthogonalized foreign alpha, OrthAlphaF; and vice versa. As the latter is unrelated to the former by construction, we can obtain a clearer picture of the role of the valuation difference. Consistent with the hypothesis, models (3) and (4) in Table 4 show that the orthogonalized foreign alpha is positively related to foreign ownership, whereas the orthogonalized domestic alpha is negatively related to foreign ownership. This result evidently supports our idea that the valuation difference between locals and foreigners is an important determinant of the allocation of domestic stocks between the two investor groups. Again, we stress that this orthogonalized alpha result is particularly convincing, since the differing effects of the domestic and foreign valuations on foreign ownership are revealed quite clearly. Thus, we employ these two models in the following robustness checks. 4.4. Robustness checks In this section, we ensure the robustness of our alpha difference results by applying a number of different specifications to our analysis. 14 If zero foreign ownership were a result of a short sale constraint, then the stocks not held by foreigners should have a lower return subsequently (e.g., Chen et al. 2002). However, Jung et al. (2009) report exactly the opposite result in the Korean stock market. 2892 H.C. Kang et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2010) 2886–2896 Table 4 Panel regressions of float-based foreign ownership. This table reports the panel regressions of float-based foreign ownership on firm characteristics including the scaled alphas in several different forms. Specifically, we estimate Eq. (4) (for models (1) and (2) below) and (5) (for models (3) and (4) below). The variables used for the regressions are defined in Table 2. Numbers in brackets are the t-statistics that take into account both heteroscedasticity and correlation among same-firm observations. Dependent variable: float-based foreign ownership (1) aF/r(eF) aD/r(eD) aF/r(eF) aD/r(eD) aF/r(eF)ORTH aD/r(eD)ORTH Control variables ln(mktcap) EBITDA BM Leverage DivYld Turnover Liquidity Export (2) Coeff. t-Stat. 0.139 [2.86] 0.286 [2.15] 0.043 0.003 0.001 0.015 0.032 0.001 0.003 0.036 Coeff. 0.139 0.425 [6.66] [0.12] [0.24] [0.47] [0.46] [3.27] [1.41] [1.92] 0.043 0.003 0.001 0.015 0.032 0.001 0.003 0.036 (3) t-Stat. (4) Coeff. t-Stat. 0.128 [2.65] [2.86] [2.95] [6.66] [0.12] [0.24] [0.47] [0.46] [3.27] [1.41] [1.92] An intercept, year fixed-effects, and firm fixed-effects are in the regressions but not reported R2 (%) 44.5 44.5 # of obs. 2798 2798 0.389 [2.77] 0.043 0.004 0.000 0.016 0.032 0.001 0.003 0.035 [6.66] [0.15] [0.21] [0.48] [0.46] [3.14] [1.39] [1.90] 44.5 2798 Coeff. t-Stat. 0.103 [2.28] 0.516 [3.52] 0.043 0.004 0.000 0.015 0.032 0.001 0.003 0.035 [6.64] [0.13] [0.21] [0.45] [0.46] [3.17] [1.38] [1.90] 44.6 2798 Table 5 Panel regressions of float-based foreign ownership – Robustness checks. This table reports the panel regressions of float-based foreign ownership on firm characteristics including the scaled alphas in several different forms. The variables used for the regressions are defined in Table 2. Numbers in brackets are the t-statistics that take into account both heteroscedasticity and correlation among same-firm observations. Dependent variable: float-based foreign ownership Alpha and residual volatility separated F a r(eF) aD r(eD) aF/r(eF) aD/r(eD) aF/r(eF)ORTH aD/r(eD)ORTH Coeff. t-Stat. 1.529 0.063 [1.20] [0.15] Beta difference also controlled for Coeff. t-Stat. 1.614 0.058 [1.18] [0.13] bF bD Control variables ln(mktcap) EBITDA BM Leverage DivYld Turnover Liquidity Export 0.044 0.007 0.000 0.021 0.029 0.001 0.003 0.036 [6.82] [0.26] [0.22] [0.64] [0.40] [2.22] [1.52] [1.97] 0.044 0.007 0.000 0.020 0.029 0.001 0.003 0.036 [6.74] [0.23] [0.23] [0.64] [0.39] [2.16] [1.52] [1.98] An intercept, year fixed-effects, and firm fixed-effects are in the regressions but not reported R2 (%) 44.4 44.4 # of obs. 2798 2798 