* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Structural Adjustment during Canada’s Wheat Boom: 1900-1913* Abstract Emma Stephens
Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup
Economic growth wikipedia , lookup
Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup
Refusal of work wikipedia , lookup
Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup
Post–World War II economic expansion wikipedia , lookup
Chinese economic reform wikipedia , lookup
Rostow's stages of growth wikipedia , lookup
Structural Adjustment during Canada’s Wheat Boom: 1900-1913* Emma Stephens Graduate Student, Department of Economics Cornell University Ithaca, NY, USA DRAFT - NOT FOR CITATION Abstract Using a theoretical model borrowed from the literature on adjustment to booming tradable sectors, I find that the observed exponential growth in Canada’s agricultural, manufacturing and non-tradable sectors and wage and price trends between the turn of the century and the First World War are consistent with a model of tariff protection of the manufacturing sector from any negative consequences of the agriculture sector boom during this period. The model implies that without tariff protection, the manufacturing sector might not have developed as rapidly due to the increase in equilibrium real wages and reallocation of the labor supply brought about by the boom in agriculture, as in a ‘Dutch Disease’ scenario. To effectively control for the effects of the increasing immigration, land settlement and capital inflow rates while examining the adjustment of the manufacturing sector to the Wheat Boom, a simple system dynamics model of the agricultural and manufacturing sectors is developed. The system dynamics model is then used to illustrate the divergent growth paths of Canada’s manufacturing and agricultural sectors and overall economic performance under different hypothetical trade policies with modern implications for domestic trade policy in developing nations. * I wish to thank Asaf Zussman, Charles Nicholson, Chris Barrett, Paul Hayes, Talia Bar, Nancy Chau, Francesca Molinari and the participants in Cornell’s Third Year Research Seminar for valuable feedback on this paper. All errors are my own. 1. Introduction At the beginning of the 20th century, the Canadian economy was rapidly changing in a number of different dimensions. The Canadian government was determined to unify the country and promote ‘east-west’ economic interactions and pursued a number of key programs, like the completion of the transcontinental railway in 1885 and an aggressive recruitment campaign to promote immigration to the country, starting in 1896 (Skelton, 1914). As well, massive movements of international capital from abroad and technological advances in many of Canada’s industries simultaneously exerted pressure on the economy at the turn of the century. The two largest components of GNP for Canada during this period were agriculture and manufacturing. Between 1870 and 1910, the two combined accounted for between 39 and 56 percent of gross domestic product, with agriculture’s share as the slightly larger part until 1911 (Table 1). Canada produced a wide variety of agricultural products and manufactured goods many of which were either destined for the export sector or subject to substantial international competition. In addition, both sectors saw phenomenal growth, particularly after 1900. A clear turning point in the time series for both sectors is observable around 1900. (Figure 1). Several theories exist about the interactions between growing sectors in an economy. One particular strand of the literature concerns the impact of a growing tradable sector on other tradable sectors that are subject to international prices (Corden & Neary, 1982, Corden, 1984). This literature was developed to explain the behavior of the Dutch and British economies after the discovery of new oil reserves in the 1980’s. Both economies suffered a contraction in manufacturing that was theorized to be partly due to the boom in 2 the oil industry spurred by adjustment to the discovery of the new tradable natural resource. This effect is known as the ‘Dutch Disease’. This theory of the adjustment process is also applicable in the case of price shocks for internationally traded goods, as well as a natural resource discovery. The Dutch Disease model of adjustment between a booming and a lagging tradable sector can be used to study the response of an economy to a great many different types of shocks, such as positive technological improvements and improved terms of trade. It has also been recently applied to historical events, such as the effect of the importation of American treasure on Spanish industry in the 16th century (Forsyth & Nicholas, 1983) and increases in overseas investment income for the U. K. between 1870-1913 (Rowthorn & Solomou, 1991). The period of rapid growth in the agriculture sector in Canada between 1900-1913 is known as the Wheat Boom era in the literature on Canadian economic history. Many economic historians have attempted to analyze the impact of the boom in the agriculture sector on Canada’s overall level of economic growth and many believe that the two trends are highly correlated (Bertram, 1963, Lewis, 1975, Altman, 1987, Inwood & Stengos, 1991). The Wheat Boom has been attributed to many different factors including technological improvements, and increased demand for Canadian agricultural output, (particularly wheat) on the international market (Dick, 1980, Ward, 1994). Some of these changes thus have qualities that should allow successful application of the Dutch Disease model to Canada during this period. However, the manufacturing sector in Canada was also 3 growing during the same period, which is in direct conflict with some of the predictions of the basic theoretical model. Thus far in the literature on Canada’s historical economic development, the growth of overall GNP per capita in Canada during this period has generally been attributed to the boom in the agriculture sector, although the exact degree is still in dispute (Chambers & Gordon, 1966, Dales, McManus & Watkins, 1967, Lewis, 1975, Inwood & Stengos, 1991) and has been used in the past as evidence to support the idea of export-led growth (also known as the Staples Hypothesis (Vickery, 1974, Ankli, 1980)) as a policy that should be promoted in many developing countries today. The Staples Hypothesis focuses on forward and backward linkages from agriculture to manufacturing to account for the observed positive levels of growth in both sectors between the turn of the 20th century and the beginning of WWI, and have concluded that these linkages promoted economic growth overall1. However, this is a longer view of the behavior of the agriculture and manufacturing sectors and the actual interactions between the two in the medium run might be better represented by the Dutch Disease model. The clear divergence between the predictions of these two models of economic adjustment is cause for concern, because the policy implications for each are completely different. On the one hand, if one believes that a booming export sector could be responsible for the decline of another important part of the economy, even if it is just in the medium run, then perhaps measures can be undertaken to lessen the impact of the shock. On the other, if exports are believed to lead to economic growth, then the booming export sector should be promoted to the highest possible degree, despite interim 1 For example, Caves (1971) examines such linkages as the relationship between the rate of export expansion and savings rates, international migration patterns, and import-competing manufacturing growth. 