Download China: Leading the Way to a New World Order?

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Chinese economic reform wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
China: Leading
the Way to a
New World Order?
Kevin Frayer/Getty Images
China:
Leading the Way to a
New World Order?
INTRODUCTION
4
5
China and the Global Financial Crisis
CHINA’S DELICATE POLITICAL
POSITION AMID REFORM
9
What Political Reform Means
10
What Makes China Different
12
IMAGINING A DEMOCRATIC CHINA
14
Asia’s Managed Transitions
14
Conceding from Strength
15
THE HIGH STAKES OF HAVING
A JOB IN CHINA
17
Employment in East Asia
17
China’s Developmental Experiment
18
WHAT KIND OF POWER WILL CHINA BECOME?
22
What Kind of Great Power?
23
The Sinocentric World Order
23
From Sinocentrism to Chinese Exceptionalism
26
BRIDGING THE GAP BETWEEN CHINA’S
CENTRAL AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS
28
A Lesson Learned
29
Implementation and Local Deviance
29
Tourists walk along a section of the Great Wall of China near Beijing. (KEVIN FRAYER/Getty Images)
Research Note: This report asks what China’s role be in the international order five, 10 or 15
years relying on 20 years of Stratfor’s collective experience in providing geopolitical intelligence.
Whether we expect Chinese power to grow or to diminish has significant implications for it and
for the future of the global order. Curated by our Research Analytics Department, it brings us up
to 2016, taking into account the latest developments.
INTRODUCTION
T
he fundamental challenge in predicting China’s future is how best to measure the myriad
compulsions and constraints that will dictate
its evolution over the next decade or so. To do this
requires more than merely listing those forces. It demands developing a framework for understanding how
they interact and for gauging their relative significance
to the core question — where China is headed. We
will develop such a framework and apply it to a wide
variety of issues in China’s political economy, with a
goal of both testing and adding nuance to Stratfor’s
core expectations for the future of China.
We assume that forecasting China’s trajectory on the
world stage necessitates an understanding of its internal challenges and imperatives. In turn, understanding
how these domestic forces will evolve and interact
— and shape the Chinese government’s behavior —
demands grasping how changes in the international
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 4
order influence the country domestically. Rather than
looking solely at China’s domestic issues or only at its
international relations, we will focus on the interplay
between the two. How do shifts in the external order
— whether changes in Japanese monetary policy, the
U.S. detente with Iran, or stagnation and fragmentation in the European Union — put new pressures on
or limit the policy options available to China’s leaders?
How, in turn, do Beijing’s imperatives and actions at
home — such as moves to support industries such
as steel and railway construction, efforts to expand
urbanization and stimulate domestic consumption,
and President Xi Jinping’s drive to consolidate political power and push through controversial social and
economic reforms — shape its behavior toward its
neighbors and its role in global markets?
These are the sorts of questions we will address going
forward, treating the inward-out and outward-in pressures on the Chinese state in roughly equal measure.
And as the nature of the interplay between changes in
China’s internal and external orders becomes clearer,
we will begin to piece together the relevant factors into
a mosaic of China’s — and the international system’s
— future development.
China and the Global
Financial Crisis
For the most part, we will focus on current and unfolding events, how they will likely play out and what
their second, third and fourth-order effects may be.
But we will begin by looking back — to the 20082009 global financial crisis and to the ways in which
it transformed China’s domestic situation and influenced the policy priorities of and challenges facing its
government. The crisis and its aftermath form an apt
starting point for our investigations. For one, they well
illustrate the interplay between changes in the international order and shifts in China’s domestic needs
and constraints. But more important, it is impossible
to grasp the compulsions and constraints currently
driving China without first understanding how the
economic crisis shaped both China’s political and
economic challenges and the international backdrop
against which those challenges will play out.
By far the most significant consequence of the global
financial crisis for China was its impact on the export-oriented economic growth model that sustained
China’s extraordinary rise in the decades after Mao
Zedong’s death. Between 1979 and 2007, exports as a
share of the country’s gross domestic product rose from
less than 6 percent to nearly 36 percent — more than
three times the ratio in the United States, twice that
in Japan, and on a par with that in Germany. In dollar
terms, the growth in Chinese exports was similarly
impressive, with export values rising from virtually
nothing in 1980 to $288 billion by 2001 and to more
than $1.2 trillion six years later. Of course, the flipside
of this tremendous growth was that, by 2007, some
300 million or more Chinese workers, many of them
migrants from the impoverished interior, worked in
and around the country’s vast coastal export empire.
For years prior to the financial crisis, Chinese leaders
readily acknowledged the limits and risks inherent to
the country’s export-oriented economic growth model.
They understood that rising rates of urbanization, education levels and cost of living in coastal cities would
eventually — despite formal and informal government
efforts to keep costs low — undermine the competitiveness of coastal China’s low-cost manufacturing
base. They grasped the political risks of a growth
model that fed on and intensified economic disparities
between coastal and interior regions. And they grasped
that, for the sake of maintaining social and political
cohesion, the country would have to move toward a
model more dependent on domestic consumption
(and thus less exposed to drops in external demand for
goods) and on high value-added services and manufacturing industries. (This would better equip China
to remain globally competitive in the face of rising
costs at home.) To these ends, Beijing launched several
regional development plans between 1999 and 2004
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 5
aimed at industrializing the hinterland so that, as costs
rose and consumer markets developed in coastal cities,
these regions might emerge as successor low-end manufacturing and raw materials supply bases.
The success of these programs was underwhelming.
Throughout the early-to-mid 2000s, strong external
demand for cheap Chinese goods, particularly in the
United States and Europe, combined with the coastal
provinces’ ever-rising demand for cheap labor from
the interior to prevent truly substantive changes in the
country’s overall policy direction. For China’s leaders,
though the long-term goals of stimulating domestic
consumption, developing a high value-added services
sector, and pushing manufacturing up the value chain
were critical, they were ultimately just that: longterm goals. In the short-term, the need to maintain
high rates of employment, along with the reasonable
fear that the pursuit of economic reforms to enable
a consumption-driven economy would undermine
employment, guaranteed that any move to reduce
the country’s reliance on low-cost exports would
be partial at best.
household consumption (by maintaining artificially
low wages and input costs) to one grounded in the
expansion of domestic consumption. It eliminated the
possibility — available to virtually all of China’s predecessors on the path toward advanced industrial status
— of industrializing over the course of decades and in
a healthy, conducive global economic environment.
The crisis imposed time constraints on the transformation that would have to be undertaken, the scale and
speed of which was already enormous. Most of China’s
population, moreover, lived in extreme poverty. Under
such conditions, the government was unwilling to embrace the destabilizing effects that full-scale adoption
of liberalizing measures might have. So, Beijing chose
not to reform but to double down on government-led
investment into housing and infrastructure projects.
The global financial crisis obliterated this logic almost
overnight. Though Chinese exports continued to
grow in raw dollar terms after 2008, their share of the
country’s economy has plummeted from 32 percent in
2008 to 23 percent in 2014. Meanwhile, a shift in the
international economic order thrust China into a radical new economic, social and political reality at home.