4.4.1. Omitted variables 4.4.1.1. Residual volatility. Thus far, we have scaled the raw alpha by the residual volatility. Some may argue that such scaling induces a spurious effect, since the residual volatility itself is a proxy for some important firm characteristics such as information asymmetry. To address this criticism, we separate the residual volatility from the alpha, and include both in the same regression. As shown in the left-half panel of Table 5, the residual volatility alone is never significantly related to foreign ownership. This result means that the residual volatility helps explain foreign ownership only in conjunction with the alpha estimate. In other words, the residual volatility is related to foreign ownership only as a precision measure for the alpha. The result thus implies that persistently positive Coeff. t-Stat. 0.130 [2.67] Coeff. t-Stat. 0.104 0.535 [2.29] [3.61] 0.408 0.007 [2.89] [1.04] 0.007 [1.02] 0.043 0.004 0.001 0.015 0.032 0.001 0.003 0.035 [6.66] [0.15] [0.27] [0.47] [0.45] [3.02] [1.36] [1.92] 0.043 0.003 0.001 0.015 0.031 0.001 0.003 0.035 [6.64] [0.13] [0.28] [0.45] [0.45] [3.05] [1.35] [1.92] 44.6 2798 44.6 2798 or negative valuations induce foreigners to change their position in the stock more than do a few large valuation shocks. 4.4.1.2. Beta difference. Another possible criticism is that our results are driven by beta, not alpha. Note that the beta in Eq. (2) and (3) represents the covariance risk with the benchmark portfolio. Consequently, the beta difference can represent the international diversification benefits (see, e.g., Alexander et al., 1987). To the extent that foreigners, unlike locals, seek low foreign beta stocks to reduce their portfolio risks, the beta difference (foreign – domestic) will be negatively related to foreign ownership. Due to the inherent negative relationship between the alpha and beta estimates, the al- 2893 H.C. Kang et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2010) 2886–2896 pha difference may be spuriously related to foreign ownership with a positive coefficient. The right-half panel of Table 5 disproves this story. The beta difference itself is only insignificantly related to foreign ownership and, further, the sign of the coefficient is the opposite of what this story predicts. The alpha difference results, on the other hand, remain virtually unchanged: the orthogonalized foreign alpha is positively related to foreign ownership, whereas the orthogonalized domestic alpha is negatively related to foreign ownership. 4.4.2. Sub-sample analysis In this section, we split the sample to further address endogeneity. A sub-sample analysis is a straightforward way of detecting any discontinuities in the explanatory power of a variable in relation to others. Hence, this analysis will help us understand the sources of the explanatory power of alpha difference. To create sub-samples, we use the median value of a given sorting variable identified each year. 4.4.2.1. By market capitalization. One possible challenge to our alpha difference results is that the buying pressure of foreigners boosts the domestic market as a whole, as well as the individual stocks, because the stocks preferred by foreigners are typically large and thus account for a large proportion of the domestic port- folio. If this were the case, then the domestic alpha estimate would be lower than the foreign alpha estimate, since the global benchmark is likely to remain unaffected by the buying pressure on domestic stocks. As a result, a spurious positive relationship can arise between alpha difference and foreign ownership. Table 6 (Panel A) vitiates this possibility. While this endogeneity story predicts a stronger alpha difference result in the larger market capitalization sub-sample, the data point to the opposite. More precisely, the orthogonalized alphas are reliably related to foreign ownership only in the smaller market capitalization subsample. It is also worth noting that