Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Chapter 2 Inclusive Growth for Latin America Tito Yepes1 2.1. Introduction 1. The World Development Report of 2009 establishes density, distance, and division as dimensions challenging both the potential for higher economic growth and equality of opportunities. Density and distance in particular are central to the discussion on economic growth, as they are the reasons for its unbalance across locations. This chapter aims to qualify density and distance within the Latin American context. 2. Benefiting from unbalanced growth refers to the opportunities arising from market forces that lead to a concentration of economic activity in a few locations. Policy makers and political economy actors sometimes consider the concentration of economic activities in a limited number of locations as constituting a challenge to progress. Here, we illustrate that such concentration is a consequence of market forces beyond the control of policymakers. We further suggest that geography transformation can lead to a higher efficiency with respect to any given location’s economic activities, sometimes generating higher concentration, and thus leading to higher economic growth. The provision of an equality of opportunities for all of a country’s inhabitants, regardless of location, is perfectly compatible with a high spatial concentration of economic growth, as discussed in chapter 6. 3. The reason that growth does not occur with balance is because of the productivity differences that confront firms across locations. As different locations offer different advantages for the efficient use of factors most firms competitively locate where it is most advantageous to them. Productivity advantages in likewise differ across location, depending on the nature of interaction between local agents or distance to other locations. Locations cannot share the same space, likewise, they do not have the same number of agents; consequently, by definition, locations offer different advantages. 1 The author thanks Darwin Marcelo for the excellent assistance provided in the elaboration of this chapter. 4. Locations offer two types of productivity advantages: (1) agglomeration economies if the advantage is due to cost saving interaction between firms located within the location; and (2) logistics if the advantage is due to relative closeness to local and distant consumers.2 We use agglomeration economies to qualify the benefits to growth caused by population density. A higher density of population offers firms a higher potential to observe agglomeration economies. Logistics is a qualification of distance that refers to the total costs faced by firms in reaching their costumers, whether local or not, inclusive of non-monetary costs. In large urban areas, advantages exist that do not require agglomeration economies, as firms are able to access a large pool of costumers. Here we consider this as part of the logistics—firms will attempt to minimize their costs for accessing all costumers (local or otherwise), so if they set up in cities in order to access more costumers, they benefit from better logistics compared with if they are located in smaller urban areas. Figure 2.1a. Spatial Sources of Productivity Advantages and Unbalanced Growth. Stronger Agglomeration Economies High Growth Low Growth Figure 2.1b. Productivity Advantages and Types of Locations. Stronger Agglomeration Economies Advanced urbanization Intermediate urbanization (Rural and small urban) Incipient urbanization Better Logistics Better Logistics Source: own elaboration based on the WDR09. 5. In Figure 2 we represent how agglomeration economies and logistics can lead to higher economic growth. The vertical axis in Figure 2.1a represents the strength of agglomeration economies. If a location has weaknesses on that front, it may be able to compensate with better logistics (the horizontal axis); the same is true in reverse—i.e., if 2 The migration of production factors across locations is a third source of higher productivity. Inasmuch as such factors are not location specific, they are analyzed in another chapter of this report. the case is relatively poor with respect to logistics. That said, with either weak agglomeration economies or bad logistics, it becomes more difficult to achieve a high economic growth rate. Locations with strong agglomeration economies and good logistics should be able to grow faster than locations lacking with respect to the one or the other. 6. In theory, any location can develop both types of advantages. It only requires creating the proper firms, firms that can consistently interact with others at the targeted location, and make the necessary infrastructure investments for achieving good logistics. Unfortunately, locations that already have firms and consumers are more likely to benefit from policy interventions oriented to economic growth than areas with no prior concentration of firms. Locations already hosting firms and consumers are more likely to have some degree of interaction and some quality of logistics, though, respectively, not necessarily strong or good. 7. Furthermore, the more firms and consumers at a given location, the more likely the firms will benefit from any kind of intervention (intended or not) with respect to agglomeration economies or logistics. That’s why the densest locations are more likely to observe higher economic growth. Growth is spatially unbalanced to the extent that patterns of density and isolation are unbalanced, so are patterns of agglomeration economies and logistics. Figure 2.1b provides a classification of locations based on density. The circles are larger where population densities are higher and match areas where growth is more likely to be higher. 8. Policies can nonetheless reinforce both agglomeration economies and logistics. However, one should be careful as to where and how to intervene. The farther a location is from densely populated areas, the less effective will be any intervention. Also areas within countries requiring or desiring policies aimed at improving their advantages are numerous, forcing policymakers or the political economy to choose where to implement such policies based on some criteria of potential opportunities 9. The fact that agglomeration economies and logistics create unbalanced growth may also bring about the phenomenon of lagging regions. Locations with structurally low growth may show a low level of participation in the economy over a number of years, and as a consequence, may become lagging regions if their of their population don’t migrate to growth centers. With low local growth, there are fewer resources to be distributed, and the challenges in allocating resources among many alternative locations become complex. This can be potentially inefficient for growth. 