It became clear in 2009-2010 that the crisis, far from
a momentary convulsion in one of the world’s pillar
economies, was in fact the start of what promised to be
a much longer period of low-to-stagnant growth across
much of the developed world. China’s leaders subsequently found themselves forced to convert the temporary stop-gap measure of the 2008-2009 stimulus
package into something more ambitious and risky.
Between 2007-2015, fixed-asset investment, always a
central component of China’s economy, rose steadily from 44 percent to 82 percent of gross domestic
product. In 2013, $10.7 trillion in new credit was extended, some $3.1 trillion of which is thought to have
been funneled into construction-related activity, much
of it in the country’s interior. And while much of the
investment has gone into productive projects — such
as high-speed rail, pipeline and power infrastructure,
road construction and ports that will ultimately help
bind inland and coastal regions into a single, efficient
and profitable national economy — much of it has
not. Housing supply imbalances and falling average
home prices across much of China between 2014 and
mid-2015, along with weak-to-negative profit margins
throughout the heavy industrial sector, attest to the
investment boom’s basic insensitivity to price signals.
While housing and construction industries will not
likely collapse outright in the months ahead, thanks
to government support and rising urbanization, they
are unlikely to re-emerge as stable, reliable drivers of
national economic growth any time soon.
In effect, the global economic crisis pushed China to
accelerate the process of moving from an economic
model grounded in the systematic repression of private
In the meantime, private consumption activity as a
portion of gross domestic product is falling, not rising.
And herein lies China’s core problem today: the Chi-
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 6
Comparing
China’s Economy
U.S.
$17.4 trillion
GDP TOP FIVE (2014)
GDP RANKINGS
WHEN MEASURED
PER CAPITA (2014)
Top 9: Luxembourg, Norway, Qatar,
Macao, Switzerland, Australia,
Denmark, Sweden, Singapore.
U.S.
$54,630
RANK 10
CHINA
806 million
LABOR FORCE
TOP FIVE (2014)
U.S
$2.3 trillion
TOP FIVE
IMPORTERS (2015)
CHINA
$2.3 trillion
TOP FIVE
EXPORTERS (2015)
TOP FIVE MILITARY
EXPENDITURE (2014)
Sources: World Bank, Trade Map, SIPRI
U.S
$610 billion
CHINA
$10.4 trillion
Japan
$4.6 trillion
Germany
$3.9 trillion
U.K.
$3.0 trillion
*Among those higher than China:
Colombia, Azerbaijan and Bulgaria.
Germany
$47,822
U.K.
$46,332
17
19
27
CHINA*
$7,590
U.S
161 million
Indonesia
124 million
Brazil
110 million
Japan
$648 billion
U.K.
$626 billion
Japan
$625 billion
Netherlands
$567 billion
Saudi
Arabia
$81 billion
France
$62 billion
India
497 million
CHINA
$1.7 trillion
Japan
$36,194
Germany
$1.0 trillion
U.S
$1.5 trillion
Germany
$1.3 trillion
CHINA
$216 billion
Russia
$85 billion
78
Copyright Stratfor 2016 www.stratfor.com
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 7
nese government has exhausted all tools (short of the
sort of broadly liberalizing reforms that are its best bet
for building a consumption-driven economy, however
politically untenable they may be) for managing the
shift away from the low-cost export-oriented growth
model that for three decades underpinned not only
employment stability, but also social cohesion and
the Communist Party’s political legitimacy. Rapidly
declining returns on government-led investment and
the realization that no matter how quickly housing
demand rises it cannot keep pace with the kind of supply growth seen between 2010-2013 suggest that the
investment-led model is quickly losing efficacy. Weak
demand globally and rising costs at home decrease
the potential for a second low-cost export boom. And
barring much deeper financial, social and political
reforms, China’s government will struggle to provide
ordinary Chinese with the opportunity and confidence
needed to build a true consumption economy.
Had China been able to make the shift from a low-cost
export economy to a consumption-driven economy
more gradually and in an environment of strong global
growth, its economic situation, and likely its social and
political situations too, would probably be different
today. What China is currently, the unique pressures
and risks it faces, was in many ways forged between
2008-2009, as much as by events or for reasons internal to China. As we will see, the legacy of 2008-2009
and the policy decisions it forced upon China’s leaders
pervade virtually every aspect of the country’s political
economy today, including its international interests
and behavior. n
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 8
Chinese guards stand outside the Great Hall of the People in Beijing. (Getty Images)
CHINA’S DELICATE
POLITICAL
POSITION AMID
REFORM
B
efore we consider the challenges facing China’s
governing institutions, it is useful to outline
some key concepts and examine prior cases
in which states struggled to close the gap between
themselves and the rapidly changing societies they
governed. Doing so will help clarify what is at stake for
China’s leaders as they embark on a period of political
reform against a backdrop of profound social and economic change. It will also shed light on how China’s
recent efforts at political reform reflect or differ from
prior cases and whether the current reform measures
are likely to succeed. And, returning to questions
outlined above, once we have established what political
reform within China entails, we can begin to consider
how these internal evolutions will reverberate outward, affecting both China’s external behavior and its
strategic environment.
What Political Reform Means
Any attempt to understand political reform in China
today must begin by asking why China’s leaders seek to
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 9
reform its political institutions. As Stratfor has argued,
the Communist Party’s fundamental goal in implementing political reforms — a term encompassing everything from the anti-corruption campaign to efforts
to improve rule of law, environmental protection and
social services — is to ensure the continued legitimacy
of their rule. For decades, that legitimacy rested on the
promises of universal employment and a moderately
wealthy society enabled by China’s economic boom.
As long as the government met these conditions for
the majority of the population (particularly the politically crucial urban coastal constituencies), many of
the problems, inefficiencies and inequities in China’s
governance could be — and largely were — overlooked by its populace with the assumption that they
would eventually be corrected. But with the economy’s
slowdown, these promises are becoming increasingly
untenable. This process has forced China’s leaders to
seek new foundations for the legitimacy of their government and the Communist Party’s control over it.
What the current efforts for political reform all point
to is a broad consensus among China’s leaders that
the future legitimacy of their rule rests in their ability
to provide what political scientist Francis Fukuyama
calls high-quality governance. This involves the state’s
ability to collect and fairly redistribute income along
with institutions’ ability to operate with a large degree
of freedom from political interference. Faced with an
increasingly well-educated and urbanized consumer
society, and pressed by the need to compete globally as
a producer of high value-added manufactured goods
as well as financial and other services, Beijing needs to
implement a variety of measures to govern effectively. Not only does Beijing strive to increase quality of
life (for example, by improving air quality, food and
workplace safety, and ordinary citizens’ ability to earn
returns on their savings), it also seeks to incentivize
industrial upgrading, innovation and entrepreneurship. The former goals are difficult enough, because
they will almost certainly impose higher costs on the
state-owned banks and enterprises that remain the
backbone of China’s economy — a tough sell at a time
when profit margins for many of these enterprises are
hovering at or below zero. And incentivizing the kinds
of investments and industrial upgrades that stimulate
economic growth will require much more profound
changes to China’s political institutions, not to mention its education system and business climate.