firm size, ln(mktcap), has remarkably different explanatory power between the two subsamples: its coefficient in the smaller market capitalization subsample is less than one fifth of the coefficient in the other sub-sample. Together with the weaker significance of the other control variables, this explains the low R2 in the smaller market capitalization sub-sample. The stronger orthogonalized alpha results in this sub-sample can thus be interpreted as the valuation difference being useful in explaining the allocation of domestic stocks when other explanations are not. 4.4.2.2. By absolute value of scaled alpha. Perhaps a better way of splitting the sample to gauge the effects of foreigners’ buying/selling pressure on our results is to directly use the magnitude of the Table 6 Panel regressions of float-based foreign ownership – Sub-sample analysis. This table reports the panel regressions of float-based foreign ownership on firm characteristics including the scaled alphas in several different forms. Specifically, we estimate Eq. (5) for each sub-sample created by the median value of the sorting variable identified each year. The variables used for the regressions are defined in Table 2. Numbers in brackets are the t-statistics that take into account both heteroscedasticity and correlation among samefirm observations. Dependent variable: float-based foreign ownership Below median ln(mktcap) each year Panel A aF/r(eF) aD/r(eD) aF/r(eF)ORTH aD/r(eD)ORTH Control variables ln(mktcap) EBITDA BM Leverage DivYld Turnover Liquidity Export Coeff. t-Stat. 0.016 [0.41] 0.281 [2.54] 0.014 0.019 0.002 0.002 0.024 0.000 0.001 0.003 [3.33] [1.52] [1.27] [0.15] [0.99] [0.68] [0.70] [0.45] Above median ln(mktcap) each year Coeff. t-Stat. 0.026 0.243 [0.67] [2.48] 0.014 0.019 0.002 0.002 0.024 0.000 0.001 0.003 [3.33] [1.51] [1.27] [0.14] [0.99] [0.74] [0.72] [0.42] An intercept, year fixed-effects, and firm fixed-effects are in the regressions but not reported R2 5.3% 5.3% # of obs. 1,401 1,401 Below median |aF/r(eF)| each year Coeff. t-Stat. 0.047 [0.46] 0.333 [1.49] 0.084 0.079 0.002 0.149 0.199 0.002 0.002 0.057 [5.36] [0.70] [0.33] [1.56] [1.06] [2.10] [0.58] [1.36] 42.0% 1,397 Coeff. t-Stat. 0.038 0.376 [0.41] [1.41] 0.083 0.076 0.002 0.150 0.195 0.002 0.002 0.058 [5.32] [0.67] [0.33] [1.57] [1.04] [2.15] [0.58] [1.36] 42.1% 1,397 Above median |aF/r(eF)| each year Panel B aF/r(eF) aD/r(eD) aF/r(eF)ORTH aD/r(eD)ORTH Control variables ln(mktcap) EBITDA BM Leverage DivYld Turnover Liquidity Export 0.061 [0.49] 0.224 0.080 0.887 0.845 [3.93] 0.032 0.052 0.004 0.013 0.053 0.000 0.002 0.030 [3.73] [1.21] [1.44] [0.36] [0.76] [0.66] [0.84] [1.65] 0.032 0.051 0.003 0.012 0.054 0.000 0.002 0.029 [3.06] [0.72] [3.31] [3.75] [1.18] [1.43] [0.34] [0.76] [0.69] [0.82] [1.64] An intercept, year fixed-effects, and firm fixed-effects are in the regressions but not reported R2 (%) 43.1 43.1 # of obs. 1401 1401 0.150 [0.58] 0.040 0.020 0.000 0.003 0.227 0.001 0.006 0.058 [4.45] [0.44] [0.18] [0.06] [1.77] [3.59] [1.22] [1.58] 42.8 1397 0.211 0.345 [2.92] [1.32] 0.040 0.019 0.000 0.001 0.227 0.001 0.006 0.059 [4.36] [0.42] [0.19] [0.03] [1.78] [3.61] [1.20] [1.59] 42.7 1397 2894 H.C. Kang et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2010) 2886–2896 Table 7 Panel regressions of float-based foreign ownership – Alternative alpha estimates. This table reports the panel regressions of float-based foreign ownership on firm characteristics including the scaled alphas in several different forms. Specifically, we estimate Eq. (5). The variables used for the regressions are defined in Table 2. Numbers in brackets are the tstatistics that take into account both heteroscedasticity and correlation among same-firm observations. Dependent variable: float-based foreign ownership aF/r(eF) aD/r(eD) aF/r(eF)ORTH aD/r(eD)ORTH Cumulative benchmark-adjusted return in place of alpha Foreign alpha estimated with local-currency return on domestic stocks Foreign and domestic alphas estimated at weekly frequency Coeff. t-Stat. Coeff. t-Stat. Coeff. t-Stat. 0.0006 [3.06] 0.116 [2.42] 0.043 [2.18] Coeff. 