10. The fact that growth resulting from interventions aimed at promoting agglomeration economies and improving logistics will more likely benefit denser locations does not mean that other areas should be abandoned. However, more proper instruments (such as institutions for providing universal access to basic services) should be employed rather than those aimed at developing agglomeration economies or logistics from scratch, which are unlikely to be efficient. 11. The rest of the chapter provides a prospective review of unbalanced growth in Latin America, and delineates policy actions through … 2.2. The Path to Distance 12. The role of agglomeration economies and logistics in enhancing productivity and scale is first determined by the initial location of towns and cities. Location is determined by the conjunction of history with geographical factors. For instance, natural resources may drive firms or farms to locate near one another, which may in turn help to develop agglomeration economies and the institutional dynamics for lowering transportation costs. Little explains why cities are located where they are today apart from historical events and the existence of harbor natural resources. 13. The geography of Latin America and the Caribbean is not uniform, neither the patterns of population settlement. On the Atlantic side of South America, most areas consist of plateaus, plains or low lands, while along the Andes, from Mexico to Chile, most areas consist of hills or mountains. Figure 2.2a shows that a high proportion of the territory in Middle American countries consists of hills or mountains; the same is true for a high proportion of the Andean countries in South America. Conversely, the Atlantic side is flatter. Some Caribbean islands contain a large proportion of highlands, such as the Dominican Republic, Jamaica and Haiti. 14. It appears that terrain characteristics have not had a major impact on present density patterns. The comparison of terrain and agglomerations provides a quick description of Latin America’s geography. Figure 2.2b provides a comparison of the agglomeration index developed by the WDR 2009 for Latin American countries with the index of proportion of territories with hills or mountains. The agglomeration index perfects the measure of urbanization by correcting for contiguity of population concentrations. Countries with a high agglomeration and with highlands include El Salvador, Chile, Mexico, or Dominican Republic. In the extreme countries, such as Guyana, Nicaragua and Paraguary, we find low agglomerations and relatively flat lands. Figure 2.2b. Urban agglomeration versus terrain. 0 50 100 Proportion of Territory with Hills or Mountains SLV CHL CRI 80 HND JAM PAN PER 60 GTM ECU MEX DOM CUB 40 BOL GUY ARG VEN COL NIC 20 Terrain : Hills and Mountains Middle America .01 .02 Andean HTI BRA SUR PRY URY 0 Atlantic South America 0 Density: Kernel .03 100 Figure 2.2a. Proportion of territories with hills and mountains. 20 40 60 80 Agglomeration Index Source: based on WDR 2009. 15. Categorization on the basis of terrain characteristics produces two very different and (relatively far-apart) sides—the Andes and the Atlantic (Brazil, Argentina, Uruguay and Paraguay). The main cities in the Andes are located far from the key waterways, reflecting the sophisticated system of transport and production of the pre-Hispanic tribes. In the case of the Incas, transport was based on routes connecting centers of civilization along a north-south axis, running alongside the mountains. The Maya and Aztec societies were organized into many groups or clans, whose agricultural production relied on the high productivity of the Andes’ valleys. 16. Pre-Hispanic tribes living alongside the Andes where located on the adjacent flatlands, where the availability of water and arable land was relatively better and there was scarce trade with tribes located far away (thus eliminating the need for sea transportation). In most cases, the Spaniards founded their cities in locations where there was already an indigenous settlement in order to be close to potential sources of precious metals. In fact, it was trade in gold and silver and other commodities that drove most of the exchange between Spain and the colonies, leading to transportation routes suited for extraction rather than for linking the economy. 17. The notable exception of the Andes corresponds to the case of Peru, where the Incans had their capital. The fight between the Spaniards and Incans for control of the territory lasted nearly fifty years. To carry out their conquest, the Spaniards were forced to strengthen their sea port of Lima so as to effectively provide their armies with food and ammunition. The Incan capital of Cuzco was destroyed in the end, permanently moving the economic center of the country to Lima. Over the years, Lima benefited from the silver trade originating in the Potosi mines, and became one of the main economic centers in South America during the colonial period. Initially, Guayaquil in Ecuador, which was meant to constitute the only shipyard in the Spanish colonies, was more prominent than Lima. However the resources generated from silver exports saw Lima eventually become more important. 18. The trade flows during the colonial period reinforced the prominence of a few coastal cities along the Andes. The Spaniards restricted trade with their colonies to Spanish goods, banning from trading all Pacific ports outside Lima and Veracruz. Trade went from Sevilla to Cartagena, and then to Portobelo (a port in Panama that was destroyed by pirates in the seventeenth century), where it was transported by land to the Pacific. From there, goods were shipped to Callao (Lima) and Veracruz (see Figure 2.3a). All supplies from Europe were transported by land from Lima to Santiago and even up to Buenos Aires and Montevideo. Some goods were transported from the one ocean to the other and back, something which created an opportunity for smuggling and pirating on the Atlantic side of South America. But trade other than that in metals was minimal, as the colonies were generally self-sufficient. The Potosi mines represented the major source of cargo, and is said to have produced two-thirds of the total silver exported to Spain during the colonial period. This made Lima the most prominent city of the Viceroyalty of Peru. Free trade was only opened in the late-eighteenth century. Figure 2.3a. Routes of trade during the seventeenth century. Figure 2.3b. Location of the main cities of Latin America. Monterrey Havana Guadalajara Mexico City Santo Domingo Guatemala Tegucigalpa Caracas Managua San Jose Panama Guayaquil Medellin Bogota Cali Manaus Quito Belem Fortaleza Recife Lima Brasilia Salvador La Paz Belo Horizonte Rio de Janeiro Asuncion Sao Paulo Curitiba Cordoba Porto Alegre Rosario Montevideo Santiago Buenos Aires Source: Based on Clayton(1975), and Herbert Source: own elaboration. and dos Santos (1973) 3. 