Scholars and policymakers almost unanimously agree
that strong protection for physical and intellectual property rights are essential building blocks for
wealthy societies and advanced industrial economies.
There is less consensus on the conditions under which
such protections can take root. One school, embodied
in Daron Acemoglu and James A. Robinson’s Why
Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and
Poverty, maintains that protecting property rights and
thus encouraging research and development, innovation and entrepreneurship requires first establishing
democratic or inclusive political institutions with
built-in checks (such as a strong and independent
judiciary) on the government’s power. Another school,
which includes Fukuyama and has its roots in Samuel
Huntington’s Political Order in Changing Societies,
disagrees about the importance of democracy in developing a prosperous society. Adherents of this second
school affirm that a country needs fair and impartial
adjudication of civil disputes and strong protection for
individual property and other rights to move from a
low value-added to a high value-added economy, but
they argue that inclusive or democratic political institutions are not essential to this process.
In his 2013 essay “What is Governance?”, Fukuyama
outlines two essential conditions of effective governance: high state capacity and a high degree of bureaucratic autonomy. The first describes the state’s ability
to tax citizens’ income and to efficiently, effectively
and fairly redistribute that income in the forms of
physical infrastructure, social services and other public
goods. The second describes the ability of a country’s
administrative institutions to set long-term goals
and experiment without much political interference.
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 10
Comparing China’s Quality of Life, 1985 vs. 2014
AUTOMOBILE
OWNERSHIP
DISPOSABLE
INCOME
Vehicles sold
Per capita, USD
2014
123,393,600
1985
284,900
2014
$5,470
LIFE
EXPECTANCY
COLLEGE
EDUCATION
College and above
per 100,000
1985
67
2014
8,930
2014
75
1985
615
1985
$246
Source: World Bank, National Bureau
In Fukuyama’s conception, bureaucratic autonomy
without strong state capacity is a recipe for weak and
kleptocratic institutions, while strong state capacity
without bureaucratic autonomy subjects the policymaking process to political whims — as during the
Maoist era — and makes protection of property and
other individual rights more difficult.
Crucially for China, by this definition effective governance does not have to be democratic to achieve
high-quality administration, the efficient provision of
public goods and fair adjudication of civil disputes.
Indeed, as Fukuyama and Huntington both show,
the world — and in particular, Asia — abounds with
examples of states that achieved high-quality gover-
Copyright Stratfor 2016 www.stratfor.com
nance and correspondingly high incomes and quality of life under institutional structures that could
scarcely be considered democratic. Perhaps the most
famous example is Japan, which went from war-torn
and impoverished to the world’s second largest and
second wealthiest economy in four decades under
what amounted to a single-party state in which a small
collection of elite civil ministries designed and enforced development policy. A similar narrative applies
to South Korea, Taiwan and Singapore, all of which
achieved not only fast-growing but also innovative and
advanced manufacturing-based economies in the total
or partial absence of democracy, largely by following
Japan’s example. Such conditions are not isolated
to Asia. In the 19th century, the Prussian (and later
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 11
German) state maintained a fast-growing economy at
the leading edge technologically along with a highly
effective civil bureaucracy without devolving power.
What Makes China Different
At the very least, this body of thought and these prior
cases suggest that whatever myriad constraints there
may be on China’s capacity to reform and improve its
political and administrative institutions, they are not
grounded in its lack of multiparty elections. That said,
there are important differences between contemporary
China and Japan in the 1940s-1960s, South Korea
and Taiwan in the 1960s-2000s, and Prussia in the
19th century.
First, they face different external economic and strategic environments. The transformations of Japan, South
Korea and Taiwan (including both their initial industrialization and their shift up the value chain) all took
place, to differing degrees, under the strategic umbrella
of the United States and with active economic support
from Washington in the context of the Cold War. The
industrialization that China underwent decades ago
occurred under similarly conducive circumstances,
but today its environment is much more challenging, both economically and politically. Furthermore,
China’s current task is profoundly different and more
difficult than mere industrialization: In an extremely short period of time, it must transform a colossal,
internally diverse and fragmented economy from one
dependent on low value-added manufacturing to one
based on high value-added manufacturing and services. However, perhaps most relevant to our current
discussion is the contrast between China’s political
institutions and those of non-democratic economic
success stories such as South Korea. China possesses
a relatively high capacity state, but its bureaucracy
is comparatively less autonomous, especially in respects that are crucial for attaining high-functioning
and impartial administration.
This difference is particularly sharp in the comparison
between China and Japan during the post-World War
II era. Although nominally an electoral democracy,
Japan through the 1990s (and arguably to this day)
was in fact a one-party state. However, as political scientist Chalmers Johnson and others have made clear,
throughout this period it was not the party at the helm
of that state, the Liberal Democratic Party, that actually had power. Rather, it was the autonomous civil
bureaucracies that controlled the policymaking process
and enjoyed significant independence from (and influence over) the electoral apparatus. Power belonged to
the bureaucracies, which had their own highly institutionalized recruitment processes, and moved outward
to the rest of the political structure.
In China, by contrast, power resides not with the
country’s vast administrative bureaucracies, but with
the Communist Party that oversees them and exerts
almost complete control over internal recruitment and
advancement. Indeed, despite calls for stronger rule of
law and judicial reform, all signs point to a strengthening of the Communist Party’s control over the state
under President Xi Jinping. In addition to conducting
an anti-corruption campaign that bolsters the Party’s
power, the president has put small, appointed groups
that answer directly to him in charge of making economic and national security policy. All of this suggests
that the policymaking process in China is becoming
more centralized, more personalized and arguably
more political.
This is not to suggest that Xi’s measures will necessarily
fail. By centralizing power the president may indeed
preserve political order as China’s economic slowdown
deepens. But if Xi aims to achieve high-quality governance as a basis for the Communist Party’s legitimacy, he is charting a new and untested path toward
that goal. The scholarly consensus is that the most
effective governments balance a strong state with an
independent and apolitical bureaucracy; instead the
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 12
president is making China’s bureaucratic institutions
even more politicized and beholden to dictates from
Party leadership.
It is unclear how the centralization of economic policymaking under Xi and his “leading small groups,”
and the attendant sidelining of Premier Li Keqiang,
the State Council and the technocratic bureaucracy
they oversee (institutions that reached their apogee
under the previous administration), will empower
China’s judicial and administrative systems to perform better. Likewise, it is unclear how and when the
anti-corruption campaign, which has paralyzed China’s
bureaucracy and dramatically reduced its autonomy
and willingness to experiment, will begin to have
the reverse effect. For now, all signs point to a continued centralization and personalization of political
power — a process that will be difficult to square with
the growing need for better governance in a rapidly
changing China. n
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 13
A Chinese student displays a banner during the April 1989 demonstrations in Tiananmen Square
which were later crushed by Chinese troops. (CATHERINE HENRIETTE/AFP/Getty Images)
IMAGINING A
DEMOCRATIC
CHINA
S
tratfor has long emphasized that China’s ruling
party is more resilient and its grip on power
more durable than may seem to be the case. The
resilience is partly rooted in successful Communist
Party efforts to improve the quality of the country’s
governing institutions and to extend the reach of the
domestic security apparatus. It is also bolstered by
the less tangible forces of nationalism and entrenched
institutional bureaucracy, which bind a nation together
and slow the onset of crisis. Government survival is
also helped by the relative restraint that major powers
have shown amid China’s economic rise and military
modernization. The United States, for example, has
not pushed aggressively against China’s currency revaluation, moved to seriously contain or reverse China’s
maritime expansion, or isolated China diplomatically.
