Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
House Price Cycles and the Real Economy DENIZ IGAN IMF – RESEARCH LIME WORKSHOP BRUSSELS - DECEMBER 8, 2012 Disclaimer: Views expressed in the presentation and during the talk are those of the presenter and should not be ascribed to the IMF. Background Work The Changing Housing Cycle and the Implications for Monetary Policy – Chapter 3 in WEO April 2008 Housing, Credit, and Real Activity Cycles: Characteristics and Comovement – JHE 2011 (revision of Three Cycles: Housing, Credit, and Real Activity, IMF WP 09/231) Global Housing Cycles – IMF WP forthcoming Early Warning Exercise – conducted twice a year Outline Research questions Relevant literature (briefly) Preview of results Methodology and data (briefly) Results Conclusions and policy implications Research Questions How similar are the cycles: in duration, amplitude, etc.? How do the cycles relate to the interest rate changes? Are the cycles synchronized, or does one lead the others? How important are global versus local factors? What are the policy implications? Literature—Domestic Context Bank credit, house prices and aggregate demand tend to move in tandem Financial accelerator effects through external finance premium and collateral prices result in procyclicality of bank credit Bernanke and Gertler, 1989; Kiyotaki and Moore, 1997 Liquidity and leverage of banks also contribute Adrian and Shin (2008), Berger and Bouwman (2008) Liquidity of housing wealth and availability of housing financing can also alter the relationship through consumption and investment Literature—International Context The degree of synchronization in real and financial cycles increased Kose, Prasad and Terrones, 2003; Imbs, 2004; Otrok and Terrones, 2005 International comovement in house prices may reflect comovement of interest rates Especially with debt-financed ownership and adjustablerate mortgages Global liquidity may have also contributed Belke and Orth, 2008 Literature—Monetary Policy Transmission through the credit channel and the housing market Monetary policy, credit and asset prices Benign neglect: Monetary policy is not an effective tool for targeting asset prices, so better not to prick the bubble but mop up afterwards (Bernanke, Gertler, and Gilchrist, 1999) Leaning against the wind: Monetary policy needs to play a more proactive role to prevent financial bubbles (Borio and Lowe, 2002, and Borio, 2006) Contribution of This Paper Multidirectional links Goodhart and Hofman (2008) Focus on output, bank credit, house prices (as well as residential investment) and interest rates Descriptive approach GDFM as opposed to VAR Data properties Unit root tests Filtering as opposed to differencing Different horizons Short to medium term (6 to 16 quarters) Long term (16 to 32 quarters) Preview of Results House price cycles lead credit and business cycles over the long run Interest rates tend to lag other cycles at all horizons Country cycles are largely driven by global factors the role of which has increased over time, especially for credit and business cycles U.S. cycles tend to lead other countries’ respective cycles Generalized Dynamic Factor Model Identifies a common component using a large number of series Builds on the traditional factor models Sargent and Sims (1977) and Geweke (1977) By allowing for serial correlation and weakly cross-sectional correlation of idiosyncratic components Chamberlain (1983) and Chamberlain and Rothschild (1983) Recent examples Giannone, Reichlin, and Sala (2002) Forni and others (2005) Eickmeier (2007) (Approximate) GDFM Yt X t t where Yt is a (N x T) vector stochastic stationary process with zero mean and unit variance and Xt and Ξt are (N x T) vectors of common and idiosyncratic components, respectively. Xt can be written as: Yt CFt t where Ft is a (r x T) vector of common factors and C is a (N x r) matrix of factor loadings. The model has N>>T and r<<N. The common factors assumed to follow an AR(1) process: Ft BFt 1 ut , with B and (r x r) matrix and ut a (r x T) vector of