4 adjustments between the different exporting sectors. The Dutch Disease model should apply in the Canadian case. However the predicted result of a decline in the manufacturing sector did not occur. It is important to determine why, if the Canadian experience of economic growth at the turn of the 20th century is to be used as a model for other countries to follow in the future. One limitation of the Dutch Disease model in its most basic form is that it models adjustment in the medium run and relies partly on assuming that important state variables such as labor or land or financial capital are held fixed. The turn of the century in Canada was a time of rapid expansion of the area of farmland and the country aggressively attracted immigrants to settle the Western Provinces (Dick, 1980, Urquhart, 1986). As well, inflows of foreign capital due to overseas investment also boomed in the period under study (Dick & Floyd, 1992). Therefore, following the theoretical discussion, I present a simple system dynamics model of the Canadian economy that allows for variable stocks of labor and land and foreign capital inflows. Some sample simulations under different structural assumptions are presented and their impact on important variables like output in both the agricultural and manufacturing sectors, as well as prices and wages is discussed. As can be demonstrated with the simulations, the adjustment of the different sectors of the economy both to the boom in agriculture as well as to the many other changes that occurred in this period is still consistent with the variant of the Dutch Disease model used in the theoretical discussion within certain parameter ranges. Furthermore, the model reveals that particular assumptions about trade policy need to be made in order to generate a scenario that most closely matches the trends observed in the Canadian economy during this era. These simulations allow for a 5 discussion of trade policy in developing countries and the assumptions necessary for economic growth for small open economies that are subject to various shocks. 2. The Dutch Disease Model of Adjustment and the Canadian Economy This description of the Dutch disease model comes from Corden and Neary (1982). An economy is supposed to consist of multiple tradable and non-tradable sectors that generally share one or more factors of production. In the simplest version, the economy is modeled to have two tradable and one non-tradable sector. All three sectors have a particular factor of production, which is unique to that sector, as well as one shared factor, which is assumed to be labor. The mobility of the shared factor between each sector allows the shock to the booming tradable sector to be transmitted to the other sectors in the economy. Figure 2 shows one of the main implications of the Dutch Disease model. The labor demand functions for the tradable sector (i.e. booming plus lagging sectors), the lagging sector and the non-traded sectors are given by LT, LL and LNT respectively, with the wage rate measured in terms of the lagging sector on the vertical axis. With an increase either in productivity in the booming sector or some other increase in labor demand (an output market price increase, for example), the tradable sector labor demand curve LT shifts outwards (in this diagram, this is to the left). This results in an increase in the wages for all sectors, as labor is assumed to be completely mobile and in equilibrium, the same wage rate will prevail. The increase in wages draws labor from the lagging and nontraded sectors into the booming sector, as shown by the increase in labor from point A to point B on the graph and the decrease in labor in the lagging sector from M to M’ (labor 6 in the traded sectors is measured from the right origin OT). This is known as the ‘resource movement effect’. However, the internal adjustment to the booming sector then continues in the economy. Due to the small open economy assumption, the price of both the booming and lagging tradable sector output cannot change as it is determined in the international market. The increase in wages leads to increased demand for all goods. Therefore, the price of nontraded goods relative to traded goods increases and the labor demand curve for the nontraded sector shifts outwards as prices rise, which draws labor from both the booming and lagging tradable sectors into the non-traded sector (shown by the change in labor from point B to point G). This is the ‘spending effect’. The final result, in this particular formulation of the Dutch Disease model, is that labor moves unambiguously out of the lagging sector, while the results for final labor distribution in the booming and non-traded sectors are determined by the dominance of either the resource movement effect, in which labor increases in the booming sector, or the spending effect, in which labor increases in the non-traded sector. As well, nontradables prices relative to tradables prices have increased and the exchange rate experiences a real appreciation. Is the Dutch Disease model of adjustment appropriate for the Canadian economy during the Wheat Boom period? The two primary components of GDP in the period were agriculture and manufacturing (Urquhart, 1986). Real agricultural output was composed of dairy products, meat, wheat and other field crops, with meat products dominating production until about 1916 (Innis, 1986). Between 1900 and 1910, the rate of growth of the agriculture sector increased, with yearly (compounded) growth averaging between 2 7 and 3% per annum from 1870-1900 and up to 4% in 1910. This growth has been attributed to a number of factors, including rapid settlement of the Canadian prairies (Innis, 1986), technological labor-saving improvements in farm equipment (Ward, 1994), the development of better varieties of wheat (Urquhart, 1986) and the increased demand for Canadian wheat for bread making (Dick, 1980). In addition to production, increased numbers of people were involved in agricultural production over this same period. Table 2 shows the numbers of individuals engaged in agriculture according to the Canadian Census and the annualized growth rates of numbers of workers in agriculture. The numbers of individuals engaged in agriculture increased more than 165% between 1871 and 1911. In addition, the annualized growth rates indicate that the number of workers grew fairly steadily at around 1% per year until 1901, and between 1901 and 1911, the numbers grew by almost 3%. Therefore, there appears to have been a great increase in both the number of those employed in the agriculture sector and the overall output of this sector around the turn of the century that might be analyzable using the Dutch Disease model. However, determining the lagging sector may be difficult if the Dutch Disease model is to be used. This model developed out of concern that booming sectors, especially those in the natural resources, may negatively impact a country’s manufacturing sector, via the drain on labor out of the lagging manufacturing sector. But in Canada, the manufacturing sector overall displayed growth trends in output and workers quite similar to those of the agriculture sector. Annualized growth rates of output average around 3% per year until 1900 and then jump to 5.2%. Table 3 summarizes the available manufacturing employment data. The numbers of individuals in manufacturing also grew, but at a 8 decreasing rate, as