19. On the Atlantic side of South America, most of the key cities are located along the coast—Rio de Janeiro, Buenos Aires and Montevideo—or close to it—Sao Paulo. They evolved from ports and trading centers in countries that did not have large interior preHispanic cities (See Figure 2.3b). These cities were highly integrated with North L. A. Clayton. “Trade and Navigation in the Seventeenth-Century Viceroyalty of Peru” in Journal of Latin American Studies (Cambridge University Press), Vol. 7, No. 1, 1975.. Herbert S. Klein and Mario R. dos Santos. “Las finanzas del Virreinato del Rio de la Plata en 1790 Desarrollo Económico, Vol. 13, No. 50, 1973. Published by: Instituto de Desarrollo Económico y Social. 3 American and European trade because of their natural capacity for large scale agriculture and cattle production. Other interior cities, such as those in Argentina, developed later on the basis of monopolies imposed by Spain that allowed them to compete, and as part of an alternate route for the transport of silver from Peru, developed because of attacks on Portobello (Panama). It is this route that determined the region’s name, the Viceroyalty of La Plata, in 1776. 20. The main cities in Brazil, Paraguay, Uruguay, and Argentina are closer to waterways and, generally speaking, the transportation networks linking them are better structured. It makes these cities more complementary to one another compared to the cities of the Andes, which generally became self-sufficient. The main cities of the Andes are best understood as hubs of their respective countries and sub-regions; they therefore tend to be somewhat similar to one another in terms of function, as they all suffered from isolation and some degree of autarky. 21. The Central American countries also suffer from long (economically speaking) distances from one another. These countries have followed very similar patterns of development, making them very similar in terms of their economic development. Crosscountry infrastructure remains underdeveloped and fragile, with most efforts concentrated on reaching either the Pacific or Atlantic Ocean rather than neighboring countries. Yet as in the Andes and Mexico, the main population concentrations are relatively far from the coasts, something which reflects the relative low development of trade between the main pre-Hispanic tribes. During the colonial period, Central American cities tended to be neglected; the Spaniards gave greater importance to Mexico City and Veracruz on account of the nearby silver mines of Zacatecas and Guanajuato. Central American cities were located far from the commerce centers located on either side of the region, whether in Mexico or Panama. 22. The Caribbean islands provide a natural scenario for testing for the existence of agglomeration forces as drivers of economics growth. There exist few land borders with other countries, and the concentration of their populations in the seaports developed naturally. Still the concentration of economic activities is uneven, and it does not occur on any side of the islands. Specific factors related to agglomeration, rather than pure historical accident, may explain and justify the existence of agglomeration forces. 23. For instance, in Jamaica, Montego Bay and Port Antonio experienced similar initial conditions in developing into tourism hubs. However it is the former that developed as the economic center of the country’s tourism industry. Today, because of the low quality of the roads, it takes more time to go to Port Antonio than to Montego Bay, despite the fact that the distance from Kingston is quadruple that from Montego Bay. Roads in the country were developed as a function of the sugar and bauxite production located nearby Montego Bay, which also saw the development of a rich entrepreneurial class in connection with the commodities trade. Today Montego Bay has 120.000 inhabitants, with the highest income per capita in the country, world class tourism facilities like the largest airport of the country, and expensive real estate condominiums, restaurants and stores. Port Antonio in turn has only 15.000 inhabitants, and its tourism strength is ecological, with a completely different set of facilities. 24. The historical patterns of location and production of the pre-Hispanic tribes in the rich valleys of the Andes; the patterns of trade imposed by the Spaniards during the colonial period; and natural resources (like the silver mines of Potosi) and the huge valleys found in the south constitute three major determinants of the location of major Latin American cities. These factors established the distances observed today between local production and consumption centers and international markets within the region and abroad. Two general patterns are observed: cities close to the coast and with complementarities on the Atlantic side of South America, and interior cities with substitutability alongside the Andes. 25. Linkages between neighboring countries are fewer in the Andes compared with the Atlantic coast of South America. Except for Bolivia (landlocked) and Mexico (whose trade is mostly with the United States), those countries alongside the Andes have the lowest levels of trade with their neighbors. Compared with Argentina, Uruguay and Paraguay, Brazil has highly diversified trade partnerships, making its trade with southern neighbors less prominent (see Figure 2.4.). Figure 2.4. Share of trade with neighboring countries. (% of total trade) 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 C Ve h ile ne zu e E c la ua d Co or lo m bi a Pe ru Bo Co livi a st a Ri c Pa a na m Ho a nd u r G ua as te m al Ni ca a ra g El ua Sa lv ad or M ex ico Br az Ar i ge l nt in a Ur ug ua Pa y ra gu ay 0 Source: WDR 2009 Annexes. 