residuals. Measures of Comovement The dynamic correlation varies between -1 and 1. Formally, where the numerator is the cospectrum between y1 and y2 processes at frequency λ and S (y1) and S (y2) are the spectral density functions of the processes at frequency λ defined over –π and π. Coherence is intrinsically related to dynamic correlation given by: Coherence is symmetric and a real number between 0 and 1. Lead-Lag Relationship The phase angle between processes helps identify the lead-lag relationship where q (y1 y2) is the quadrature spectrum. Only when K (y1y2) ≠0, the phase angle converges in distribution to a normal random variable. Panel Data 18 industrial countries 1981 Q1 to 2006 Q4 1,283 series Real activity indicators Consumption Investment, including residential International trade Confidence indicators Portfolio and FDI flows Financial variables Credit to the private sector and other monetary aggregates Short-term and long-term interest rates House prices and stock prices Balance sheet data Household savings and assets (in particular, housing stock) Capital stock of business sector Unit Root Tests ERS (Elliott, Rothenberg and Stock, 1996) Generalized least squares More powerful than standard Dickey-Fuller test KPSS (Kwiatowski, Phillips, Schmidt and Shin, 1992) Cross check Stationarity as H0 instead of unit root Constant and deterministic trend Lags chosen based on the Schwarz information criterion Results of Unit Root Tests House prices are sometimes I(2) France, Ireland, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Sweden and the United States Credit series are also I(2) in some cases Japan and Spain Over-differencing versus under-differencing Unit Root Tests (Details) Table 1. Unit Root Tests ERS Australia Austria I(1) I(1) Output Decision in Cases of Conflicting KPSS Evidence I(1) ERS I(1) I(1) 2 I(1) 1, 5 I(2) Residential Investment Decision in Cases of Conflicting ERS KPSS Evidence I(0) I(1) I(1) I(1)2 ERS Credit Decision in Cases of Conflicting KPSS Evidence I(1) I(1) I(1) I(0) I(1) I(1) I(2) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) Belgium I(0) I(1) Canada I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) Denmark Finland France I(1) I(0) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(2) I(1) I(1) I(2) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(2) I(2) I(1) I(2) I(2) Germany I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) Ireland I(1) I(2) Italy I(1) I(1) Japan I(1) I(2) Netherlands I(1) I(1) I(1) House Prices Decision in Cases of Conflicting KPSS Evidence I(1) 1 I(1) I(1)1 I(1) I(2) I(0) I(2) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(2) I(1)1, 5 I(2)1, 5 I(1) I(1) I(1) I(2) 1, 5 I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) 1 I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(2) I(2) 1 I(1) I(1) 2 I(1) I(1) I(0) I(2) I(2) I(2) I(1) I(2) I(2)1 I(0) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1)1, 5 I(2) I(0) 1, 5 I(2) 1, 5 I(0) I(1) New Zealand I(1) I(1) I(1) I(2) I(2) I(0) I(1) Norway I(1) I(1) I(1) I(2) I(2)1, 5 I(1) I(1) Spain I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) Switzerland I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(2) United Kingdom United States I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(2) I(1) I(2) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1) I(1)4 I(2)5 Source: Authors' estimates. Notes: The table reports the results of two unit root tests: ERS (Elliott, Rothenberg, and Stock, 1996) and KPSS (Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt, and Shin, 1992). All tests were done including a constant and a trend. The number of lags was chosen using the Schwarz criterion and ensuring that no serial correlation is left in the residuals. Highlighting in the table identifies the cases where the two tests rendered conflticting results. In such cases, unit root tests were also done excluding a constant and trend, and graphical evidence was examined particularly closely. Output is the real GDP as calculated by the IMF's International Financial Statistics , house prices are expressed in real terms by deflating the nominal house price indices by CPI, credit is bank credit to the private sector deflated by CPI. 1. The charts do suggest that stationarity is only achieved at the specified differenced series. 