opposed to the agriculture sector, with employment growth rates declining from between 3 and 4% per year to between 1 and 2%. The changes in both agriculture and manufacturing overall mask changes in individual sub sectors of each industry. In agriculture, meat made up the primary component of agriculture until around 1910, when wheat began to dominate. In manufacturing, wood products comprised 42% of all manufacturing output in 1870 but steadily declined as a proportion of total manufacturing output to approximately 17% in 1910, while iron and steel products grew from 5% to approximately 18% (Altman, 1987). So the interaction between the agriculture and manufacturing sectors of the Canadian economy around the turn of the century may be a complicated mix of changes in many different sub sectors. For this study, I will focus on the agriculture and manufacturing sectors overall, but it is important to keep in mind that much variation exists in the sub-components of both. One final symptom of the Dutch Disease at work in an economy is a real appreciation in the country’s exchange rate. Therefore the ratio of non-traded to traded prices should increase if a booming sector is applying some pressure to domestic resources and is changing incomes in an economy. Figure 3 shows the overall ratio of non-traded to traded prices for Canada from 18701913. Between 1895 and 1905 it appears that the ratio of prices sustained an upward movement, with a flattening out thereafter. This is also in line with the Dutch Disease hypothesis that a boom will cause this ratio to rise because of the spending effect. 3. Reconciliation of the Dutch Disease model with Canadian Experience There are many variations on the ‘Dutch Disease’ model, or more generally, the medium run analysis of resource allocation in an economy with both tradable and non-tradable 9 sectors. The prediction of ‘de-industrialization’ generated by a boom in a country’s tradable sector can only be assured in a very simplistic case where the tradable and nontradable sectors share only one common factor of production. However, if more complicated interactions between the three sectors are introduced that incorporate different kinds of trade policy or two or more mobile factors, then the effects of a boom in a tradable sector become more ambiguous. In Corden and Neary (1982), three possible scenarios are presented where the booming tradable sector might actually lead to an increase the output of the lagging sector. In the first case, even in the simplest model with one shared factor of production, if the lagging sector is not entirely for export, then the prediction of de-industrialization of the entire lagging sector is not assured, as the movement of labor out of the lagging sector due to the resource movement effect is counteracted with the increased output in the nontradable sector due to the spending effect. In the traditional model, the lagging sector is assumed to be the country’s entire manufacturing industry, hence the fear of deindustrialization if the manufacturing sector is strictly for export. But if a portion of the manufacturing sector can be considered as non-tradable, for example through the imposition of tariffs, then at least some portions of the manufacturing industry may benefit from the effects of the booming tradable sector, due to the increase in demand and the spending effect’s promotion of output in the non-tradable sector. Canada at the turn of the century had in place a protectionist tariff policy known as the ‘National Policy’ that was designed to insulate the domestic manufacturing industry from competition from abroad (primarily from the United States) (Annis, 1936). Therefore, it is possible that the sectors most protected by the National Policy should be better 10 analyzed as part of the non-tradable sector and the boom in agriculture, in that it raised national income, could be said to increase demand for and the prices and output of at least some of the manufacturing sector overall output, thereby eliminating the deindustrialization effect. A second model presented by Corden and Neary incorporates both labor and capital. In this expanded model, labor is assumed to be mobile between all three sectors, but the booming sector employs a specific factor (in our case, land), and the lagging tradable sector and the non-tradable sector are assumed to share both labor and capital and do not have any other specific factors. The intensity of usage of labor and capital in the lagging and non-tradable sectors therefore becomes the determining factor on whether the booming sector causes output in the lagging sector (and the non-tradable sector) to go up or down. If the lagging sector is more capital intensive than the non-tradable sector, then the resource movement effect of the boom limits the amount of labor available to the lagging and non-tradable sectors. Accordingly, the output of the capital intensive lagging sector will rise, as the increase in the wage caused by the resource movement effect causes the output in the relatively labor intensive non-tradable sector to fall. However, the spending effect tends to increase demand for services, which raises output of the nontradable sector, and squeezes the output of the lagging trading sector, thereby counteracting the resource movement effect. But, the result on the lagging sector’s output is ambiguous and if the resource movement effect dominates, then the lagging sector will experience an increase in output, because the pressure applied to the shared factor of production (labor) more negatively affects the labor-intensive industry, which in this scenario is the non-tradable sector. This is in contrast to the simplest model, with 11 only labor shared between all sectors, in which both the resource movement effect and the spending effect squeezed the output in the lagging sector. The third model assumes that two factors of production (labor and capital) are completely mobile between all sectors of the economy. In this case, if the lagging sector is more capital intensive than the booming sector and also the non-tradable sector2, then the boom in the least capital intensive sector raises the relative wage with respect to the return on capital, as well as the price of services, and can imply an increase in the output of both the booming and lagging tradable sectors under certain conditions. 4. Statistical Evidence The three versions of the Dutch Disease model presented above that allow for a simultaneous increase in both the booming and lagging tradables sectors will now be compared to data available for Canada at the turn of the century. In order to analyze the Canadian case, it remains to decide which of the possible three models presented above might best represent the behavior of the Canadian economy at the turn of the century. 4.a Labor Mobility Model with Protective Tariffs If the only mobile factor of production is assumed to be labor, as in the first modified version of the Dutch Disease model described in section 3 then the economy should adjust to a boom in one of the tradables sectors by: 1. Reduced production of non-protected manufactures (i.e. manufactures is the lagging sector. 2. Increased real wage (in terms of non-protected manufactures) 3. Increase in the ratio of non-tradable to tradables prices. 2 No assumptions are made on the relative capital intensities of the booming and non-tradables sectors. 