Asia’s Managed Transitions
China’s situation, therefore, is one of seeming contradiction: The government is suffering an existential crisis even as its political institutions are more powerful
and sophisticated than ever. The uncomfortable mixture of institutional strength and political vulnerability
may seem exceptional. The history of modern East
Asia, however, is replete with governments that have
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 14
faced either acute or chronic challenges to their legitimacy at the peak of their effectiveness, including South
Korea, Taiwan, Malaysia, Singapore, Indonesia and
Myanmar. Some of these challenges were precipitated
by economic crisis but just as often they were not.
Most relevant for China is that each of these governments began as authoritarian, or nearly so, and ended
by embracing freely contested elections that bolstered
their legitimacy without undermining their power and
influence. All responded with state-managed, carefully
orchestrated transitions to democracy as well.
Myanmar is an emblematic — and recent — example
of such a transition. From 1962 to 2011, the country
was ruled by an authoritarian military government.
After a managed transition, the long sidelined National League for Democracy won a resounding victory
Nov. 8, 2015, in a general election that has been
lauded as both free and fair. At the same time, members of the former ruling government not only retain a
strong position in parliament, but far more important,
continue to exert extensive influence over the country’s
business community, civil bureaucracy and military,
which remains Myanmar’s single most powerful institution by far. In other words, the former junta’s longplanned concession of elections and apparent defeat
do not amount to true power concessions in terms of
Myanmar’s long-term trajectory and evolution. In the
meantime, the government has managed to garner new
respect in the eyes of its own people and the international community, guaranteeing that if its leaders return to office — as they intend — they will command
greater legitimacy with the electorate.
Of course, Myanmar’s military junta has followed
the lead of governments in South Korea, Taiwan and
Malaysia on the eve of their own transitions to electoral democracy. In each case, the entrenched political
elite opted to hold elections when confronted by a
confluence of declining legitimacy, grassroots political pressures and economic stress. However, these
elections were structurally designed to prevent them
from undermining the ruling elite’s power within the
economy and bureaucracy. In Singapore and Malaysia, the former rulers won the elections and retained
formal power. In Taiwan and South Korea, by contrast, the former rulers temporarily lost formal power
but retained control of much of the bureaucracy. In
Indonesia, the elite of the previous government never
regained formal political control but continue to exert
extraordinary influence in business, administration and
local politics. In all cases, the old government and the
elite at its helm preserved their core interests: survival
and influence.
What all of these transitions have in common is that
none of the governments absolutely needed to democratize when they did. This is true of China as well.
These governments held immense strength compared
to other domestic political parties and likely could
have endured for years without change. Their embrace
of elections was not reactive, but strategic. Elections
staved off threats to government stability or to the
safety of the elite while bolstering the elite’s long-term
chances at retaining de facto control — or eventually
control in name. In international terms, these governments ensured the goodwill of the United States and
the many benefits of Western support.
Conceding From Strength
What about China? The potential for China’s Communist Party to follow these examples and concede
to elections from a position of strength is an essential
question for the future of East Asia. China possesses all
the features noted above of a government on the verge
of a state-managed transition to democracy. These
include a strong, well-established party with a proven
track record and deep pockets but a persistent problem
securing the full support of the population.
A democratic China does not seem unlikely and a
managed transition would solve some of Beijing’s problems. Regular elections would offer a release for the
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 15
suppressed social pressures that are difficult for China’s
leaders to measure much less mitigate. Clear electoral
victory would help ease Communist Party leaders’ constant fear of losing the “mandate of heaven” by quantifying the level of support that the Party enjoys at any
given time. Planning for economic, security and social
policy would also function differently in a democratic
China, as would the management of tensions between
Beijing and the provinces or between local governments themselves. Internationally, democracy would
bolster China’s strategic interests, whether in Africa
or Southeast Asia or North America. It would also
improve China’s negotiating position with the United
States, perhaps paving the way for China to accede to
groupings such as the Trans-Pacific Partnership.
But it is its very position in the international community that prevents the Communist Party from conceding to a democratic system — a system intimately
tied with the U.S.-led world order. If democracy
ever comes to China, it will be once the Communist
Party government has been thoroughly delegitimized
through profound and sustained crisis or defeat in war.
This is because of the simple fact that China, unlike
Myanmar or South Korea, is a great power. With this
status, Beijing sees itself as having the potential to
challenge dominant U.S. power in the world system,
whereas other powers are by definition secondary to
the world system and must react.
The Communist Party, the entity that has elevated
China to great power status, has staked its legitimacy
on realizing the country’s potential to fundamentally reshape the international balance of power. This
requires economic growth and good governance, but is
not reducible to them. The gambit has become more
pronounced and explicit in the last few years, as slowing economic growth has spurred a shift to increasing
nationalism. The party’s claim to legitimacy and to
being China’s rightful redeemer after a “century of humiliation” has been central to the Communist Party’s
self-conception from the start. And like all rising great
powers before it, China’s self-conception has become
inseparable from its relationship with the system’s sole
superpower, the United States. Earlier rising powers,
such as the Soviet Union, understood themselves to
be locked in a struggle for world supremacy with the
United States. It is not ideological hatred of democracy that animates the Communist Party’s rejection of
elections but the need to lay out a different path from
Washington and to present China as an independent
and equal pole of geopolitical power.
As growth slows and security needs mount, the Communist Party’s stance will serve to bolster popular
support — nationalism feeds on external threats. In
the longer run, however, it will make governing China
and meeting the ever-rising expectations of its people
far more difficult. To bet one’s legitimacy on nationalist aspirations is risky, especially when fulfilling those
aspirations requires confronting an international order
crafted by a state as powerful as the United States.
Whatever the outcome, the Communist Party’s unwillingness to follow the path of other East Asian democracies and to accept the subordination to a U.S.-led
order will make China perhaps less predictable to its
counterparts and competitors in the coming years, but
it will also make it far more interesting to watch. n
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 16
Chinese migrant workers in a bus after a day's construction work in Beijing. (KEVIN FRAYER/Getty Images)
THE HIGH STAKES
OF HAVING A JOB
IN CHINA
Employment in East Asia
C
hina is certainly not the first country to have
organized its political and economic institutions around the goal of preventing unemployment. The fear of unemployment and the social
instability it breeds sits, in many ways, at the heart of
modern conceptions of the proper role of the state in
regulating economics. For example, Western Europe
and the United States, having extended voting rights in
the 19th and early 20th centuries, made monetary policy decisions with an eye toward keeping employment
high and protecting the economic well-being of their
newly empowered constituents. Out of this process
grew the view, spurred by the global depression of the
1930s, that absent the state’s mediating hand, capitalism would generate iniquities so great they would
undermine the foundations of society. Translated into
monetary and fiscal policy, this view became known
as Keynesianism, a doctrine that dominated economic
decision-making in Europe and the United States for
more than four decades.