0.0004 0.002 0.002 [3.77] Control variables ln(mktcap) 0.042 EBITDA 0.001 BM 0.001 Leverage 0.015 DivYld 0.032 Turnover 0.001 Liquidity 0.003 Export 0.035 [6.62] [0.02] [0.28] [0.46] [0.47] [3.00] [1.44] [1.86] 0.042 0.001 0.001 0.015 0.032 0.001 0.003 0.035 t-Stat. Coeff. [2.42] [3.95] [6.61] [0.04] [0.26] [0.45] [0.46] [3.13] [1.45] [1.88] 0.103 0.305 0.233 [1.67] 0.043 0.003 0.000 0.016 0.032 0.001 0.003 0.036 [6.58] [0.11] [0.20] [0.50] [0.46] [3.46] [1.46] [1.93] 0.042 0.003 0.000 0.016 0.032 0.001 0.003 0.036 An intercept, year fixed-effects, and firm fixed-effects are in the regressions but not reported R2 (%) 44.6 44.6 44.4 # of obs. 2798 2798 2798 alpha. If the alpha is caused by foreigners’ purchases and sales, then the alpha difference result should be stronger when such demand/supply shocks are more evident, i.e., when the absolute value of the alpha is greater. As shown in Table 6 (Panel B), the alpha difference turns out to be significant when the scaled foreign alpha is small in absolute terms. In contrast, the alpha itself is significant only in the other sub-sample. We therefore reject this alternative explanation for our results. Recall that, in our hypothesis, the foreign alpha of a domestic stock represents the average signal to which foreigners respond. Consequently, these results are interpreted as follows. When foreigners receive a strong signal on a stock in either direction (i.e., when the absolute value of the scaled foreign alpha is large), they obtain what they want and domestic investors yield (i.e., foreign ownership is positively related to the scaled foreign alpha itself).15 On the other hand, when foreign investors do not have such a strong signal (i.e., when the absolute value of the scaled foreign alpha is small), the scope for interaction grows and the valuation difference becomes relevant (i.e., foreign ownership is positively related to the scaled alpha difference).16 4.4.3. Alternative specifications In this section, we modify the alpha or regression specifications to further investigate our hypothesis. 4.4.3.1. Cumulative daily valuation. We have thus far used the scaled alpha difference obtained from Eqs. (2) and (3). As explained in Sections 2.2.2 and 2.2.3, those equations are to produce a summary of daily valuations over a certain year, so that it can be related to the annually reported ownership information. An alternative way of obtaining a valuation measure that corresponds to the annually updated stock ownership information is to cumulate daily valuations during the year. Specifically, we cumulate 15 Of course, domestic investors need a reward to make this concession. As shown by Jung et al. (2009), the existence of a higher average return accruing to the stocks held less by foreign investors is consistent with this interpretation. That is, this premium can be considered to be a compensation that domestic investors receive in return for giving up stocks that foreigners demand and instead holding other stocks to clear the market. 16 Consistent with this interpretation, when the sub-samples are created by the absolute value of the scaled domestic alpha, neither the alpha itself nor the alpha difference are significant in the regressions. 44.5 2798 t-Stat. [2.27] [2.06] [6.56] [0.10] [0.21] [0.48] [0.46] [3.48] [1.46] [1.94] 0.024 [0.49] 0.043 0.004 0.001 0.018 0.035 0.001 0.003 0.037 [6.67] [0.17] [0.28] [0.56] [0.50] [3.56] [1.46] [1.98] 44.4 2798 Coeff. t-Stat. 0.042 0.008 [2.26] [0.16] 0.043 0.004 0.001 0.018 0.036 0.001 0.003 0.037 [6.63] [0.15] [0.27] [0.56] [0.50] [3.59] [1.46] [2.00] 44.4 2798 the daily benchmark-adjusted returns (i.e., return on a stock minus return on its benchmark) during a given year. To account for precision and persistency, we then scale the cumulated daily valuations by their standard deviation during that year. Finally, the valuation difference is obtained by deduction the scaled cumulative domestic benchmark-adjusted return from the scaled cumulative foreign benchmark-adjusted return. The first two models in Table 7 show that our results are robust to this alternative way of obtaining a valuation measure. 