12 Over the period between 1879-1913, much of the manufacturing industry in Canada was protected by substantial import tariffs. The Canadian government launched a protectionist campaign with the institution of what was called the National Policy in 1879, which was designed to promote the development of sectors of the economy that were facing competition from foreign imports. Table 4 summarizes the tariff rates on different Canadian products in different years between 1879, when the National Policy was first introduced, and 1907. Many manufacturing products (and also agricultural products) were protected during this period. The tariffs on agricultural output declined over this period but a vocal manufacturing sector in Canada managed to convince the government that tariffs on almost all manufactures were necessary for Canada’s economic development (Kilgour, 1988). This was also in spite of the fact that these tariffs, especially on agricultural implements and other manufactured goods crucial to the agricultural industry hurt farmers in the Western part of the country and were loudly denounced by members of the agricultural sector (Annis, 1936). One notable exception within the tariff policy appears to be the wood products sub sector in manufacturing output. As mentioned previously, wood products declined from 42% to 17% of total manufacturing output between 1870 and 1910. This reduction has mostly been attributed to the loss of markets for wood products brought on by the decline in wooden shipbuilding at the end of the 19th century (Urquhart, 1986). However, the various tariff programs listed in Table 4 do not specifically target the wood products industry. It may have been subjected to an overall tariff that covered all untargeted imports, however the relative lack of protection given to this sector, in light of the implications of the Dutch Disease model that non-protected lagging sectors should 13 decline, might give some evidence that the booms in agriculture and protected manufacturing sectors might have also contributed to the decline of the wood products sector. Therefore, even though overall manufacturing output increased during the Wheat Boom era, some sub sectors that may have been better protected by tariffs (like iron and steel products) seem to account for most of this growth, and extreme decline in non-protected sectors like wood products is also observed. As well, as has already been noted, the ratio of non-tradables to tradables prices did increase during this period. Finally, Mackinnon (1996) finds that Canadian Pacific Railway (C. P. R.) real wages in both unskilled and skilled positions grew between 1901 and 1913 (Table 5). The national railways employed up to 10% of the non-agricultural labor force in Canada before WWI and can thus be seen as a partial proxy for manufacturing industry wages overall in the country. Interestingly, in the Mackinnon wage study, there is also an observed differential between nominal C. P. R. wage rates offered in the western provinces of British Columbia, and the prairie provinces, over those offered in Ontario and Quebec. The Prairie Provinces were the center of the agriculture boom and if C. P. R. wages can proxy for overall nonagriculture wages, then these wages were higher than wages offered in Ontario and Quebec. This might be further evidence that the booming agriculture sector raised wages, because the effect of this boom would be felt the strongest in the provinces where agriculture was most practiced. Therefore, these three trends seem to match the modified Dutch Disease model described above, with mobile labor but some parts of the manufacturing sector protected and not for export. Demand from the booming agricultural sector for many manufactured goods 14 must have increased but due to the protective tariff, this demand was not satisfied by increased importation from outside of Canada and may have led to the observed overall increase in the output of the manufacturing sector, despite the opposite prediction of the Dutch Disease model. 4. b Labor and Capital Mobility in the lagging and non-tradable sector plus labor mobility between the agriculture and other sectors. Taking now the Canadian economy as in the second model of section 3, assume again that the manufacturing industry is completely tradable and the tariffs did not significantly impact the level of competition. If agriculture (as the booming sector) has some specific factors of production and only shares labor with the rest of the economy, then, if it is assumed that the manufacturing sector is more capital intensive than the non-tradable sector, manufacturing output can increase along with a booming agricultural sector only if the overall output of the non-tradable sector decreases. This is because the resource movement effect tends to boost production of the manufacturing sector as it is more capital intensive than the services sector3. The boom in agriculture reduces the amount of labor available to both manufacturing and the non-tradable sector, and the resultant reallocation of labor and capital between these two sectors increases manufacturing sector output. However, the spending effect that results from an overall increase in national income due to the boom in the agriculture sector will increase demand for nontradable goods and this pressure will again draw labor out of manufacturing and back into the non-tradable sector. So, the resource movement effect and the spending effect again counteract each other, and the only way that this model could be applied to the Canadian case, knowing that the overall production of the manufacturing industry rose during the 3 This is given as an application of the Rybcszynski Theorem. 15 period under consideration, would be if there was an observed decrease of output in the non-tradable sector. The ratio of non-tradable to tradable prices should also increase in this model, therefore without the further implication for the output of the non-tradable sector, it would be difficult to distinguish this model from the model described in section 4. a. The non-tradable sector essentially represents the provision of services to the Canadian population. The non-tradables price series for Canada is composed of information about housing construction and rent, plus other services like fuel and light (Dick & Floyd, 1992). Table 6 gives nominal GNP data on the total income received in construction, transportation, electric light and power, residential rents and communications for selected years. Using these sectors as representative of the non-tradable sector of the Canadian economy, this income data was deflated using the non-tradable price series of Dick and Floyd to get a rough estimate of real output in the non-tradable sector. As can be seen in Figure 4, even by this arguably imprecise measurement of output in the non-tradables sector, this version of the Dutch Disease model does not seem to match the evidence available on the non-tradables sector. Given the assumptions about the manufacturing sector being more capital intensive than the non-tradables sector, expansion in manufacturing, given a boom in agriculture, can only come at the expense of output in the non-tradables sector. But the evidence seems to suggest that the nontradable sector, as represented by various industries like construction and communications, was also expanding, and experienced a sharp increase after 1895, similar to the increases observed for both manufacturing and agriculture at this time. Even if we consider only residential rents, which are arguably closest to the terms used to 16 create the non-tradable price index, there is still an observed increase in rents, although it is much less pronounced than the overall increase in output in the non-tradables sector, using the sub-sectors listed as proxies for the entire sector. Therefore, the simultaneous increase observed in the Canadian economy in agriculture, manufacturing and the nontradables sector is not consistent with the assumptions of this model of structural adjustment. 