But in industrialized countries with well-developed
democratic institutions, such as the United States and
much of Western Europe after World War II, the pressure to maintain employment had limits. These countries could count on the adaptability of their educated,
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 17
mobile and technologically savvy workforces and their
globally competitive enterprises to ensure that opportunities in one part of the economy would compensate
for unemployment elsewhere. Moreover, regularly
scheduled elections ensured that in the worst cases
economic disruption might doom individual leaders
or administrations but would not threaten the legitimacy of the government itself. Thus, while the focus
on employment was a central component of fiscal and
monetary policy in Western democracies, it was not
the only determinant for economic decision-making.
The same could not be said for the export- and investment-led economic growth model of the newly industrializing economies of East Asia. The governments of
postwar Japan, South Korea in the wake of colonialism
and a devastating civil war, and post-1949 Taiwan
each faced large and rapidly growing pools of unemployed urban workers, many of them migrants recently
displaced by war and land reform. Each government
responded by launching state-led industrialization programs unprecedented in scope and speed and unique
in their use of state power to foster industrial giants
capable of competing in the global marketplace. For
all three countries, as well as for China and to some
extent for the post-colonial states of Southeast Asia,
rapid export-led industrialization was first and foremost a means to generate employment, ensuring social
stability and the security of their fragile governments.
Also like China, all three countries eventually exhausted the utility of their labor-intensive, low-cost export
growth models and were forced to shift up the value
chain to produce higher-value goods. Crucially, when
the time came for Japan, South Korea and Taiwan
to move from producing low to high value-added
industrial goods, these countries could rely on the
ever-growing and ever-wealthier foreign consumer
markets — namely, the United States — to take in
the swelling volumes of expensive goods they produced. No matter how much these countries produced
throughout the 1980s, 1990s and 2000s, their goods
almost always found ready overseas buyers.
Consequently, Japan, South Korea and Taiwan did not
need to rapidly boost domestic consumption to offset
declines in antiquated export industries. They could
continue to rely on exports, or at least the financial
returns on exports produced by their companies’
overseas operations, to fund employment and maintain quality of life back home. To be sure, all three
today boast large consumer markets, but most of their
imports come from energy, raw materials and parts
for processing and re-export, rather than imported
goods for consumption. To a far greater extent than
the United States and most of Western Europe, these
economies rely on manufacturing and exports to drive
growth, not services and consumption.
China’s Developmental
Experiment
Since the introduction of its economic opening and
reform policies in 1978, and especially in the decades
following the protests in Tiananmen Square, China has
followed a similar path to those of Japan, South Korea
and Taiwan during the 1960s-1980s. Like these earlier
incarnations of the developmental state, China has
used state power to foster globally competitive “national champions” in areas including energy, construction,
shipbuilding, finance and heavy industry. Like Taiwan,
it has used these state-owned conglomerates to lay the
foundations for a private sector-led manufacturing
export boom. More recently, it has focused on cultivating, like South Korea and Japan, several privately
owned but state-aligned technology and manufacturing
firms. Beijing looks to these firms to drive the country’s
nascent shift up the global value chain. And like its
predecessors, China has done this to maintain employment across an increasingly diversified workforce.
It is unclear whether China’s shift up the value chain
and cultivation of a capable workforce can occur
quickly enough to offset the impacts on employment
of declines in low-cost exports and a slowing construction sector. What is clear is that unique challenges
stand in Beijing’s way of doing so.
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 18
Comparing Exports and Household Consumption
Exports as a percentage of GDP by selected years
China
1980
1990
2000
2013
Japan
1980
1990
2000
2013
South
Korea
1980
1990
2000
2013
United
States
1980
1990
2000
2013
6.0%
15.9%
20.7%
23.3%
13.4%
10.3%
10.9%
16.2%
30.2%
25.9%
35.0%
53.9%
9.8%
9.2%
10.7%
13.5%
Household consumption as a percentage of GDP by selected years
China
Japan
1980
1990
2000
2013
50.6%
47.8%
47.4%
36.0%
1980
1990
2000
2013
South
Korea
1980
1990
2000
2013
United
States
1980
1990
2000
2013
Source: World Bank
54.8%
53.3%
56.5%
61.1%
65.8%
55.3%
53.6%
50.9%
61.3%
64.0%
66.0%
68.6%
Copyright Stratfor 2016 www.stratfor.com
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 19
In the decades following World War II, Japan helped
create a clear international division of labor, enabling
it to grow its way out of poverty through exports
to mainly American consumers. In time, as rising
costs pressed Japan to advance toward higher value-added industry, South Korea and Taiwan took
its place at the bottom of the international division
of labor. Critically, this process coincided with the
gradual de-industrialization of the U.S. economy and
the movement of the United States’ workforce into
service-oriented sectors.
All of this worked because of the progressive industrialization of the East Asian developmental states and
the U.S. economy’s shift toward services and consumption. The size of the American consumer market was
such that even as China entered at the bottom of the
supply chain in the early 1990s, pushing South Korea,
Taiwan and Japan further up, there was still no shortage of demand.
Today, as China struggles to carve out its own place in
the global market for high-tech and advanced manufactured goods (all the while trying to retain its grip on
low-cost export sectors), it is unclear whether global
market demand is, or soon will be, sufficient to absorb
future Chinese output. China may simply be too large
a producer — and the United States, Europe and other
advanced economies too small of consumers — to
follow the pattern established by Japan, South Korea
and Taiwan exactly.
Of course, the Chinese government is aware of the
pitfalls of relying too much on demand to drive the
economy’s shift from low to high value-added manufacturing. Beijing’s decision to highlight and accelerate
financial reforms in the second half of 2015 suggests
as much. Instead, by relaxing controls on the yuan,
instituting programs such as depositor insurance and a
strong social safety net, and accelerating urbanization
in the interior of the country, the government intends
to cultivate a domestic consumer base sufficient to ab-
sorb more of what Chinese industry produces. But doing so on a scale sufficient to underpin nationwide economic growth will be extraordinarily difficult. Though
it is growing, private household consumption in China
still accounts for just 36.5 percent of gross domestic
product. This is extremely weak compared to other export-intensive economies such as Germany, Japan and
South Korea, all of which boast consumption-to-GDP
ratios higher than 50 percent. Cultivating strong and
sustainable household consumption takes time, and in
China’s case it will require significant financial reforms
aimed at improving the confidence and financial power of Chinese citizens.
In following the export-led growth model pioneered
by Japan, South Korea and Taiwan, China’s size presents problems. Certainly these countries have suffered
setbacks and crises as they developed economically.