26. The difficult logistics created by the Andes also have an impact on countries’ internal linkages, as illustrated by the case of Colombia. An analysis of regional economic interaction shows that the major seven regions of the country compete with, rather than complement, one another—growth in one of them results in a decrease in the share in trade of the other regions Bonet (2003, 2005).4 If the coefficient between two regions has a negative sign (See Table 2.1), it signals that there is a competitive relationship; if the coefficient is positive, this means that there is a complementary relationship. The regions with the largest shares in the country’s GDP—Bogotá, WestCentral, and Pacific—as well as that with the highest growth rate—New Departments— 4 Their analysis is based on Dendrinos-Sonis (1988, 1990), whose approach assesses the competition or complementarity between a country’s sub-regions. In this case, they measure the relative share of GDP of regions in Colombia over time, and examine whether the growth of some regions comes at the expense of others, or respective growths are complementary. Elasticity is estimated for each pair of regions. exhibit competitive relationships, such that their rapid growth results in a decrease in the share of the other regions. Table 2.1 Competitive and complementary relationships among Colombia’s sub-regions. NorthCentral SouthCentral Caribbean Pacific New Depts. Bogotá WestCentral Caribbean + + + + - - - North-Central + - - - - - - New Depts. - - - - + - - West-Central - - - - - - - South-Central - - - - - - - Pacific - - - - - - + Note: A positive sign indicates complementary and a negative sign, a competitive relationship. Source: Bonet (2005). 27. These low interregional links means that most economic sectors at a regional level are self-sufficient, with most providers of forward and backward linkages concentrating in the three richest cities in Colombia. Some analysts have pointed out that the high transportation costs in Colombia, associated with weak infrastructure, are one of the leading causes of the low spatial and sector interaction. Because transportation weaknesses reduce the potential for economic growth, the obstacles for better interregional links are greater (World Bank 2004c, 2005; Cardenas, et. al., 2005; and Perez 2005). 28. With respect to the Atlantic side, the linkages between regions are stronger. For instance, Brazil’s Southeast initiates most of the supply chains for every region. Figure 2.5 shows that Brazil’s regions are very well connected, such Southeast forms the base for almost the entire production chain, not only for itself, but for all the other regions as well. Both with respect to backward and forward linkages, every region is sourced by Southeast by at least 60%. linkages (diagonally). Furthermore, the Center and North miss within region Figure 2.5. Interregional linkages in Brazil. (Share of value by source) b. Forward a. Backward 80% 80% 60% 60% 40% 40% 20% 20% South 0% st ea uth So uth So r nte Ce Ce nte r t as th e No th No No th Source e Us South ea st 0% st ea uth So uth So r nte Ce Ce nte r th No st ea th No No th e Us Source Source: Based on the interregional I/O matrix in Hadad et al. 2.3. Benefiting from Density 29. Latin American countries are diverse in terms of density and distances between the main urban areas; consequently, they are diverse in terms of opportunities for growth. The densest locations have accumulated higher participations in national economies, while income differences across countries’ locations have remained persistent. Notwithstanding, Latin America’s growth has benefited overall from density. 30. The densest locations have accumulated the largest participations in national economies because of their respective higher long-term growth. Figure 2.6 shows population densities and participations in national production by countries’ sub-regions. Participation in national production is the accumulation of growth rates over a number of years. Sub-regions are grouped into four clusters5 according to their density and 5 Calculated using the Ward criterion, which minimizes the loss of information by minimizing the square distance between each observation and the group centroid. participation in GDP. Group 1 is made up of regions with incipient urbanization and very low participation in the national economy—they qualified considered as lagging regions. This group includes among others Colombia’s Pacific, Guatemala’s Petén, and Brazil’s North. 4 1 1 2 3 4 2 3 0 Ln( Participation in National Product ) Figure 2.6. Density and participation in the national economy. Latin American countries’ sub-regions -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 Ln( Population Density ) Source: own elaboration based on … 31. On the other side of the distribution (Group 4) are those regions with advanced urbanization—these region, such as Costa Rica’s central valley, Southeast Brazil, Colombia’s central region, Peru’s coast, and Argentina’s Gran Buenos Aires, include Latin America’s main cities. Between these two extremes, we have two classifications for areas of intermediate urbanization. Group 2 is made up of regions that have low density relative to areas of advanced urbanization, though benefiting from substantial participation in national economies. This group includes Argentina’s Pampa, Bolivia’s La Paz and Santa Cruz, Colombia’s east, Mexico’s northeast, and Nicaragua’s Atlantic coast. Finally, we have Group 3, made up of areas that have high density and low participation in national economies—among these are Colombia’s Atlantic coast and Chile’s Valparaiso. 32. Differences in income per capita across locations have been persistent for most countries. There is limited evidence of regional convergence in income per capita within Latin American countries. An IMF6 review shows that there are signs of income convergence in Chile, Colombia, and Peru, but at a very slow pace. For example it would take nearly 60 years to close half the gap between regions in Chile. Brazil has displayed an even slower pace of convergence, and it is estimated that the regions in Argentina and Mexico have not experienced any convergence at all. Furthermore, in some countries, there have not even been short-term episodes of income convergence between subregions. Analyzing Argentina7 over a 31-year period, with sub-periods of about 10 years, the estimated speeds of convergence yielded insignificant coefficients. In Colombia, there is relative agreement as to the lack of long-term income convergence, though there is some dissent concerning certain periods of catch-up in lagging regions. In the cases of Mexico, Brazil, Peru, and Colombia, there is evidence of clubs or groups of sub-regions that have been able to catch with one another internally, but with increasing disparities between clubs. 33. Urbanization or densification of specific locations has had a positive impact on economic growth in most Latin American countries. Overall, Latin America has seen the most rapid urbanization process ever recorded, surpassing every other developing region. There exists a clear association between economic growth and urbanization in many of the region’s countries. For instance, during the twentieth century, Brazil went through a rapid process of urbanization that closely correlated with long-term trends in economic growth (see Figure 2.7a). Urbanization helped to improve the productivity of factors that later transmitted into economic growth. An analysis of statistical causality shows a positive and persistent impact from urbanization on growth in Brazil (see Figure 2.7b, the red line). The same exercise for different countries shows similar patterns when it is significant. Bolivia shows the opposite effect, with urbanization having a negative and persistent impact on growth. 