4.c Fully Mobile Labor and Capital between all sectors If labor and capital are fully mobile between all sectors, as in the third modified Dutch Disease model of section 3, then the results for the output of each sector and the real wage, in terms of the lagging manufacturing sector, are ambiguous. Table 7 summarizes the possible relative capital intensity combinations between the booming, lagging and non-tradable sectors and the subsequent implication for prices and wages in each sector of the boom. (i.e. kj is the capital intensity ratio for sector j (j=B, L, NT for Booming, Lagging and Non-Tradables sector, respectively) and pNT is the price of output in the non-tradable sector. w is the wage, in terms of lagging manufactures). In looking at the Canadian economy, we know that prices in the non-tradables sector unambiguously increased over the given time period, so we can restrict our attention to the scenarios where pNT is shown to increase. As well, with the C. P. R. wages of Mackinnon (1996), we might imagine that wages also rose. In the Corden and Neary model, however, it is not possible to observe a simultaneous increase in lagging sector output along with an increase in non-tradables prices and an increase in wages4. 4 This is because with increasing prices and wages, as in section 4. b, any increase in the manufacturing sector output must come at the expense of output in the non-tradables sector, which was not observed in Canada in the time being considered. 17 Therefore, the model with capital and labor fully mobile over all three sectors is not consistent with Canadian data. 5. Simulation Model of the Turn of the Century Canadian Economy In order to further support the notion that the correct model of adjustment for the agriculture and manufacturing sectors is one in which the manufacturing sector is partly protected from rising real wages by trade tariffs, I develop a simple system dynamics model of the agriculture, manufacturing and non-tradables sectors that allows both for analysis of the adjustment of the manufacturing and non-tradable sectors to the Wheat Boom, while simultaneously taking into account the concurrent growth in the labor force, area of farm land and foreign capital flows during the same period. The model tracks the stocks of labor, real output, land and uses these stocks to calculate output, wage, labor allocation and price trends as they adjust to changes due to the Wheat Boom. A simplified diagram that shows the primary causal relationships between the stocks in the model is shown in Figure 55. As can be seen in Figure 5, the simulation model is simply a dynamic version of the Corden and Neary model that allows for variation in the levels of the key state variables. Three important feedback loops that dominate the behavior of the simplified model over time have been labeled. The first, shown with green arrows, is the resource effect that leads to a reduction in manufacturing output in response to an increased demand for agricultural output, due either to an increase in the world price or due to a change in the level of agricultural production6. The shock to demand drives up real wages, which reduces the amount of labor supplied to the 5 Full information on the model structure is available from the author upon request. I also assume for simplicity that increased land area for farming leads to an increased demand for agricultural sector labor and that increased capital inflows leads to an increase in the demand for manufacturing sector labor and have not specified exact production functions in either sector. 6 18 manufacturing sector, as the increased demand draws workers from manufacturing and the non-tradable sector into agriculture. The second loop, which runs around the outside of the entire diagram, is the spending effect mentioned in earlier sections of the paper. The increase in real GDP leads to an increase in demand for all outputs, which are assumed to be normal goods. However, it is only in the non-tradables sector that this increase in demand leads to an increase in real wages, as output prices in agriculture and manufacturing are fixed by the international market. This increase in wages again leads to a reduction in manufacturing output. The third loop is shown in blue (labeled “Real Appreciation”) and represents the overall increase in non-tradables prices that are a direct result of the boom in the tradable sector (in this case agriculture). In the causal loop diagram, the primary stocks have been placed inside the boxes. By identifying these elements as stocks and developing appropriate rate equations, the diagram shown becomes a full-fledged stock and flow structure in the system dynamics model of the interaction between agriculture, manufacturing and the non-tradables sector. It is the ability to describe the flows into and out of the labor and output pools for the three sectors under consideration, both due to the boom in agriculture but also due to other inflows and outflows like immigration, emigration and land settlement, that allows for the analysis of the Canadian economy using the Dutch Disease framework, while simultaneously controlling for the dynamic processes that were important during the period between the turn of the century and the First World War. 5.a Simulation Results The model simulates for thirty years. The simulation starts in approximately 1890, which is a few years before the observable upward trends in the different production sectors 19 takes place and is a year that has a large amount of data available. The initial values for key stocks and flow rates, like labor force, immigration/emigration rates, output for each sector, etc. were collected from Dick (1980) and Urquhart (1986) wherever possible to initialize the model. It is important to note that much other data on dynamic variables like appropriate adjustment times that govern many of the first order adjustment rate equations in the model are not known and were given very rough estimates. The dynamics described by the different simulation runs are therefore primarily qualitative rather than precise quantitative predictions. 