Japan, in particular, has struggled to free itself from the
constraining institutional legacies of its developmental
past. But none faced quite the same web of challenges
that China does: to cultivate an advanced manufacturing-based economy grounded in high levels of
human capital (and correspondingly high wages) while
creating the high-income consumer base necessary to
sustain that economy. Where Japan, South Korea and
Taiwan could look to the American consumer to help
them climb up the value chain, China must look first
and foremost to itself.
For China, 2016 is only the beginning of this long and
likely arduous process. In the years to come, China will
have little recourse but to rely on other countries to
consume the increasingly advanced goods it produces;
its safest bet is to beat out South Korea and Taiwan on
price if not quality. In the meantime, China’s leaders
will do what they can to roll out reforms and initiatives that they hope will begin to generate the kind of
domestic consumption the country desperately needs.
However, this will almost certainly come at the cost
of full employment. The question is whether China’s
political structure can bear the social consequences. n
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 20
A man flies a kite in Shanghai despite heavy smog, which causes traffic problems, health issues
and school closures in the city.(ChinaFotoPress/Getty Images)
WHAT KIND OF
POWER WILL
CHINA BECOME?
I
n times like these, it is tempting to embrace visions of irreversible decline — just as it was easy,
in the expansive years of consistently high growth,
to view China’s rise as straightforward and inevitable.
As Stratfor pointed out well before the 2008-09 global
financial crisis, which set in motion many of the policies and processes that underlie China’s current woes,
the only certainty in the high-growth years was that
they would someday end. Their ending, we predicted,
would unleash tremendous and potentially destabilizing social pressures long kept at bay by the promise of
universal employment and rising material prosperity.
At the least, this process would slow China’s political,
military and economic rise as the decade ends. At
worst, it would send China into a more debilitating
and longer-lasting period of crisis and fragmentation.
It is crucial to remember that international politics, defined as it is by the rise and fall of great powers, follows
rhythms very different from and often far slower than
those of international markets and media. The rise of
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 21
great powers is never a clear-cut process, as the vicissitudes of European politics from the Treaty of Westphalia to the Paris Peace Conference make clear. Even
for the United States — as inevitable a modern great
power as any — the path to international pre-eminence was pockmarked by numerous economic crises
and profound domestic social and political tension.
We will now step back and look at China’s trajectory
in the early 21st century. While we can anticipate with
some certainty that the coming years will be difficult
for China’s economy and political system, the question remains: What kind of power will China be if
and when it emerges on the other side of its current
troubles? After all, there are many reasons to expect
that in 10 or 15 years, China will be a greater, not a
lesser, power than it is today: It has the world’s largest (and still growing) consumer market, an increasingly urbanized and educated workforce more than
twice the size of the United States’ total population,
an industrial sector pushing ever closer to the world
technological frontier, a large (if insufficient) domestic
natural resource base, and powerful and sophisticated
governing institutions.
What Kind of Great Power?
The question is what kind of great power China will
be. Will it become, to use Henry Kissinger’s term, a
revolutionary power bent on overturning the regional
and global political status quo? Will it be forced by
the systemic uncertainty of an anarchic international
order to go on the offensive in maximizing its share of
world power — a process that, as the political scientist
John J. Mearsheimer argues, will inevitably bring it
into conflict with the United States? Or will China,
as many in the tradition of “defensive realism” rooted
in the ideas of Kenneth Waltz argue, strive only for
enough power to ensure adequate security and thereafter adopt a defensive stance? Needless to say, how
we answer these questions will in large part determine
how we view the future of international politics, in
East Asia and globally.
The aim of this essay is not to provide a definitive
judgment on China’s trajectory but rather to weigh the
forces — both material and ideological — that will
shape how China’s leaders view and act within their
evolving geopolitical environment. To gather clues to
the kind of power China might become, we first look
to China’s past — to the Sinocentric world order over
which it dominated until the mid-19th century and to
the strategies with which successive dynasties built and
maintained that order. Having established the kind
of power China was before its entry into the modern
international system, we can better judge whether and
to what extent the worldview and strategies adopted
by its dynastic rulers can function in a world characterized by very different pressures, both systemic and
domestic.
The Sinocentric World Order
China is unique among historical great powers in
having presided over a legitimate and remarkably
stable regional order for nearly two millennia. If the
defining features of modern international politics are
the persistence of anarchy — that is, absence of world
government — and the dynamic of “balance of power”
generated by this anarchy, then the Chinese dynastic
world order was marked, first and foremost, by strong
elements of anarchy’s structural obverse: hierarchy.
Thanks in large part to its overwhelming demographic
heft, its technological and bureaucratic sophistication,
and often but not always its military superiority, China
was the unquestioned center of gravity in East Asia
for most of the period from 221 B.C. to A.D. 1842.
This material superabundance relative to that of other
regional powers was, in turn, powerfully reinforced
by the pull of China’s civilizational pre-eminence. So
great was China’s power and influence relative to all
other premodern East Asian polities that even when
invaded by outsiders — such as the Mongols in 1271,
the Manchu in 1644 and, unsuccessfully, the Japanese
in 1592 — China remained central. Beijing, not the
ancestral lands of Genghis Khan or of the Manchurian
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 22
China’s Slowing Economic Growth
Real gross domestic product growth, measured by percent change year-over-year, adjusted for inflation.
15%
10%
5%
2015
2013
2011
2009
2007
2005
2003
2001
1999
1997
1995
1993
1991
1989
1987
1985
1983
0%
Housing starts by floor space, measured by percent change year-over-year.
80%
60%
40%
20%
0%
−20%
Source: NBS, Stratfor calculations
leader Nurhaci, served as the political capital for the
Yuan and Qing dynasties.
In Western Europe, the relative parity in economic
and military power among Spain, Britain, Austria,
France and later Germany ultimately gave way to an
international system grounded in the formal equality
Jan. 15
Jan. 14
Jan. 13
Jan. 12
Jan. 11
Jan. 10
Jan. 09
Jan. 08
Jan. 07
Jan. 06
Jan. 05
Jan. 04
Jan. 03
Jan. 02
Jan. 01
−40%
Copyright Stratfor 2016 www.stratfor.com
and mutually recognized sovereignty of independent
nation-states. By contrast, Sinocentric East Asia was
formally unequal, with the autonomy of lesser states
(especially those closest, culturally and geographically, to China) often contingent on their acceptance of
Chinese supremacy.
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 23
Just as Confucianism, the dominant political philosophy in dynastic China, envisioned domestic society as
a more or less rigid hierarchy of asymmetric social roles
— emperor and vassal, husband and wife, father and
son — so China’s rulers saw themselves as sitting at the
apex of a world order (tianxia, literally “all under heaven”), in which non-Chinese states were merely extensions of the emperor’s heavenly mandate. That China
viewed its world and external relations not in terms of
anarchy and sovereign competition but of hierarchy
and filial harmony is most clearly seen in the system of
“tribute” through which it managed interstate trade.
Growing out of an earlier program of direct taxes
on defeated neighboring polities, the tribute system
imagined international trade as simply the exchange of
gifts between the emperor, as world sovereign, and his
many kingly vassals.