4.4.3.2. Currency of denomination. Recall that the foreign alpha is estimated using the US dollar-denominated return on domestic stocks. This reflects the perspective of an investor who is not hedged against domestic currency movements, or that of an investor who is motivated to invest in the domestic market by the uncertainty associated with the domestic currency. Given that the domestic alpha is estimated using the domestic currencydenominated return, the alpha difference may contain the differing perspectives on the domestic currency. To gauge the importance of this component in the alpha difference, we use an alternative foreign alpha, which is estimated using the domestic currencydenominated return. The middle two models in Table 7 show that the results are somewhat sensitive to using this alternative foreign alpha. Specifically, the orthogonalized domestic alpha becomes marginally insignificant with a t-statistic of 1.67, while the sign remains correct. The orthogonalized foreign alpha continues to enter the regression significantly with a positive coefficient. Note that the different benchmarks and the different perceptions on the domestic currency are not mutually exclusive. For example, it is plausible that domestic investors use a domestic benchmark because their consumption basket is denominated in the domestic currency. Thus, the somewhat weaker results with this alternative specification should not be taken as evidence against our hypothesis. 4.4.3.3. Estimation using weekly data. As mentioned earlier in Section 4.1, the positive domestic return-foreign equity capital flow relationship disappears at weekly frequency in some markets including Korea (e.g., Griffin et al., 2004; Froot and Ramadorai, 2008). Given that we use the regression alpha as a proxy for the average signal to which investors respond, the lack of such responses at weekly frequency suggests that the alpha difference 2895 H.C. Kang et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2010) 2886–2896 Table 8 Regressions of float-based foreign ownership – Alternative regression specifications. This table reports the Tobit or panel regression of float-based foreign ownership on firm characteristics including the scaled alphas in several different forms. Specifically, we estimate Eq. (5). The variables used for the regressions are defined in Table 2. Numbers in brackets are the t-statistics that take into account both heteroscedasticity and correlation among same-firm observations (only for panel regressions). Dependent variable: float-based foreign ownership Tobit regressions aF/r(eF) aD/r(eD) aF/r(eF)ORTH aD/r(eD)ORTH Control variables ln(mktcap) EBITDA BM Leverage DivYld Turnover Liquidity Export Coeff. t-Stat. 0.092 [2.34] Observations with zero foreign ownership are excluded Coeff. 0.077 0.385 0.312 [2.02] 0.054 0.008 0.001 0.011 0.061 0.001 0.003 0.037 [14.14] [0.29] [0.25] [0.50] [0.89] [2.04] [1.94] [2.20] 0.054 0.009 0.001 0.010 0.061 0.001 0.003 0.037 t-Stat. Coeff. t-Stat. 0.126 [2.11] [2.08] [2.37] [14.07] [0.33] [0.25] [0.46] [0.89] [2.10] [1.94] [2.22] An intercept, year fixed-effects, and firm fixed-effects are in the regressions but not reported ln(likelihood) of R2 (%) 2673.42 2673.42 # of obs. 2798 2798 estimated using weekly data is not useful in explaining foreign ownership. Another relevant observation is that the domestic and global benchmarks become remarkably similar in weekly data. Specifically, while their correlation coefficient at daily frequency is 0.281, it increases to 0.525 at weekly frequency. Thus, the scope for valuation difference due to benchmark difference shrinks at this longer interval. Consistent with these two