2. The ERS test barely passes the confidence level. 3. Schwarz criterion suggests taking 3 lags and there is no SC either with 1 or 2 lags. Three lags suggest I(1). 4. The KPSS test barely passes the confidence level. In addition, observation of the series suggests that it contains a unit root. 5. When the ERS test on first differences does reject the I(1) null, a relatively higher error of type I is assumed for KPSS test (1 percent). Band-Pass Filter Corbae and Ouliaris (2006) ideal band-pass filter Passes through the components of time series with periodic fluctuations between 6 and 32 quarters (in line with widely used minor-major cycle lengths) Consistent No finite sampling error Not subject to end-point problems Advantages of Filtering over Differencing Figure 1 - United States: Spectra of Real GDP Filtered (Y axis: spectrum; X axis: periodicities in quarters) 1,4 0,00025 1,2 0,0002 1 0,00015 0,8 0,6 0,0001 0,4 0,00005 0,2 0 In fin ite 64 ,0 32 ,0 21 ,3 16 ,0 12 ,8 10 ,7 9, 1 8, 0 7, 1 6, 4 5, 8 5, 3 4, 9 4, 6 4, 3 4, 0 3, 8 3, 6 3, 4 3, 2 3, 0 2, 9 2, 8 2, 7 2, 6 2, 5 2, 4 2, 3 2, 2 2, 1 2, 1 0 GDP Ideal Band Pass, Corbae-Ouliaris Filter GDP First Differenced (RHS) Wrong data transformation may introduce a downward bias in the degree of economic integration and an upward bias in the efficiency of uncoordinated macroeconomic policies. Table 2. Variance Shares Average M aximum M inimum Standard deviation Coefficient of variation Variance share exceeding 20 p ercent Differenced Series Filtered Series 0.07 0.18 0.01 0.04 0.62 0.03 0.31 0.70 0.01 0.17 0.55 0.68 Source: Authors' estimates. Notes: The table rep orts the variance shares of common comp onents for two alternative way s of data treatment - first differencing and filtering using the ideal band p ass filter. The series included in this illustrative exercise are outp ut, house p rices, credit, short- and long-term interest rates. The last row shows the number of series, in p ercent of the total number of series, for which the variance share exp lained by the common comp onents of the included series exceeds 20 p ercent. Characteristics of Cycles Credit and house price cycles tend to be slightly more protracted on average than business cycles... but peaks and troughs generally are not too far. Credit and house price cycles have larger swings than real activity cycles). In some countries, there are significant differences across these characteristics… Countries that allow MEW and refinancing tend to have larger amplitude and longer duration in house price cycles relative to the business cycle if the share of variable rate mortgages is large (e.g., New Zealand versus Germany). Characteristics of Cycles Procyclicality Financial accelerator model is not empirically supported in all countries—correlations vary in significance and sign. Collateral is a driver of procyclicality more than lending is—stronger correlation between output and house prices than between output and bank credit. Procyclicality Table 5. Correlation Coefficients for Total Cyclical Components Output-House Prices Output-Credit Output-Residential Investment Credit-House Prices Credit-Residential Investment House PricesResidential Investment Australia Austria Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany Ireland Italy Japan Netherlands New Zealand Norway Spain Switzerland United Kingdom United States 0.55 0.74 0.72 0.70 0.46 0.89 0.59 0.28 0.53 0.37 0.45 -0.14 0.51 0.54 0.74 0.36 0.85 0.13 0.69 0.82 0.79 0.63 0.62 0.40 0.73 -0.31 0.81 0.19 0.46 0.69 0.17 -0.09 0.61 0.11 0.69 0.59 0.65 -0.04 0.67 0.50 0.38 0.87 0.70 0.50 0.50 0.45 0.43 0.44 0.79 0.20 0.75 0.26 0.73 0.50 0.36 0.75 0.85 0.77 0.60 0.53 0.33 -0.02 0.54 0.25 0.73 -0.03 0.44 -0.10 0.25 0.17 0.74 0.37 0.26 0.02 0.67 0.30 0.48 0.67 0.28 -0.36 