What is most striking about this highly inegalitarian
order, from the perspective of modern world politics, is
how persuasive and stable it proved. To be sure, China’s
history is littered with war and devastation. But most of
this devastation resulted from internal political upheaval and civil war, not from foreign invasion. Likewise, it
must be emphasized that in periods of dynastic decline
within China, tributary relations — and the acknowledgement of Chinese supremacy that underpinned
them — often became mere glosses on what was, in
substance, international trade among autonomous
states. Even so, the periodic superficiality of China’s
regional authority notwithstanding, it is noteworthy
that for hundreds of years, non-Chinese states conducted their business with China as well as independent
of China in the language and terms of the Sinocentric
tribute system. The historical record suggests that for
long periods, the states of Korea and Vietnam, and to
a lesser extent Japan and polities in Central and Southeast Asia, often accepted, however grudgingly, their
place as subordinate cogs in a Sinocentric order.
All of which begs the question: How did successive
dynasties maintain the coherence and stability of the
Chinese world order?
The overwhelming impression given by the bulk of
historical scholarship on pre-modern China’s foreign
relations, as well as by official dynastic histories, is that
generally the Chinese empire sustained its regional
pre-eminence through civilizational and economic
“soft power,” while adopting a defensive military posture and conservative grand strategy. Rather than move
aggressively to expand control over neighboring states,
this traditional interpretation holds that the Chinese
empire sustained its pride of place primarily through
its civilizational and commercial pull. Sheer demographic and economic size made China an invaluable
market for foreign traders, access to which was contingent on the recognition of China’s primacy. Meanwhile, its sophisticated bureaucratic and philosophical-literary traditions naturally made China a model to
be emulated by smaller, weaker states. Together, these
advantages meant that China only rarely had to resort
to force to secure its interests — and then only to rectify morally degraded, illegitimate or renegade regimes.
Not surprisingly, this interpretation coheres closely
with Confucianism’s systematic denigration of military
aggression and celebration of the more “pacific” arts of
the civilian scholar-official.
However, alongside Confucian China’s peaceful and
defensive orientation ran another strand of decidedly
more assertive strategic behavior. Consider, for example, several episodes in the external relations of Ming
China, the last Chinese-ruled dynasty and by most
accounts one of the most consciously Confucian of
China’s imperial houses. In the century and a half after
coming to power, Ming China invaded and annexed
Vietnam, led a series of large-scale punitive campaigns
deep into inner Asia to pre-empt any future threats
to its northern border, and launched several waves of
“treasure fleets” throughout Southeast and South Asia
in calculated and often openly coercive displays of
Chinese military might. On at least three occasions,
these fleets — loaded with upward of 27,000 soldiers
— were used to forcibly remove local kings perceived
to have disobeyed Ming authority.
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 24
Such assertions of military and political might are by
no means unique to the Ming. Nor was it China’s most
expansive dynasty, militarily speaking. Indeed, Ming
China is perhaps best known for building the current Great Wall — that potent symbol of traditional
China’s purportedly defensive and stabilizing strategic
posture. It would be wrong to deny that for much of
its history — especially but not only during times of
relative military weakness or dynastic decline — China
has behaved defensively, working to bolster the status
quo rather than to destabilize it. After all, China never
seriously sought to expand far beyond what are today
its recognized borders, despite manifold opportunities
to do so. Nonetheless, it is clear that despite successive
dynasties’ efforts to write pacifism and “virtue” into
China’s foreign relations, China has often — especially
during times of military and political dominance over
neighboring states — behaved in ways that belie its
pacifist self-image.
From Sinocentrism to
Chinese Exceptionalism
It is possible, but not likely, that these twin legacies —
the conservative and defensive versus the assertive and
expansive — will have no bearing on China’s foreign
policy in years to come, as the country’s deepening
global economic integration and expanding international interests compel it to adopt a more proactive
diplomatic and military posture. Material capabilities,
combined with the disposing and constraining forces
of the international system, may be the key determinants of whether a great power is more or less active
on the world stage. But while these factors tell us what
kinds of pressures great powers face and give us some
sense of how able they are to overcome those pressures,
they do not tell us the means by which great powers
will strive to do so. Ideas about the world matter: They
shape how political and military elite filter, interpret
and make sense of the ever-shifting inputs on which
they base their decisions. In a country as intensely
aware of its own oracular history as China, the effect of
inherited ideas on contemporary foreign policy cannot
be discounted.
With this in mind, it is worth noting the emergence in
recent years of an active, if still somewhat nascent, discourse of exceptionalism among Chinese policy elite.
Invocations of China’s “difference” and “singularity”
(to use Kissinger’s term) move in multiple directions,
sometimes referring to the incomparable magnitude of
China’s domestic economic challenges or the uniqueness of its particular social and political fissures. More
often than not, however, and especially when evoked
by Chinese leaders, this sense of exceptionalism is
explicitly tied to the notion of China’s peaceful rise.
More pointedly, it is drawn on to express the idea that
China, thanks to its legacy as a benign and inclusive
rather than aggressively expansionist hegemon in
pre-modern East Asia, will not seek, as so many other
modern great powers have, to remake the status quo in
its own favor. China, they contend, is an exception to
the modern international rule that as great powers rise,
they invariably seek to impose their will on the international system, as well as on the individual states that
compose it.
Whether China’s future leaders can make good on
this promise remains to be seen. The fact is that until
relatively recently, China has lacked the sort of thickly
interwoven international interests and dependencies
that might necessitate a more far-reaching, assertive
foreign policy. More to the point, it has lacked the
military capabilities and political wherewithal to act
to protect, in any systematic manner, its international
interests. On both fronts, this is beginning to change.
So, too, is China’s understanding of its external interests and responsibilities, at least as reflected in recent
moves to assert its territorial claims in the South and
East China seas and early efforts to built blue water-capable naval forces.
But even if China’s long history of defensive and
status quo-promoting behavior fails to preclude it
from acting like a more conventional great power in
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 25
the years to come, this does not, in itself, render that
legacy meaningless. In this respect, it is instructive to
consider the role that ideas have played in shaping the
foreign policy of another heir to a vivid exceptionalist
discourse: the United States. Far from a mere cover for
power-political interests, the idea of the United States
as exceptional — whether as an exemplar for other
countries or as an active agent in the spread of democracy worldwide — has played an important role in
shaping how the nation wielded material resources.
As China’s wealth and military power grow, as they
likely will in the long run, the anarchic structure of
the international system will push China to use this
power to improve its security and the safety of its
increasingly far-flung interests and assets. The question
is not whether China will be forced to respond to these
systemic pressures, but how it will attempt to adapt the
lessons of its history to cope with the risks and uncertainties of a very different kind of world order from
that it so long dominated. n
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 26
Chinese President Xi Jinping and other top leaders attend a plenary session of the National
People's Congress in March 2013. (FENG LI/Getty Images)
BRIDGING THE
GAP BETWEEN
CHINA’S CENTRAL
AND LOCAL
GOVERNMENTS
T
o explain the conflict of interest between the
central and local governments in contemporary China, one must first consider the
effects of the country’s regional geographic, cultural
and economic diversity on its rulers. China cannot
be understood as a monolith. For much of its history,
it has operated as a collection of regional clusters —
nine “macro-regions,” according to historian William
Skinner’s model of late imperial China — with diverse
geographies and resources, distinct cultural and linguistic traditions, and disparate economic needs and
political interests.