5.b.1. Simulation of the ‘baseline’ Corden and Neary model Figure 6 shows the result of simulating the most restrictive form of the model, under circumstances that most closely match the original Corden and Neary (1982) theoretical framework. In this simulation, the total labor force is held constant and world prices for agricultural and manufacturing output are assumed to be fixed. However, the price for non-tradable output is calculated within the model in response to the changing distribution of labor between the three sectors. An increase in farmland area drives the ‘boom’ and increases the demand for labor in the agricultural sector. Using the fact that the labor force is fixed as well as an approximate elasticity of labor demand response to increases in farming land, the final medium run changes in supply curves for labor in the manufacturing and non-tradables sector that result from the boom in labor demand in agriculture are calculated and the stocks of labor in the two ‘lagging sectors’ gradually shift, with both manufacturing and the non-tradable sector experiencing an initial decrease due to the ‘resource effect’ (this is analogous to the movement from point A to B in Figure 2). The shifts in the demand and supply curves are then used to 20 endogenously determine the new equilibrium wage that should be common across all three sectors, under the assumption of perfect mobility of labor. As soon as wages start to increase in response to the agriculture boom, the ‘spending effect’ that results from the real appreciation begins to operate, and the labor force shifts again, this time out of manufacturing and agriculture and into the non-tradable sector (this is movement from B to G in Figure 2). The price of non-tradable output is also determined endogenously through the changing labor supply and demand curves as well as the changing demand for non-tradable output brought about by the ‘spending effect’. Finally, the changes in labor lead to changes in output, with the manufacturing sector experiencing an overall decrease in the amount of final output, which is the hypothesis of the ‘Dutch Disease’. As can be seen in Figure 6, most variables demonstrate the behavior described above. Output in agriculture initially increases in response to the movement of labor from the other sectors into agriculture, but gradually experiences a decline as the ‘spending effect’ draws labor out of agriculture and into the non-tradable sector. Also, output in the nontradable sector has increased while manufacturing has decreased, which is as expected. Wages climb almost continuously during the simulation period time but non-tradable prices and GDP first increase and then decrease. This is due to the relative productivity of labor in each sector and the changes in labor allocation. Figure 7 shows the resultant trends in this allocation, with the left panel representing the changes in labor between agriculture and the total ‘lagging’ sector, composed of manufacturing and non-tradables combined, and the right panel showing how the labor supply adjusts in the manufacturing and non-tradable sectors specifically. As can be seen, although the total lagging sector 21 labor does not change too much, labor moves unambiguously out of the manufacturing sector and into the non-tradable sector. 5.b.2 Model simulation with changing land area as well as a variable labor force Figure 8 shows the results from allowing labor force as well as land area to change7. Now, due to the steady increase in labor supply (the net immigration rate was approximately 0.5% per year (Urquhart, 1986)), output eventually increases, but both wages and sectoral output remain level for most of the simulation, as the increasing amount of labor available puts downward pressure on wages, and the effects of labor shifting between the different sectors on the trends in output are dampened. However, the effect of the boom on the price of non-tradables as well as the overall trend in GDP are more similar to the actual data for the Canadian economy presented in Figures 1 and 3, and support the fairly intuitive notion that changes in the stock of available labor may have made important contributions to the output and price dynamics in Canada in the period under consideration. Finally, the graphs in the bottom panels of Figure 8 that show the changes in the labor allocation between the sectors have some similarity with the data presented in Tables 2 and 3, with a decrease in the growth rate in the agricultural labor force actually observed around 1901. Although this is very circumstantial and there are many other reasons possible for such a change, it could also be interpreted as some friction in the adjustment of the labor force between the agricultural and manufacturing/non-tradable sectors that are represented both in the theoretical and simulation model described here. 5. b. 3. Model sensitivity analysis of different degrees of tradability 7 Other changes between the baseline model and the model in section 5.b.2 include pressure from increases in demand for manufacturing output brought on by an increase in capital to reduce labor in non-tradables. 22 In section 4, the possibility that trends in wages, output and prices observed in Canada between around 1900 and 1913 were consistent with the presence of a protective tariff, was presented, as the output in the non-tradable sector was observed to increase rather than decrease over this time period. Figure 8 goes some way to further supporting this idea and shows the response of key variables when subjected to a range of elasticities that correspond to the impact of real GDP on manufacturing sector labor demand. Recall that in the non-tradable sector, labor demand will increase as a result of increases in real GDP due to the spending effect. A similar effect may be assumed for industries in the manufacturing sector that may have been more closely protected from import competition by the presence of a tariff, with increases in real GDP brought about by the boom in agriculture leading to increases in the demand for labor in those industries. To test the response of the model, the ‘real GDP elasticity of demand for labor in manufacturing’ was varied between a value of 0, which indicates no additional ‘spending effect’ on the economy, at 10 which may represent a high level of response8,9. The sensitivity analysis is compared to the ‘baseline’ model, shown by the red line (labeled ‘Corden Neary’ on the graphs). The results of the sensitivity analysis are tentative but suggestive. The wage rate is highly sensitive, both numerically and behaviorally, to the elasticity parameter, indicating possible model misspecification, however wage increase is more steep and rapid with the most protected manufacturing sector possible in the model (represented by the upper contour of the colored distribution). As well, manufacturing sector output grows with tariff protection rather than eventually falling as in the unprotected case (while still lying 8 The model is highly sensitive to the effects of real appreciation and tests of elasticities greater than 10 resulted in model errors. 9 The sensitivity analysis was conducted using Monte Carlo simulations, with 200 repetitions. 23 above the level suggested in the Corden Neary model). This more closely matches the observed trends in manufacturing sector output at the turn of the 20th century. Interestingly, agricultural output rises farther and falls less under a protected manufacturing sector than would otherwise be the case, although again the behavioral sensitivity shown between the upper and lower contours of the distribution is cause for caution in further interpretation. However, the protected manufacturing sector distributes labor more evenly throughout the economy, possibly leading to greater overall output (due to the different productivity levels and prices) and a smaller loss from the agricultural sector than in the unprotected case, which may explain the trends observed for agriculture. Finally, non-tradable prices rise higher in the protected case rather than falling in the unprotected case. As this more closely matches the Canadian experience (see Figure 3), it also suggests that the tariff may have played an important role not only in the manufacturing sector, but in all other parts of the economy as well. 6. Conclusion The Canadian economy experienced rapid growth in almost all sectors between the turn of the 20th century and WWI. Although some models of structural adjustment predict that booms in certain sectors may lead to negative effects on other areas of the economy, under some assumptions on factor mobility and