observations, the final two models of Table 7 show that the relationship between the alpha difference (i.e., orthogonalized alphas) and foreign ownership disappears when the alphas are estimated using weekly data.17 4.4.3.4. Alternative regression specifications. As mentioned in Section 4.3, zero foreign ownership is unlikely to be a sign of data truncation; hence, the Tobit regression is not warranted. However, we repeat the analysis using this alternative specification to ensure the robustness of our results. The results in the left-half panel of Table 8 show that our results are robust to this alternative regression specification. Another possible alternative regarding data truncation is to use only the observations with non-zero foreign ownership. That way, we can ensure that we are not simply picking up the variation between the zero foreign ownership case and the rest. The results in the right-half panel of Table 8 show that the valuation difference is still useful in explaining the dispersion among non-zero foreign ownership cases. 5. Conclusions In this paper, we propose an investor heterogeneity approach to the distinct domestic stock holdings between domestic and foreign investors. Specifically, we hypothesize that domestic and foreign investors evaluate domestic stocks via different models and the resultant difference in valuation leads them to hold different sets of domestic stocks. To make this hypothesis empirically testable, we specify the model difference in terms of benchmark: that is, domestic investors utilize a domestic benchmark, whereas foreign investors employ a global benchmark. This particular specification 0.334 [2.06] 0.051 0.008 0.001 0.008 0.071 0.001 0.003 0.035 [6.42] [0.26] [0.49] [0.18] [0.76] [2.43] [1.12] [1.57] 44.2 2384 Coeff. t-Stat. 0.105 0.452 [1.92] [2.57] 0.051 0.009 0.001 0.008 0.071 0.001 0.003 0.035 [6.41] [0.29] [0.49] [0.20] [0.76] [2.47] [1.11] [1.57] 44.2 2384 is motivated by two of the most well-established empirical regularities in international finance: namely, that foreigners are a return-chaser across countries and that domestic investors— especially those in emerging markets—prefer home-country stocks to overseas ones. Using data from Korea, we find strong empirical support for our hypothesis. More precisely, we find that foreigners hold stocks for which their valuation is higher than that of domestic investors. As we control for a variety of firm characteristics known to be correlated with foreign ownership, our results indicate that the valuation difference between domestic and foreign investors can help explain the allocation of domestic stocks between the two groups over and above the existing explanations. Our results thus suggest that risk-sharing within a market can be better understood when heterogeneity among investors is explicitly recognized and, further, the country of residence provides one useful dimension for gauging such heterogeneity. Acknowledgements Previous versions of the paper were circulated under several different titles including: ‘‘Do different interpretations of the same information help explain the distinct stock holdings of foreign investors?” and ‘‘Do different interpretations of the same information help explain the home bias?” We are genuinely grateful to an anonymous referee for many of the constructive comments. We also thank Kee-Hong Bae, Joon Chae, Jay Chung, Gwang Heon Hong, Sung Wook Joh, Dae Il Kang, Bong-Chan Kho, Joonghyuk Kim, Woojin Kim, Kuan-Hui Lee, Hyoung-Jin Park, and the seminar participants and discussants at Korea University Business School, Seoul National University, the SKK GSB, the Korea Institute of Finance, the 2008 joint conference by five Korean finance associations, the 2008 KFMA meetings, the 2008 KFA meetings, the 2008 CAFM conference, the 2009 INFINITI conference, and the 2009 CICF conference for comments. Any remaining errors are our own responsibilities. Financial support from Korea University is gratefully acknowledged (Kyung Suh Park). References 17 Note that this weaker result with weekly data is not attributable to imprecise year-by-year estimation of Eqs. (2) and (3) with fewer observations. On average, the residual volatility is smaller and the regression R2 is higher with the weekly estimation. Alexander, G., Eun, C., Janakiramanan, S., 1987. Asset pricing and dual listing on foreign capital markets: a Note. Journal of Finance 42, 151–158. Allen, F., Gale, D., 1999. Diversity of opinion and financing of new technology. Journal of Financial Intermediation 8, 68–89. 