This diversity has created political challenges for
China’s central rulers throughout history. More than
just a barrier to central coordination and oversight,
however, regional diversity has informed rulers’ strategies to manage a unified China. Over successive
generations of central rulers, these strategies have been
based on distrust of regional and provincial administrations. Throughout the period since the 1949 Communist victory, central leadership has viewed regional
and provincial governments as potential obstacles in
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 27
communicating with and, by extension, managing
local societies.
A Lesson Learned
Distrust of intermediate administration is by no means
unique to modern China. As historian Mark Edward
Lewis observes, the denigration of regional identities
and customs was central to the Qin and Han dynasties’
campaigns to legitimize their regimes across the vast
empire. The concept of the region as a threat to the
imperial system became embedded in the literary and
philosophical traditions through which subsequent
dynasties represented the Chinese state. Regional and
subregional governments were seen as dubious units
of territorial administration, necessary but potentially dangerous components of the central government
that could break away from the empire if not properly
controlled. Consequently, preserving strong influence
over regional governments and restricting the autonomy and authority of lower governments became core
features of central administration.
This lesson was not lost on China’s modern rulers. It
undoubtedly helped justify both the Nationalist and
Communist parties’ turns to Leninism. But the push
to centralize power and to marginalize lower levels
of government, especially in a country as regionally
fragmented as China, has yielded unintended consequences. By over-centralizing political control without
fortifying local infrastructure, the Nationalist government undermined its hold on power, overwhelming
its own ability to administrate. More than once, the
excessive centralization of power has threatened to
do the same to the People’s Republic. In short, history attests — and the Communist Party’s occasional
attempts to delegate authority to local governments
confirm — that too much central control is as problematic as too little.
While the Nationalist and Communist propensity for
centralization certainly embodies the Leninist empha-
sis on central political authority, one finds striking similarities in the wider body of Chinese political thought
that also viewed regional and local administrations as
inconvenient and even harmful to central state interests throughout history. Both traditional and Leninist
conceptions of the Chinese state, including the perils
facing it and the administrative structure best poised to
ensure its survival, view lower levels of government as
a threat to central interests. As a result, local administrations are poorly institutionalized and often undisciplined, weakening the center’s influence on them.
Implementation
and Local Deviance
Unlike in the United States and other federal systems,
where sometimes-disparate policies are made and
implemented at the state and local levels, the Chinese
policymaking process has long been characterized by
centralization and uniformity. The central government
designs and decides on nearly all major policies. Because local conditions vary widely even across regions,
it is impractical to expect uniform implementation
of centrally devised national policies. As Beijing well
understands, effective implementation of its wishes
requires a degree of openness to local autonomy over
how policies are carried out.
This arrangement has positive and negative consequences for governance in China. On the one hand,
it helps mitigate the friction that inevitably arises
when policies made in Beijing are carried out across
regions and localities that share little in common with
the capital or with one another. On the other hand,
it makes pushing through important national reforms
exceedingly difficult. As Beijing attempts to move from
an economic model geared toward growth at whatever
cost to one that prioritizes goals such as work safety,
environmental protection and improved social services,
these obstacles to effective policy enforcement will take
on renewed political significance.
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 28
Major Regions of China’s Core
China’s size and geography often widen the gap between the interests
of the central government and those of local administrations.
MONGOLIA
Manchuria
Province borders
Macroregions
NORTH
KOREA
Beijing
Northwest
China
North
China
East China
Sea
Xi’an
Chengdu
Upper
Yangtze
Yungui
INDIA
MYANMAR
150 mi
Middle
Yangtze
Lower Shanghai
Yangtze
Southeast
Coast
Lingnan
VIETNAM
LAOS
Wuhan
TAIWAN
Hong
Kong
300 mi
Copyright Stratfor 2016 www.stratfor.com
In many ways, the policy trends that defined China
during the first two decades of Reform and Opening
trace back to the fundamental tension between uniform central policymaking and flexible local policy
implementation. In the 1980s, Beijing decentralized
fiscal and administrative powers, substantially improving the autonomy and power of provinces and localities. Though decentralization may have been necessary
to preserve political integrity and spur economic
rejuvenation in the wake of the Cultural Revolution,
it nonetheless generated new pressures that, by the
late 1980s, threatened to undermine the Communist Party’s grip on power. In response, the central
government recentralized power in the early 1990s.
Remarkably, the central-local gap persisted largely
unabated under decentralization and recentralization
alike, continuing through the 2000s and into the era
of President Xi Jinping.
The unshakable local deviation from central government mandates reflects China’s size and regional
diversity. Furthermore, that the gap has endured both
hyper-centralized and relatively decentralized political
conditions suggests a problem not only in the central
government’s level of authority but also in its structure. If anything, the past 30 years of political reform
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 29
should dictate that the current political structure,
with its high degree of formal central control and
informal local autonomy, inherently limits the central
bureaucracy’s ability to monitor local activities, the
enormous improvements in the state’s surveillance
technologies notwithstanding.
Unfortunately, as China’s export sector stagnates and
construction activity slows, Beijing cannot afford to
continue as it has with regard to local government. As
the economy slows, ensuring good — or at least better
— governance at the local level will become politically
imperative, not least because sluggish growth will force
the party to justify its continued rule anew: Economic doldrums and poor governance do not make for
social tranquility.
The gap between central and local interests, and the
government’s persistent inability to bridge it, perhaps
explains past Chinese rulers’ attention to what Mao
called “correct thought.” If local officials cannot be
monitored or controlled effectively through professional incentives, then perhaps the best option is to
strive for control over their minds. This, after all, was
not Mao’s idea; its roots run to the very foundations of
Chinese dynastic statecraft. n
This report cannot be shared or copied without express permission from Stratfor. For pricing, contact us: https://www.stratfor.com/contact
STRATFOR • 30
Your world.
In context.
As the world’s leading geopolitical intelligence platform, Stratfor brings global
events into valuable perspective, empowering businesses, governments and
individuals to more confidently navigate their way through an increasingly
complex international environment.
Globally engaged individuals
and organizations join Stratfor
Worldview for objective
geopolitical intelligence and
analysis that reveals the
underlying significance and
future implications of
emerging world events.
Our premium Stratfor Threat
Lens™ product helps
corporate security leaders
anticipate, identify, measure,
and mitigate risks that
emerging threats pose to
their people, assets, and
interests around the world.
Stratfor Advisory Services
provide global enterprises
predictive, customized
intelligence assessments that
uncover key opportunities and
pinpoint hidden risks associated
with their strategic planning and
critical investment decisions.
www.stratfor.com
www.stratfor.com/threat-lens
www.stratfor.com/enterprise
P.O Box 92529 Austin, Texas 78709-2529
T: + 1-512-744-4300
F: + 1-512-744-4105