0.37 0.44 0.35 0.59 0.08 -0.20 0.24 -0.06 0.45 0.21 0.76 -0.40 0.83 0.70 0.58 0.93 0.51 0.28 0.14 0.50 -0.07 0.32 0.65 0.59 0.76 0.45 0.78 0.51 Mean 0.52 0.48 0.52 0.42 0.27 0.49 Source: Authors' estimates. Notes: The table reports the correlation coefficients for the total cyclical component of output (real GDP), house prices, residential investment, and credit series, over the entire sample period. For each pair listed in the column title, entries in the table show the correlation between the series over the whole sample period. Correlation coefficients larger than 0.40 are deemed to be significant and are highlighted. Common Components A large share of common components drive the three cycles. The share of the common component in GDP and in credit has increased over time. The importance of common shocks and/or the speed of transmission of shocks has increased over time. Common Components GDP Common component Total cyclical movement 0.05 0.03 GERMANY UNITED STATES 0.04 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.03 -0.02 -0.04 -0.05 1981Q1 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 0.03 -0.03 1981Q1 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 0.04 UNITED KINGDOM JAPAN 0.03 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.03 1981Q1 -0.02 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 -0.03 1981Q1 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 Common Components Credit Common component Total cyclical movement 0.05 0.10 UNITED STATES 0.04 GERMANY 0.08 0.06 0.03 0.04 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.02 -0.01 -0.04 -0.02 -0.06 -0.03 -0.08 -0.04 1981Q1 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 0.06 -0.10 1981Q1 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 0.04 UNITED KINGDOM JAPAN 0.03 0.04 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.04 -0.04 -0.06 1981Q1 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 -0.05 1981Q1 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 Common Components House prices Common component Total cyclical movement 0.03 0.02 UNITED STATES GERMANY 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.00 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.02 -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 -0.03 1981Q1 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 0.20 -0.03 1981Q1 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 0.08 UNITED KINGDOM JAPAN 0.06 0.15 0.04 0.10 0.02 0.05 0.00 -0.02 0.00 -0.04 -0.05 -0.10 1981Q1 -0.06 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 1997Q1 2001Q1 2005Q1 -0.08 1981Q1 1985Q1 1989Q1 1993Q1 Evolution of Common Components Table 7. Evolution of Cyclical Movements Driven by Common Components 1980s Output 1990s House Prices 1980s 1990s 2000s Residential Investment 1980s 1990s 2000s 2000s Australia Austria Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany Ireland Italy Japan Netherlands New Zealand Norway Spain Switzerland United Kingdom United States 0.82 0.30 0.90 0.85 0.08 0.79 0.43 0.67 0.76 0.89 0.72 0.72 0.16 0.56 0.60 0.84 0.90 0.78 0.84 0.72 0.89 0.92 0.63 0.81 0.82 0.66 0.85 0.79 0.71 0.84 0.90 0.18 0.88 0.73 0.92 0.56 0.64 0.91 0.97 0.91 0.66 0.95 0.95 0.81 0.93 0.91 0.93 0.96 0.90 0.50 0.95 0.95 0.70 0.90 0.63 0.59 0.90 0.89 0.68 0.65 0.20 0.33 0.57 0.26 0.64 0.21 0.80 0.62 0.70 0.81 0.84 0.85 0.60 0.90 0.78 0.62 0.59 0.82 0.62 0.65 0.76 0.79 0.65 0.85 0.84 0.87 0.85 0.86 0.74 0.62 0.35 0.54 0.92 0.74 0.87 0.82 0.69 -0.02 0.90 0.92 0.21 0.11 0.53 0.53 0.83 0.59 0.78 0.42 0.45 0.84 0.88 0.77 0.70 0.65 0.86 0.79 0.73 0.68 0.76 0.79 -0.16 0.83 0.75 0.62 0.66 0.19 0.74 0.09 0.84 0.35 0.71 0.85 0.90 0.18 0.81 0.56 0.61 0.31 0.64 0.89 0.75 0.58 0.54 0.67 Mean Median 0.65 0.74 0.77 0.83 0.87 0.92 0.60 0.65 0.71 0.77 0.58 0.64 0.63 0.74 0.59 0.65 1980s Credit 1990s 2000s 0.62 0.81 0.90 0.46 0.69 0.94 0.94 0.49 0.70 0.66 0.82 0.86 0.84 0.31 0.86 0.57 0.51 0.73 0.90 0.49 0.81 0.89 0.55 0.68 0.40 0.38 0.91 0.67 0.31 0.63 0.78 0.39 0.21 0.40 0.86 0.80 0.85 0.91 0.91 0.87 0.60 0.79 0.25 0.57 0.84 0.35 0.67 