intensity, these models may also be useful in examining the Canadian economy, which did not experience a marked decline in its non-booming sectors. The Dutch Disease model of structural adjustment is one such tool. If some sectors of Canadian manufacturing are assumed to have been effectively protected via tariffs, then the observed trends in agricultural and manufacturing output along with the ratio of non-tradable to tradable goods prices and 24 real wages seem to fit with a picture of primarily mobile labor between different sectors of the economy combined with some protection from international competition. Other modifications of the Dutch Disease model that allow for simultaneous increases in output in multiple tradable sectors do not seem to be supported by the data available. As well, a simple system dynamics model of the three production sectors in question further supports the idea that a tariff protecting the manufacturing sector may also partly explain the upward trends in both manufacturing and agriculture during this period, even under conditions where labor and land inputs to production are changing over time. These results may have implications for current trade policy, in that the observed benefits of a leading export sector cannot be simply explained and the impact of booming export sector will only be complimentary to other sectors under certain conditions (in the case of Canada, it appears that these conditions were tariff protection and non-mobility of most factors of production except labor). Understanding the medium run adjustment of these sectors should help to create better trade policy, which may have been focused historically on the long run picture. Bibliography Altman, M. (1987). A revision of Canadian economic growth: 1870-1910 (a challenge to the gradualist interpretation). The Canadian Journal of Economics, 20(1), 86113. Altman, M. (1992). Revised real Canadian GNP estimates and Canadian economic growth, 1870-1926. Review of Income and Wealth, 38(4), 455-473. Ankli, R. E. (1980). The growth of the Canadian economy, 1896-1920: Export led and/or neoclassical growth. Explorations in Economic History, 17, 251-274. 25 Annis, C. A. (1936). A study of Canadian tariffs and trade agreements. Ph. D. dissertation, Cornell University. Bertram, G. W. (1973). Economic growth in Canadian industry, 1870-1915: The Staple Model and the Take-off Hypothesis. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, (May), 159-84. Caves, R. (1971). Export-led growth and the new economic history. In J. N. Bhagwati, R. W. Jones, R. A. Mundell, J. Vanek (Eds.), Trade, Balance of Payments, and Growth: Essays in Honor of Charles Kindleburger (pp. 403-442). Amsterdam: North Holland. Chambers, E. J. & Gordon, D. F. (1966). Primary products and economic growth: An empirical measurement. The Journal of Political Economy, 74(4), 315-332. Corden, W. M. (1984). Booming sector and Dutch disease economics: Survey and consolidation. Oxford Economic Papers, 36(3), 359-380. Corden, W. M. & Neary, J. P. (1982). Booming sector and de-industrialization in a small open economy. The Economic Journal, 92(368), 825-848. Dales, J. H. (1966). The protective tariff in Canada’s development: Eight essays on trade and tariffs when factors move with special reference to Canadian protectionism 1870-1955. Canada: University of Toronto Press. Dales, J. H, McManus, J. C. & Watkins, M. H. (1967). Primary products and economic growth: A comment. The Journal of Political Economy, 75(6), 876-880. Dick, T. J. O. (1980). Canadian wheat production and trade 1896-1930. Explorations in Economic History, 17, 275-302. 26 Dick, T. J. O. & Floyd, J. E. (1992). Canada and the gold standard: balance of payments adjustment 1871-1913. Canada: Cambridge University Press. Firestone, O. J. (1958). Canada’s economic development, 1867-1953. London: Bowes & Bowes. Forsyth, P. J. & Nicholas, S. J. (1983). The decline of Spanish industry and the price revolution: A neoclassical analysis. Journal of European Economic History, 12(Winter), 601-609. Innis, R. M. (1986). Output and productivity in Canadian agriculture, 1870-71 to 192627. In S. L. Engerman & R. E. Gallman (Eds.), Long-term Factors in American Economic Growth (pp. 737-778). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Inwood, K. & Stengos, T. (1991). Discontinuities in Canadian economic growth, 18701985. Explorations in Economic History, 28, 274-286. Kilgour, D. (1988). Uneasy patriots: Western Canadians in confederation. Edmonton: Lone Pine Press. Lewis, F. (1975). The Canadian wheat boom and per capita income: New estimates. The Journal of Political Economy, 83(6), 1249-1257. Mackinnon, M. (1996). New evidence on Canadian wage rates, 1900-1930. The Canadian Journal of Economics, 29(1), 114-131. Rowthorn, R. E. & Solomou, S. N. (1991). The macroeconomic effects of overseas investment on the U.K. balance of trade, 1870-1913. The Economic History Review, 44(4), 654-664. 27 Skelton, O. D. (1914). General economic history, 1867-1912. In A. Shortt & A. G. Doughty (Eds.), Canada and its Provinces, v. 9 (pp. 95 – 274). Toronto, Canada: Glasgow, Brook & Company. Urquhart, M. C. (1986). New estimates of gross national product, Canada, 1870-1926: Some implications for Canadian development. In S. L. Engerman & R. E. Gallman (Eds.), Long-term Factors in American Economic Growth (pp. 9-94). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Vickery, E. (1974). Exports and North American economic growth: ‘Structuralist’ and ‘Staple’ models in historical perspective. The Canadian Journal of Economics, 7(1), 32-58. Ward, T. (1994). The origins of the Canadian wheat boom, 1880-1910. The Canadian Journal of Economics, 27(4), 865-883. 28 Table 1 Real Agriculture, Manufacturing and Total GNP, Selected Years, ($000) (1900=100) Year 1871 1881 1891 1896 1901 1911 1913 Agriculture 111,184 175,912 170,881 168,375 246,703 348,753 388,359 Manufacturing 80,421 120,651 172,503 156,859 206,353 418,651 444,750 Total GNP 345,454 529,788 666,670 649,313 996,284 1,849,412 2,138,683 Source: Altman (1992), Tables 1 & 2. Altman’s variant A GNP estimates are used for column (3). The components of the agriculture sector include dairy products, other animal products, wheat, other field crops and other outputs. The components of manufacturing are food & beverages, tobacco & products, rubber products, leather products, textile products, clothing, wood products, paper, printing & publishing, iron & steel products, transportation equipment, non-ferrous metal products, electrical apparatus & supplies, nonmetallic mineral products, petroleum & coal products, chemical products and other miscellaneous industries. 29 Figure 1. Real Agricultural and Manufacturing Output, 1871-1913 500,000 450,000 400,000 350,000 $ (x1,000) 300,000 Agriculture Manufacturing 250,000 200,000 150,000 100,000 50,000 0 1865 1870 1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910 1915 1920 Year Figure 2. Tradable, Lagging and Non-tradable Labor Demand Curves LNT’ Wage LT’ LNT LL LT G w B w’ w A ONT M M’ M’’ OT Source: Corden & Neary (1982), Figure 1. 30 Table 2. Employment and Employment in Agriculture, 1871-1911 (thousands of persons). Year 1871 1881 1891 1901 1911 Total Gainfully Occupied Total Engaged in Agriculture 1130 1378 1606 1783 2724 579 667 744 717 958 Proportion Engaged in Agriculture Annualized labor growth rates in agriculture 0.51 0.48 0.46 0.40 0.35 1.4 1.1 -0.4 2.9 Source:Urquhart (1986), Table 2.7. Table 3. Employment in Manufacturing, 1870-1910 (thousands of persons) Year 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 Total Manufacturing Employment 182 248 353 414 500 Annualized labor growth rates in manufacturing 3.1 3.6 1.6 1.9 Source:Altman (1987), Table 7, (in the footnote). Altman’s Urquhart adjusted figures are used for column (2). 