6 Regional Convergence in Latin America. by María Isabel Serra, María Fernanda Pazmino, Genevieve Lindow, Bennett Sutton, Gustavo Ramírez, The International Monetary Fund, 2006. 7 Garrido et al. (2000), Marina (2000), and Figueras et al. (2003). Figure 2.7a. Long-run trends of urbanization and growth in Brazil. Figure 2.7b. Long-run trends of urbanization and growth in Brazil. 0.08 BRASIL MEXICO 0.06 COLOMBIA Cumulative response: GROWTH BOLIVIA URUGUAY 0.04 0.02 0 -0.02 -0.04 -0.06 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Years of Impact 2.4. Cities Transforming Under The Pressure of Density 34. Cities are perhaps the most important and most visible manifestation of economies of scale, and play a central role in economic growth. Firms located in cities (especially larger and denser cities) could benefit from those advantages associated with situations wherein there exits proximity between similar firms working in the same sector (the localization of economies) as well as proximity to firms in other sectors (the urbanization of economies). (Duranton and Puga 2003; Glaeser 2007). By bringing together pools of entrepreneurs with similar economic interests, cities facilitate both the creation of new ideas and the translation of ideas into production. Besides these knowledge spillovers, by creating thick markets for labor, capital, and intermediate and final goods, cities enable cost savings and efficiency. 35. Cities are more competitive when firms are able to fully exploit the location advantage provided by agglomeration economies and better logistics—that is, when firms efficiently use the supply chain typical of the sector in which they operate, have easy access to consumers, and show deep linkages (and spillovers) with firms of the same or other sectors. 36. Cities are also evidence of the existence of negative externalities. Size and proximity (which are inherent to agglomeration economies) often lead to traffic congestion, pollution, and other drawbacks that can weaken a city’s performance and possibly lead both firms and households to relocate to areas with better environments for life and productivity. To remain competitive, cities need to maximize their agglomeration economies while maintaining logistics that contain congestion costs, thereby enhancing the productivity edge that firms gain by locating there. 37. In Latin America, 29 cities in seven Latin American countries concentrate at least one percent of national GDP. Figure 2.8 shows the economies of each of these 29 cities and 7 countries (in total GDP at international prices) indexed relative to Sao Paulo. Sao Paulo, Buenos Aires, and Mexico City are by far the largest economic centers, with Rio de Janeiro occupying a strong but distant fourth place. However, Sao Paulo only ranks ninth in per capita GDP. By this measure, México City is the wealthiest city, followed by Monterrey and Brasilia. The economy of Sao Paulo by itself is larger than the national GDP of every country in the region except Brazil, Mexico, Argentina, Venezuela, and Colombia. 6.0 0.83 1.00 1.00 0.93 Figure 2.8. Relative GDP of selected cities and countries. 0.90 5.0 GDPj / GDP SAO PULO 0.70 0.43 0.60 0.28 0.24 0.24 0.22 0.17 0.17 0.16 0.15 0.15 0.14 0.14 0.12 0.10 0.07 0.02 0.05 0.02 La Paz 0.04 0.01 el Salvador 0.02 0.01 Antofagasta 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 Bolivia Chile El Salvador São Paulo Colombia Mexico São Paulo Buenos Aires Distrito Federal (Mx) Rio de Janeiro Bogotá D. C. Monterrey Belo Horizonte Guadalajara Campinas Santiago Rosario Salvador Juárez Curitiba DF (Br) Cordoba Puebla Medellín Recife Cali Mendoza Fortaleza Barranquilla Concepción Santa Cruz Argentina 0.0 0.00 Brazil 0.10 Cochabamba 0.20 0.10 0.30 0.21 0.40 0.29 0.50 0.09 GDPi/GDP SAO PAULO 0.80 Sources: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database (October 2007); Instituto Nacional de Estadística Geografía e Informática de México (2000,2004); Instituto Nacional de Estadísticas y Censos de Argentina (1993, 2001); Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (2004); Instituto Alexander Von Humboldt (2003) y Departamento Administrativo Nacional de Estadística de Colombia (2003); and Sistema Nacional de Información Municipal de Chile (2006). Note: GDP indexed relative to Sao Paulo. 38. Argentina and Chile have a high concentration of economic activity in their capitals, although the second most major city in Chile also has substantial importance. Brazil, Colombia, Mexico and Bolivia share a similar structure with many important urban centers. Chile and Colombia’s cities are the best served in terms of access to basic infrastructure services. Buenos Aires and Mexico City have relatively low levels of service compared to their rank for other economic variables. By contrast, many cities with middle- or even low-ranking GDP per capita, such as Sao Paulo, Santiago, Antofagasta, Bogotá, and Cali, are at the top of the rankings for access to water. 39. The most important six capital cities in Latin America concentrate nearly one fifth (or more) of their country’s respective GDP and at least double the GDP share of their country’s respective second most major city. The contribution of Buenos Aires (46%) and Santiago (31%) are five times that of Rosario (9%) and Concepción (6%) respectively; Bogotá’s contribution (24%) is 2.5 times Medellín (9%); México DF (22%) is 3.1 times Monterrey (7%); and Sao Paulo (17%) is 2.3 times Rio de Janeiro (7%). Bolivia has two main economic centers--La Paz (20%) and Santa Cruz de la Sierra (21%). Box 1. Basic indicators for the main cities of Latin America. Source: Author’s elaboration based on national sources. 40. The benefits that can be extracted from urbanization are, however, limited. As the proportion of a population living in cities reaches a high level, the benefits in terms of home market strengthening and agglomeration economies diminish. Major cities that have contributed largely to job creation begin to face substantial problems of congestion reflected in more difficult logistics, high land prices that discourage new firms from locating there, and longer commutes for workers. Under such circumstances, manufacturing firms begin to consider the possibility of relocating outside major cities, provided they can continue to feed into its supply chain. Among the many towns generally surrounding major cities, some will align their advantages and attract firms and jobs. As such, core cities transform into services providers and hosts of firm interaction. 