0.87 0.67 0.34 0.80 0.27 0.71 0.51 0.87 0.89 0.89 0.92 0.90 0.91 0.82 0.53 0.94 0.88 0.69 0.96 0.84 0.67 0.83 0.59 0.91 0.87 0.68 0.72 0.60 0.60 0.66 0.69 0.84 0.88 Source: Authors' estimates. Notes: The table reports the correlation coefficients for the total cyclical components (including the common and idiosyncratic component, as shown in Figure 2) and the common components (shown in Figure 4). Leads and Lags During the minor cycle, house prices lead output and credit only in a few cases. In the long run, there is some support for financial accelerator mechanism, but which channel? balance sheet improvements -> credit -> house prices or house prices -> creditworthiness -> credit Short-term interest rates never lead house prices. House prices lead output, which in turn leads credit. U.S. cycles lead the corresponding cycles in the long run in most cases, and U.S. credit cycles lead only in the short run. Leads and Lags (Details - 1) Table 6. Leads and Lags between Cycles within Countries Credit-Output Credit-House Prices Credit-Residential Investment Output-House Prices Output-Residential Investment 6-16 quarters 16-32 quarters 6-16 quarters 16-32 quarters 6-16 quarters 16-32 quarters 6-16 quarters 16-32 quarters 6-16 quarters 16-32 quarters Australia Austria Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany Ireland Italy Japan Netherlands New Zealand Norway Spain Switzerland United Kingdom United States lag lead lag lag lead lag contemp. lead lead lead lag contemp. lag lead lag contemp. lead lead lag lag contemp. lag lead lag lag lead lead lag lead lead lag lead lag lead lag contemp. contemp. lead lag lag lead lag lag contemp. lead lead contemp. lag contemp. lead lag lag lag lag lag lead lag lag lag lag lag contemp. lead lag lead lag lag lead lag lead lag lag lag lag lag lag contemp. lag lag lead lag lag lag lag lag lead lag lead lag lag contemp. lag lag lag lag lag lag lead lag lead lag contemp. lag contemp. contemp. lag lag lag contemp. contemp. lag lag lag lag lag contemp. lead contemp. lead lag lead lag contemp. contemp. contemp. lag lag lead lag contemp. lag lag lag lag lead lead lead lag lead lead lag lag contemp. lag lag lag lag lag lag lead lag lead lag lead lag lag contemp. lead lag lag lag lag contemp. lag contemp. lag lag lag contemp. lag lag lead contemp. contemp. contemp. lead lead lag lag lag Lags Contemporaneous Leads 39 17 44 50 11 39 50 22 28 67 6 28 78 6 17 67 22 11 44 39 17 56 11 33 72 6 22 50 33 17 Source: Authors' estimates. Notes: The table reports the lead-lag relationship between pairs of series that are the focus of the analysis. Interest rates are nominal short-term rates. For each pair listed in the column title, entries in the table indicate whether the first variable leads or lags the second variable, or whether the relationship is contemporaneous, on average, over the frequency band. The numbers in the bottom indicate the percentage of countries with a given type of relation. Leads and lags are calculated using the approach suggested by Croux, Forni and Reichlin (2001). Leads and Lags (Details – 2) Table 8. Lead-Lag Relations between the United States and Other Countries Output House prices Residential Investment Credit Short-term interest rates 8-16 quarters 16-32 quarters 8-16 quarters 16-32 quarters 8-16 quarters 16-32 quarters 8-16 quarters 16-32 quarters 8-16 quarters 16-32 quarters Australia Austria Belgium Canada Denmark Finland France Germany Ireland Italy Japan Netherlands New Zealand Norway Spain Switzerland United Kingdom lag lead lead lag lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lag contemp. lead lead contemp. lag lead lead contemp. lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead contemp. lead lead lead contemp. lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lag lead lead lag lead lead lag lead lead lead contemp. contemp. lead lead contemp. lead lead lag contemp. lead lead lag lead lag lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lag lead contemp. lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lag