31 Figure 3. Price Series - Canada 1870-1913 150 140 130 Price Index 120 Non-tradables to Tradables Ratio 110 Overall Prices 100 90 80 70 1865 1870 1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910 1915 1920 Year Source: Dick & Floyd (1992), Table B. 2. 32 Table 4. Tariff Rates in Canada, selected sectors, 1879-1913 Sector Wheat Meat pre-1879 none -- 1879 $0.15/bushel -- 1887 $0.15/bushel -- 1894 $0.12/bushel -- 1907-1913 $0.12/bushel $0.02 $0.03/lb. -$1.08/100 lb. Butter Sugar (refined) Coal $0.04/lb. 25% $0.04/lb 35% --- --- none $0.50/ton -- -- Agr. implements Pig iron Slabs, blooms, loops or billets Stoves and castings Iron wire nails Bolts, rivets, nuts Cotton (grey or unbleached) Wool (blankets etc.) Clothing (wool) Boots and shoes All other goods not otherwise specified 17.5% 25% 20-35% 20%-25% $0.00 $0.53/ton 17.5%-20% none 5% $2.00/ton 12.5% $4.00/ton $9.00/ton 27.5% $5.00/ton $2.50/ton $2.50/ton 17.5% 25% 30% 27.5% $7.00/ton -- 30% 30% 27.5% 30% -- 30% 30% 27.5% 30% 17.5% $0.01/sq. yd 22%-30% and 15% 22%-30% 25%-32.5% 17.5% $0.075/lb and 20% 20%-27.5% 20%-30% 30%-35% 17.5% 25% 25% 30% 35% 17.5% 25% -- -- 30% 17.5% 20% 20% 20% -- Source: Annis (1936). Canada instituted a preferential tariff in 1907, with an lower rate for British imports than for imports from other countries. The higher, general tariff is listed in column (5) as Canada imported most of their goods from the U.S. at this time. The symbol ‘—‘ means data was not available. 33 Table 5. C. P. R. Real (hourly) Wage Rates for different skill levels, 1901-1913 (1913=100) Year 1901 1913 Machinists labor) 71.5 100.0 (Skilled Helpers labor) 79.7 100.0 (Semi-skilled Laborers labor) 86.4 100.0 (Unskilled Source: Mackinnon (1996), Table 5. Table 6. GNP in selected non-tradable sectors, 1870-1910 Sector Construction Transportation Electric Light and Power Communications Residential Rent TOTAL Non-tradable Prices (1890=100) Real Non-tradable output Real Rent 1871 1880 21000 20400 22609 25001 ----21959 27275 65568 72676 118 111 55566.1 65473.9 18609.32 24572.1 Year 1890 1900 1910 30100 32500 158500 40460 62083 153591 936 1700 9503 745 1818 10401 37493 60453 132764 109734 158554 464759 100 99 135 109734 160156 344266 37493 61063.6 98343.7 Source: Urquhart (1986), Table 2.1. Non-tradables prices are from Dick & Floyd (1992), Table B.2. 34 Figure 4. Real Non-tradable Output 500000 450000 Real Output (x $1000) (1890=100) 400000 350000 300000 250000 Real Nontradable Output Real rent . 200000 150000 100000 50000 0 1865 1870 1875 1880 1885 1890 1895 1900 1905 1910 1915 1920 Year Table 7. Relative Capital Intensities and price and wage movements kL > kNT kL < kNT kL > k B pNT ↑, w ↑ pNT ↓, w ↑ kL < k B pNT ↓, w ↓ pNT ↑, w ↓ 35 Figure 5. Causal Relationships between the three economic sectors, wages and prices Increase in Productivity due to technology + Supply of Manufacturing Sector Labor Manufacturing Sector Output - + Demand for Agricultural Sector Labor + World Price Increase for Agricultural Output + Resource Effect Agricultural Output + + Real GDP + Real Wages + Demand for Non Tradable Output + + Spending Effect + Non Tradable Sector Output + Non Tradables Prices Real Appreciation Demand for Non Tradable Sector Labor + 36 Figure 6. Response to increased farmland areas – various indicators. (farm land area growth rate=8% per year). Wages - Agriculture (Booming) vs. Manufacturing+ Non Tradable Sector (Lagging) Real Output by Sector 4 20 M 3.25 15 M 2.5 10 M 1.75 5M 1 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 24 26 28 Total Canadian Agricultural Output : Corden Neary Total Canadian MF Output : Corden Neary Total Canadian NT Output : Corden Neary 30 tonnes tonnes tonnes 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 24 26 Booming Sector Wages : Corden Neary Lagging Sector Wages : Corden Neary 28 30 dollars/hour dollars/hour Relative Non Tradable to Tradable Price Levels (1890=100) Nominal and Real GDP (1890=100) 200 600 M 170 500 M 400 M 140 300 M 110 200 M 80 0 0 2 4 6 Non Tradable to Tradable Price Index : Corden Neary 8 10 12 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 24 26 28 2 30 Dmnl 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 Real GDP : Corden Neary Nominal GDP : Corden Neary 24 26 28 30 dollars dollars 37 Figure 7. Labor supply response to increasing farmland areas (farmland area growth rate=8% per year). Agriculture (Booming) and Manufacturing+Non-Tradable Sector (Lagging) Labor Supply Lagging Sector Labor Distribution 2M 600,000 1.5 M 450,000 1M 300,000 500,000 150,000 0 0 0 2 4 6 Booming Sector Labor Supply : Corden Neary Lagging Sector Labor Supply : Corden Neary 8 10 12 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 people people 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 Manufacturing Sector Labor Supply : Corden Neary Non Tradable Sector Labor Supply : Corden Neary 24 26 28 30 people people 38 Figure 8. Response to increased farmland areas with variable labor (farmland area growth rate=8% per year, immigration rate=2% per year, emigration rate=1.5% per year). Wages - Agriculture (Booming) vs. Manufacturing+ Non Tradable Sector (Lagging) Real Output by Sector 8 60 M 6 45 M 4 30 M 2 15 M 0 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 24 26 28 Total Canadian Agricultural Output : FullModel Total Canadian MF Output : FullModel Total Canadian NT Output : FullModel 30 tonnes tonnes tonnes 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 24 26 Booming Sector Wages : FullModel Lagging Sector Wages : FullModel 28 30 dollars/hour dollars/hour Relative Non Tradable to Tradable Price Levels (1890=100) Nominal and Real GDP (1890=100) 200 2B 170 1.5 B 1B 140 500 M 110 0 80 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 24 26 28 Non Tradable to Tradable Price Index : FullModel 2 4 6 8 10 12 30 Dmnl 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 24 26 28 Real GDP : FullModel Nominal GDP : FullModel 30 dollars dollars Agriculture (Booming) and Manufacturing+Non-Tradable Sector (Lagging) Labor Supply Lagging Sector Labor Distribution 2M 2M 1.5 M 1.5 M 1M 1M 500,000 500,000 0 0 0 2 4 Booming Sector Labor Supply : FullModel Lagging Sector Labor Supply : FullModel 6 8 10 12 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 people people 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 Time (year) 18 20 22 Manufacturing Sector Labor Supply : FullModel Non Tradable Sector Labor Supply : FullModel 24 26 28 30 people people 39 Figure 9. Sensitivity analysis of wages, output and non-tradable prices to the degree of manufacturing sector tradability Parameter and Range Tested: Elasticity of manufacturing sector labor demand to real GDP, 0-10. Note that an elasticity of 0 represents complete tradability. ElasticitySensitivity Corden Neary 50% 75% 95% Booming Sector Wages 6 100% 4.5 Wages 3 1.5 0 0 ElasticitySensitivity Corden Neary 50% 75% 95% Total Canadian MF Output 20 M 7.5 15 Time (year) 22.5 30 7.5 15 Time (year) 22.5 30 7.5 15 Time (year) 22.5 30 100% 15 M Manufacturing Output 10 M 5M 0 0 ElasticitySensitivity Corden Neary 50% 75% 95% 100% Total Canadian Agricultural Output 20 M 15 M Agricultural Output 10 M 5M 0 0 40 ElasticitySensitivity Corden Neary 50% 75% 95% 100% Non Tradable to Tradable Price Index 200 170 Non Tradable Price Index 140 110 80 0 7.5 15 Time (year) 22.5 30 41