2896 H.C. Kang et al. / Journal of Banking & Finance 34 (2010) 2886–2896 Anderson, E., Ghysels, E., Juergens, J., 2005. Do heterogeneous beliefs matter for asset pricing? Review of Financial Studies 18, 875–924. Baker, M., Foley, F., Wurgler, J., 2009. Multinationals as Arbitrageurs: the effect of stock market valuations on foreign direct investment. Review of Financial Studies 22, 337–369. Basak, S., 2000. A model of dynamic equilibrium asset pricing with heterogeneous beliefs and extraneous risk. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 24, 63–95. Baxter, M., Jermann, J., 1997. The international diversification puzzle is worse than you think. American Economic Review 87, 170–180. Bodie, Z., Kane, A., Marcus, A., 2008. Investments. McGraw-Hill, New York. Bohn, H., Tesar, L., 1996. US equity investment in foreign markets: Portfolio rebalancing or return chasing? American Economic Review 86, 77–81. Boot, A., Gopalan, R., Thakor, A., 2006. The entrepreneur’s choice between private and public ownership. Journal of Finance 61, 803–836. Brennan, M., Cao, H., 1997. International portfolio investment flows. Journal of Finance 52, 1851–1880. Chae, J., Kim, S., Lee, E., 2009. How corporate governance affects payout policy under agency problems and external financing constraints. Journal of Banking and Finance 33, 2093–2101. Chan, K., Covrig, V., Ng, L., 2005. What determines the domestic bias and foreign bias? Evidence from mutual fund equity allocations worldwide. Journal of Finance 60, 1495–1534. Chang, C., Hsieh, P., Lai, H., 2009. Do informed option investors predict stock returns? Evidence from the Taiwan stock exchange. Journal of Banking and Finance 33, 757–764. Chen, J., Hong, H., Stein, J., 2002. Breadth of ownership and stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics 66, 171–205. Chen, L., Johnson, S., Lin, J., Liu, Y., 2009. Information, sophistication, and foreign versus domestic investors’ preferences. Journal of Banking and Finance 33, 1636–1651. Choe, H., Kho, B., Stulz, R., 1999. Do foreign investors destabilize stock markets? The Korean experience in 1997. Journal of Financial Economics 54, 227–264. Choe, H., Kho, B., Stulz, R., 2005. Do domestic investors have an edge? The trading experience of foreign investors in Korea. Review of Financial Studies 18, 795–829. Cochrane, J., 2001. Asset Pricing. Princeton University Press, New Jersey. Constantidies, J., 1982. Intertemporal asset pricing with heterogeneous consumers and without demand aggregation. Journal of Business 55, 253–267. Cooper, I., Kaplanis, E., 1994. Home bias in equity portfolios, inflation hedging, and international capital market equilibrium. Review of Financial Studies 7, 45–60. Coval, J., Thakor, A., 2005. Financial intermediation as a belief-bridge between optimists and pessimists. Journal of Financial Economics 75, 535–570. Dahlquist, M., Pinkowitz, L., Stulz, R., Williamson, R., 2003. Corporate governance, investor protection, and the home bias. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 38, 87–110. Dahlquist, M., Robertsson, G., 2001. Direct foreign ownership, institutional investors, and firm characteristics. Journal of Financial Economics 59, 413–440. David, A., 2008. Heterogeneous beliefs, speculation, and the equity premium. Journal of Finance 63, 41–83. French, K., Poterba, R., 1991. Investor diversification and international equity markets. American Economic Review 81, 222–226. Froot, K., O’Connell, P., Seasholes, M., 2001. The portfolio flows of international investors. Journal of Financial Economics 59, 151–193. Froot, K., Ramadorai, T., 2008. Institutional portfolio flows and international investments. Review of Financial Studies 21, 937–971. Gibbons, M., Ross, S., Shanken, J., 1989. A test of the efficiency of a given portfolio. Econometrica 57, 1121–1152. Glassman, D., Riddick, A., 2001. What causes home asset bias and how should it be measured? Journal of Empirical Finance 8, 35–54. Griffin, J., Nardari, F., Stulz, R., 2004. Are daily cross-border equity flows pushed or pulled? Review of Economics and Statistics 86, 641–657. Grinblatt, M., Keloharju, M., 2000. The investment behavior and performance of various investor-types: a study of Finland’s unique data set. Journal of Financial Economics 55, 43–67. Harris, M., Raviv, A., 1993. Differences of opinion make a horse race. Review of Financial Studies 6, 473–506. Harrison, M., Kreps, D., 1978. Speculative investor behavior in a stock market with heterogeneous expectations. Quarterly Journal of Economics 92, 323–336. Hausman, J., 1978. Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica 46, 1251– 1271. Ingersoll, J., 1987. Theory of Financial Decision Making. Rowman and Littlefield, New Jersey. Jung, C., Lee, D., Park, K., 2009. Can investor heterogeneity be used to explain the cross-section of average stock returns in emerging markets? Journal of International Money and Finance 28, 648–670. Kalev, P., Nguyen, A., Oh, N., 2008. Foreign versus local investors: who knows more? who makes more? Journal of Banking and Finance 32, 2376–2389. Kandel, E., Pearson, N., 1995. Differential interpretation of public signals and trade in speculative markets. Journal of Political Economy 103, 831–872. Kang, J., Stulz, R., 1997. Why is there a home bias? An analysis of foreign portfolio equity ownership in Japan. Journal of Financial Economics 46, 2–28. Karolyi, A., Stulz, R., 2003. Are assets priced locally or globally. In: Constantinides, G., Harris, M., Stulz, R. (Eds.), Handbook of the Economics of Finance, vol. 1. Amsterdam, North Holland. Kho, B., Stulz, R., Warnock, F., 2006. Financial globalization, governance, and the evolution of the home bias. Working paper, Ohio State University. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., 1999. Corporate ownership around the world. Journal of Finance 54, 471–517. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 2000. Agency problems and dividend policies around the world. Journal of Finance 55, 1–33. Lewis, K., 1995. Puzzles in international financial markets. In: Grossman, G., Rogoff, K. (Eds.), Handbook of International Economics, vol. 3. Elsevier, Amsterdam. Lewis, K., 1999. Trying to explain home bias in equities and consumption. Journal of Economic Literature 37, 571–608. Lins, K., Warnock, F., 2006. Do foreigners invest less in poorly governed firms? Working paper, NBER 12222. Maddala, G., 1992. Introduction to Econometrics. Prentice Hall, New Jersey. Morris, S., 1995. The common prior assumption in economic theory. Economics and Philosophy 11, 227–253. Petersen, M., 2009. Estimating standard errors in finance panel data sets: comparing approaches. Review of Financial Studies 22, 435–480. Pontiff, J., 2006. Costly arbitrage and the myth of idiosyncratic risk. Journal of Accounting and Economics 42, 35–52. Rubinstein, M., 1974. An aggregation theorem for securities markets. Journal of Financial Economics 1, 225–244. Seasholes, M., 2000. Smart foreign traders in emerging markets. Working paper, University of California-Berkeley. Tesar, L., Werner, I., 1995. Home bias and high turnover. Journal of International Money and Finance 14, 467–493. Treynor, J., Black, F., 1973. How to use security analysis to improve portfolio selection. Journal of Business 46, 66–86. Varian, H., 1985. Divergence of opinion in complete markets: a note. Journal of Finance 40, 309–317.