lead lead lead lead contemp. contemp. contemp. contemp. contemp. lead lead contemp. lead contemp. lead lead contemp. contemp. lead contemp. contemp. lead lead lead lead contemp. lead lead lag lead lead lead lead lead lag lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead contemp. lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead lead contemp. lead lead lead lead Lags Contemporaneous Leads 18 12 71 6 18 76 18 0 82 18 24 59 6 6 88 6 0 94 0 65 35 12 6 82 0 0 100 0 12 88 Source: Authors' estimates. Notes: For each pair of countries and the variable, entries in the table indicate whether the cyclical component in the United States leads or lags the cyclical component in the respective country listed in the first column, or whether the relationship is contemporaneous, on average, over the frequency band. The numbers in the bottom indicate the percentage of countries with a given type of relation. Leads and lags are calculated using the approach suggested by Croux, Forni and Reichlin (2001). Conclusions House price cycles lead other cycles in the long run Interest rates tend to lag other cycles at all horizons Global factors are important for all cycles, especially for credit and real activity in the latter part of the sample period U.S. leads other countries in all cycles Similar conclusions from other research A six-variable VAR: real GDP, private consumption, residential investment, CPI inflation, the nominal (short term) interest rate and real house prices. 20 countries, sample from 1986-2009. House price shocks are identified with a Cholesky decomposition. In practice they look like “housing demand shocks” because they lead to a strong comovement between real house prices and residential investment. Alternative identification through sign restrictions. VAR delivers average responses, but there could be asymmetries between house price booms and busts. Impact on Real GDP of a 10% decline in real house prices 4 3 1.5 1 France 2 4 Spain 0.5 4 3 Australia 3 2 2 1 0 1 0 1 -0.5 0 -1 0 -1 -2 -4 -2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 4 2 United States 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 2.0 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 7 8 9 10 11 12 3 Netherlands 2 New Zealand 1 1.5 2 1 -3 0 2.5 4 3 -2 -2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 5 United Kingdom -1 -1 -1.5 -3 3 Korea 0 1.0 -1 0.5 -2 0 0 -1 -2 -1 -3 0.0 -4 -3 -2 -0.5 -4 -3 -5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 -5 -1.0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 -6 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Mortgage market characteristics matter Average estimated impact on GDP by VAR analysis (in percent) Countries included in the calculation of average impact Penalty-fee prepayment and refinancing available not available -2.77 Australia, Denmark, Japan, United Kingdom, United States Austria, Belgium, Canada, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, -1.71 Netherlands, Norway, Spain, Sweden Option to withdraw mortgage equity available not available Typical loan-to-value ratio at origination less than or equal to 60 percent between 60 and 79 percent more than or equal to 80 percent Australia, Canada, Denmark, Finland, Greece, Ireland, Japan, Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, United Kingdom, United States -1.61 Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Spain -2.27 -0.06 Austria, Italy -1.67 Canada, Finland, France, Germany, Norway, Spain, United Kingdom Australia, Belgium, Denmark, Ireland, Japan, Netherlands, Sweden, -2.21 United States Policy Implications Can a uniform policy prescription of taking into account asset prices in monetary policy making be made? It seems not, statistical properties of house prices vary across countries. In addition, some shocks to house price inflation are persistent. The U.S. business, house price, and interest rate cycles tend to lead the respective cycles in other countries over all horizons and more so recently. Questions domestically-focused economic policies.