41. Consequently, major economic centers do not contribute as much to national growth as relatively well-located smaller cities become more competitive for new firms and jobs. In the case of Brazil, major cities show lower growth rates compared with smaller cities8. Apparently, the same process has been evident in other Latin American countries in terms of the relationship between major cities and smaller ones (see Figure 2.9). Mexico City, Sao Paulo, and Santiago grew less than Monterrey, Curitiba and Antofagasta respectively. Rio de Janeiro and Sao Paulo grew less (40% and 20%, respectively) than the national growth rate for the period 1970-2000. By contrast, urban areas of over 2 million people or less than 1 million grew by at least 20% more than the national average in the same period. 1. If Index>1, the urban area’s growth is higher then national. If the Index < 1, it is lower. 2.404 Figure 2.9. City growth over national growth. a. Selected Latin American cities b. Brazilian cities 2 42. 1.45 1.42 1.37 1.37 1.00 0.55 0.61 0.62 Bogotá Concepción Porto Alegre Guadalajara Santiago Campinas Fortaleza Puebla Belo Horizonte Recife Curitiba Juares Monterrey DF (Br) Antofagasta 0.92 0.52 São Paulo 1 2 1 4 3 1 2 3 1 1 2 1 1 1 2 2 1 3 0.44 Salvador 1 1 Distrito Federal (Mx) 0.50 0.91 0.85 1.00 0.00 GDP growth rates for 1970-2000, by city 1.96 1.15 1.15 1.50 1.21 2.00 Rio de Janeiro 0.24 City GDP Growth/Country GDP Growth 2.50 0.6 0.8 0.9 1.0 1.1 1.1 1.1 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.3 0 RJ SP REC PA BH SAL 1-2 CAM CUR FOR < 1 2-3 In Colombia, the densest locations observed the largest growth for the period 2000-2003. By contrast, the densest locations in Mexico and Brazil had lower growth rates (negative); rather, high growth was concentrated in areas of intermediate density. Consistent and representative data on product or GDP growth by municipality is extremely difficult to find. Figure 2.10 shows the most comparable municipal data that it was possible to collect on differences in growth by density. The municipalities for each country are first collapsed into economic areas—for example, one economic area might include all municipalities within a metropolitan area. Percentiles with equal participation in national GDP are then made, so that they should be comparable in terms of their contribution to national growth. The number of percentiles is lower in Colombia and Mexico, as their capitals exhibit larger participations in national economies relative to Brazil. The sizes of the circles reflect relative population densities. Figure 2.10. GDP growth on the basis of density. Brazil 1996 – 2003 Mexico 1999-2004 Colombia 2000-2003 % % 7 4 P2 P3 P1 P2 1.5 P4 0.5 5 4 P1 P3 3 1 -1 P4 -0.5 P5 -3 Anual GDP Growth Anual GDP Growth 2.5 Anual GPD Growth % P4 3 P3 P2 3 2 P1 2 -1.5 Source: Based on data from Alexander Von Humboldt Institute for Colombia, INEGI for Mexico, and IPEA for Brazil. 43. Large cities experience transitions over time towards services-led growth. Large cities experience a pattern of change in economic activities, moving from manufacture industries to service ones. Rapidly growing cities, such as Mexico City and Sao Paulo, have seen an increase in participation for services and a steady decrease in participation for manufacturing with respect to overall economic activity, as shown in Figure 2.11. Over the last two decades, services (in particular financial and personal services) have increased their share in overall economic activity by about 3 and 8 percentage points in Mexico City and Sao Paulo, respectively. This pattern has been replicated by other major Latin American cities, where the magnitude of manufacture industries has been shrinking over time. Figure 2.11. Share of manufacture and service sectors in value added. Manufacture Industry 55.00% Service Sector 53.78% 50.00% 50.00% 42.99% 45.00% 41.95% 30.00% 30.00% 25.00% 25.00% 20.00% 17.15% 16.92% 16.60% 13.30% 15.00% 15.00% 10.00% Bogotá 1995-2005 Source: 46.29% 42.57% 42.62% 35.00% 35.00% 20.00% 45.00% 40.00% 38.91% 40.00% 54.08% 55.00% México City MA 1999-2004 Sao Paulo Meso 1985-2003 Bogotá 1995-2005 México City MA 1999-2004 Sao Paulo Meso 1985-2003 44. The transformation of economic activities has had important effects on the labor market. When labor demand increases in areas where manufacturing takes place, it becomes insufficient to absorb an increasing labor supply in the large cities. The transition from manufacturing to services creates an enabling environment for employment generation in the small and peripheral areas where manufacturing firms relocate. In Brazil, small cities with a significant entry of manufacturing firms experienced a faster pace of job creation during the nineties than the largest cities. This is what happened in Curitiba, where jobs grew at about three times the pace as in Metropolitan Sao Paulo (MRSP), as shown in Figure 2.12a. The transformation of jobs is uniform regardless of types of skills in the manufacturing sector. While there was a substantial increase in low skill jobs in the manufacturing sector in Brazil, Metropolitan Sao Paulo (MRSP) saw a large decrease. The same was true for higher levels of skills, though with sustained increases in personal and business services (see Figure 2.12b). Figure 2.12a. Job growth in the 1990s in Brazilian Cities. Jobs' growth in 1990s 50% Figure 2.12.b. Employment in manufacturing firms by skill level. % Changes in manufacturing employment (1996-2002) 25 40% 30% Whole Decade 20 First Half 10 15 MR SP Brazil 5 0 20% -5 -10 10% -15 Business services Personal services High-skilled Medium-skilled Low-skilled Curitiba Meso 1 to 2 Meso < 1 P. Alegre Meso > 2 R. Janeiro B.Horizonte Fortaleza Sao Paulo Recife Salvador -10% Campinas -20 0% Source: Based on IPEA data. 45. The transition from manufacture to services prompts the relocation of manufacturing firms outside large cities. During the transition, manufacturing firms relocate in smaller areas outside and near large cities. Sao Paulo is a clear example of a city in transition. Since the early seventies, Sao Paulo’s participation in Brazilian manufacturing has fallen consistently, from 40 percent in 1970 to less than 20 percent in 2001 (Figure 2.13a). During this period, manufacturing firms did not move out of Sao Paulo en masse but rather gradually increased their scale of production in other areas, such that between 1970 and 2003 Sao Paulo’s annual industry growth was at least 5 percentage points lower than the annual growth rate of industry in the rest of the state as well as that for all other states as a whole. Between 1970 and 2003, Sao Paulo’s industry grew at 2 percent per annum on average. This was significantly lower than the annual rates of growth of industry in the rest of the state (7.7 percent) and in all other states combined (6.8 percent). 