
PROOF Write the specified type of proof. 1. two
... 5. BRIDGE BUILDING A surveyor needs to find the distance from point A to point B across a canyon. She places a stake at A, and a coworker places a stake at B on the other side of the canyon. The surveyor then locates C on the same side of the canyon as A such that A fourth stake is placed at E, the ...
... 5. BRIDGE BUILDING A surveyor needs to find the distance from point A to point B across a canyon. She places a stake at A, and a coworker places a stake at B on the other side of the canyon. The surveyor then locates C on the same side of the canyon as A such that A fourth stake is placed at E, the ...
Counting Regions in Hyperplane Arrangements
... The rows and columns of ∂St ∂S are indexed by the 3-faces of S, with the 3-faces of Sc indexed first. (The block ∂ t ∂ is the Laplacian of the subcomplex Sc ; both its rows and its columns are indexed by the 3-faces of Sc .) Next we will show that all other eigenvectors are contained in a collection ...
... The rows and columns of ∂St ∂S are indexed by the 3-faces of S, with the 3-faces of Sc indexed first. (The block ∂ t ∂ is the Laplacian of the subcomplex Sc ; both its rows and its columns are indexed by the 3-faces of Sc .) Next we will show that all other eigenvectors are contained in a collection ...
Bounded negativity of Shimura curves
... Here a lattice is called irreducible if it does not have a finite index subgroup that splits as a product of two lattices. Our geometric definition of Shimura varieties differs from the arithmetic literature on this subject where Shimura varieties are typically not connected. It is the point of view ...
... Here a lattice is called irreducible if it does not have a finite index subgroup that splits as a product of two lattices. Our geometric definition of Shimura varieties differs from the arithmetic literature on this subject where Shimura varieties are typically not connected. It is the point of view ...
Brouwer fixed-point theorem

Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is a fixed-point theorem in topology, named after Luitzen Brouwer. It states that for any continuous function f mapping a compact convex set into itself there is a point x0 such that f(x0) = x0. The simplest forms of Brouwer's theorem are for continuous functions f from a closed interval I in the real numbers to itself or from a closed disk D to itself. A more general form than the latter is for continuous functions from a convex compact subset K of Euclidean space to itself.Among hundreds of fixed-point theorems, Brouwer's is particularly well known, due in part to its use across numerous fields of mathematics.In its original field, this result is one of the key theorems characterizing the topology of Euclidean spaces, along with the Jordan curve theorem, the hairy ball theorem and the Borsuk–Ulam theorem.This gives it a place among the fundamental theorems of topology. The theorem is also used for proving deep results about differential equations and is covered in most introductory courses on differential geometry.It appears in unlikely fields such as game theory. In economics, Brouwer's fixed-point theorem and its extension, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem, play a central role in the proof of existence of general equilibrium in market economies as developed in the 1950s by economics Nobel prize winners Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu.The theorem was first studied in view of work on differential equations by the French mathematicians around Poincaré and Picard.Proving results such as the Poincaré–Bendixson theorem requires the use of topological methods.This work at the end of the 19th century opened into several successive versions of the theorem. The general case was first proved in 1910 by Jacques Hadamard and by Luitzen Egbertus Jan Brouwer.