46. The transition, and particularly the exit of manufacturing firms, was triggered by decreasing returns to scale in large cities. Differences in returns to scale state that as cities grow, the returns on economic activities in the manufacturing sector fade away faster than the returns in other sectors, such as business services (Figure 2.13b). For a certain range in population size, returns on manufacturing activities fall while returns to business services continue to increase. 47. Among the many factors influencing this transition, services themselves play a key role. As major cities develop, the services sector develops as well. Services firms fragment into areas of specialization, thus providing manufacturing firms opportunities to focus on their own productivity. In small urban areas with lower scale of production, firms generally carry their own services in-house—for instance, delivery and supply chains. In major cities, however, these components break into new firms, thus freeing manufacturing from the need to continue locating within the major city. Firms move out as far as they can to benefit from cheap land, but not too far as they wish to continue being fed by the supply chain. Figure 2.13a. Sao Paulo state and Metropolitan: share in Brazil manufacturing GDP. Figure 2.13b. Returns to scale and city size. Share of Brazilian Industrial GDP Profitability 60% The difference in returns to scale hypothesis 50% 40% 30% Manufacturing 20% State 10% Metropolitan size 0% 1940 1950 1960 1970 Source: IPEA data. 48. Business Services 1980 1990 2000 Source: own elaboration. An econometric model confirms the negative effect from size in the participation of Brazil’s largest cities (Rio de Janeiro and Sao Paulo) in national manufacturing GDP (see Table 2.2.). An instrumental variables model with data for the period 1970-2001 uses as a dependent variable the change in share in total GDP of each of the 130 sub-regions of Brazil. This is a classification that collapses all municipalities into economic areas. A second model uses only manufacturing GDP (as no data is available for other sectors). The model is instrumented using levels in the year base in order to control for endogoneity bias. The results show that when the largest cities are included in the sample, the coefficient for city size (i.e., new inhabitants) is negative for manufacturing; the coefficient, however, is not significant for total GDP. On the contrary, if Brazil’s largest cities are dropped from the sample, the impact of size turns out to be positive and significant for both manufacturing and total GDP. The results therefore confirm that there is a negative impact from increases in population size on the manufacturing GDP of Brazil’s largest cities, and, therefore, that sector transformation is a structural process, as the evidence above suggests. 49. The model also includes an indicator for changes in logistics (transport costs) and another for the dynamics of agglomeration economies (economic growth). With respect to logistics, the results suggest that better logistics—which is, in fact, the case in Brazil, where transportation costs have been decreasing steadily over the last 30 years—should promote a more even distribution of economic activities. This does not mean that it will necessarily to a completely even distribution; only that, at minimum, economic activities will not become totally concentrated in a few urban areas. Some sectors tend to become highly concentrated, and then later spread out towards other sectors, thus allowing more efficient spaces to take over manufacturing production. The existence of good logistics seems to have a catalyzing effect, such that these more efficient spaces can adequately feed off of the national supply chain. Regarding the dynamic effect of growth, which is a representation of agglomeration economies, as expected, the results are not conclusive. As agglomeration effects are not specific but rather take many forms, one should not expect to observe a common process across locations. Table 2.2. Models of participation in total and manufacturing GDP. Share winners All areas only Change in GDP Share - ** Change in Transport Costs New inhabitants - ** +* All without Rio de Janeiro or Sao Share losers only Paulo - ** - ** + ** -* 32 0.87 134 0.26 - ** + ** - ** - ** + ** 104 0.24 32 0.47 134 0.24 Economic Growth Observations R-squared 136 104 0.40 0.25 Change in Manufacturing Share Change in Transport Costs New inhabitants Economic Growth Observations R-squared * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1% - ** -* 136 0.40 Change_in_Share = constant + change_in_transport + (chage_in_population GDP_growth = pib1970 pop1970) 50. The role of agglomeration (or external) economies is to enhance the scale of production for individual firms or farms, beyond the impact of factors within the control of managers and farmers (known as internal economies). These can be classified (see Table 2.3, extracted from the WDR09) into two broad categories, depending on whether the interactions brought about by geographical proximity are within one industry (localization) or between two or more industries (urbanization). The extent to which firms gain from proximity depends on the unintentional sharing of inputs, information, and labor. It also depends on improving the matches between production requirements and types of land, labor, and intermediate inputs; also on to what extent new techniques are learned and new products developed (WDR09, Chapter 4). Table 2.3. Economies of scale due to agglomeration. Shopping Shoppers are attracted to places where there are many sellers. Adam Smith´s Outsourcing allows both upstream input suppliers and downstream specialization firms to profit from productivity gains caused by specialization. Marshall´s labor Workers with industry-specific skills are attracted to locations where pooling there is a greater concentration of the relevant industry. A worker is Localization Static more likely to be able to find a new job in the same industry if his or her employer experiences a downturn of fortunes. An individual firm also benefits by being better able to hire labor when experiencing an upturn in fortunes, especially if it coincides with a downturn for other firms. Dynamic Marshall-Arrow- Reductions in costs that arise from repeated and continuous Romer´s learning production activity over time and its spatial spillover. by doing Urbanization Static Jane Jacobs´ The more that different things are done locally, the more opportunity innovation there is for observing and adapting ideas from others. Marshall´s labor Workers in an industry bring innovations to firms in other industries; pooling this is similar to no. 6, but here, the benefit arises from the diversity of industries in one location. Adam Smith´s This is similar to no. 5, above, the main difference being that the division of labor division of labor upstream is made possible by the existence of many different downstream buying industries located in the same place. Dynamic Romer´s The larger the market, the higher the profit, the more attractive the endogenous location to firms, the more jobs there are, the more labor pools there, growth the larger the market, and so on. Pure agglomeration Spreading fixed costs of infrastructure over more taxpayers; diseconomies that arise from congestion and pollution. Source: WDR09, adapted from Maureen Kilkenny (2006). 51. The ultimate role of agglomeration economies is to help expand the production level that is effectively sold in the market. That is the ultimate objective for all producers in a competitive market under a rate of return of capital under an equilibrium. However, the more they produce, the more they need to transport from their plant or farm to their consumers. Therefore, economies of scale observe an inverse relationship with transport and thus explain the importance of logistics in strengthening location advantage due to agglomeration economies. It does not make sense for firms or farms to develop (and in fact, they may well not develop) any arrangement of agglomeration economies if the transportation costs from their location to their destination markets are not competitive with alternative locations. 2.5. Rural Productivity Advantages without Density 52. The tension between the development or strengthening of agglomeration economies and the reduction of transportation costs is mediated by the role of the home market. The larger and more affluent the home market in which firms and farms locate, the higher the possibility of developing agglomeration economies, as transportation costs for reaching costumers are at a minimum. As stated in the WDR09, agglomeration economies are amplified by density (the home market) and attenuated by distance (transportation costs). 53. This traces the differences between urban and rural areas. Production in both types of areas can develop agglomeration economies and suffer from reduced economies of scale if transportation costs are too high. However, as urban activities make less use of land, they can locate more easily near stronger (larger and affluent) home markets than rural activities. Competition for land forces rural activities to locate far from markets, thus making them more reliant on transportation costs relative to areas that have similar productivities. Therefore, agglomeration economies do not develop as naturally in rural areas as they do in urban areas. On the basis of proximity, firms in cities may develop some sort of agglomeration economies. Farms in specific areas, on the other hand, may need coordinated action in order to simultaneously solve the consolidation and logistics problems of production and the development of agglomeration economies. 54. Rural space is also uneven in terms of the concentration of economic activities. Certain areas exhibit specialization in certain kinds of production, as land productivity is higher for certain products. Productivity differentials, as drivers of the location of economic activities and specialization in rural spaces, along with transportation costs, are the foundation of economic geography. David Ricardo proposed that the best land in terms of productivity will be paid a higher rent because of the competition between potential users for exploiting its advantage. Either the owner should forgive that additional pay off, or the tenant will have to extract the additional productivity in order to pay for it. Competition between farmers will concentrate production in areas of higher productivity, in as much as they will obtain benefits above the market rate of return for capital in such areas. Some areas will be below market productivity for a particular produce, thus leaving them vacant or in need of switching to a different kind of production. 55. With rural activities, productivity differentials are more evident given the natural endowments of respective areas. However, there are factors other than pure natural advantages that producers utilize in order to strengthen their competitiveness. Among these are, for instance, the capacity to get organized in consolidating production sharing costs for the just-in-time logistics of perishable products; likewise, to develop public and necessary R&D and quality assurance institutions. In Latin America, there are good examples of rural areas that have been growing fast despite missing the advantages of density—this on top of pre-existing natural conditions. In most cases, institutional factors and the development of good logistics have contributed to rural development. 56. In Peru’s coastal area, weather conditions make asparagus production ideal. On top of that, the government enacted a policy aimed at seeing the area move away from traditional agriculture, through the development of R&D and quality assurance institutions such as would improve the final product. It also contributed to the creation of the Instituto Peruano del Espárrago and supported cold logistics operators. As a result, as 2003, the asparagus sector was responsible for the creation of fifty thousand jobs and producing 24% of Peru’s agriculture exports, for a net-worth of over $200 million. 57. In Brazil, during the eighties, the National Center for Research on Soya developed new techniques allowing Soya cultivation in tropical areas. This was an improvement over the traditional production then taking place in only the southern part of the country. This technological change allowed areas made up of large flatlands, as found in the Cerrado region, to participate in soya cultivation, which in turn saw Brazil achieve 24% of the world’s soya production by 2002. 58. In Colombia, the areas surrounding Bogota offer the ideal natural conditions for the production of flowers, though in this, they do not differ that much from other regions in Colombia as well as regions in such countries as Ecuador and Costa Rica. The difference is that Bogota was able to put in place a sophisticated airport logistics, thus allowing producers to reach costumers just in time for the high season. Effectively, these producers were able to expand their scale of production and operations. This was made possible in part by the free skies policy that exists with the US and the EU for cargo, enacted by the government years earlier. Additionally, producers had organized themselves with the support of export promotion agencies in order to reach destination markets. In 2007, exports reached nearly $1 billion.