Download FRBSF E L CONOMIC ETTER

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Production for use wikipedia , lookup

Economic planning wikipedia , lookup

Workers' self-management wikipedia , lookup

Economics of fascism wikipedia , lookup

Economic democracy wikipedia , lookup

Economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup

American School (economics) wikipedia , lookup

Rostow's stages of growth wikipedia , lookup

Business cycle wikipedia , lookup

Transformation in economics wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
FRBSF ECONOMIC LETTER
Number 2008-06, February 15, 2008
Recent Trends in Economic Volatility:
Conference Summary
This Economic Letter summarizes the papers presented
at a conference on “Recent Trends in Economic Volatility”
held at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco by
the Bank’s Center for the Study of Innovation and
Productivity on November 2 and 3, 2007.The papers are
listed at the end and are available at http://www.frbsf.org/
economics/conferences/0711/
Over the last 25 years, the U.S. economy has become much less volatile; that is, the swings from
boom to bust have been greatly reduced, as has
the pain typically associated with such cycles. As
Figure 1 illustrates, the volatility of GDP growth
has fallen by more than half since 1985. Many
observers refer to this phenomenon as the “Great
Moderation.” To what can we credit this improved
environment? Researchers have uncovered several
potential drivers, including improved technology
(especially related to inventory and supply chain
management), better monetary policy, and simple
good luck, but to date they have found little consensus on which factor is most important. Also in
dispute is the extent to which the decline in
aggregate volatility has been mirrored in the microeconomic data on income and employment.
In other words, have households and businesses
also experienced a decline in volatility? The seven
papers presented at the Center for the Study
of Innovation and Productivity’s conference on
“Recent Trends in Economic Volatility” investigate these questions. Although the debate is not
over, the papers have moved the research forward
and highlighted key questions for future work.
Structural change vs. good luck in explaining
the Great Moderation
The first paper of the conference, by Galí and
Gambetti, begins with a useful summary of the
various explanations for the Great Moderation,
placing them into two broad categories: structural
changes and “good luck.” Structural changes in-
Figure 1
Variance of quarterly real GDP growth
(Five-year moving variance)
2.0
1.8
1.6
1.4
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
70
75
80
85
90
95
00
Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.
clude changes in the way monetary policy is conducted and technology-driven changes that affect
the way firms operate. “Good luck” essentially
means smaller and fewer economic shocks. Galí
and Gambetti go on to use a standard empirical
model known as a structural vector autoregression
in order to characterize the correlations in postWorld War II data among key U.S. macroeconomic
variables.They posit that if declining volatility is
merely the result of “good luck,” then the data
should show no change in the correlations between
them.Their model, however, finds that this is not
the case, as correlations between output, labor
hours, and productivity have indeed changed
since the early 1980s. Having eliminated good
luck as an explanation, they attribute most of the
decline in volatility to a decline in nontechnology
shocks, which have come about due to a change
in the Federal Reserve’s monetary policy “rules”
(specifically, an increased emphasis on fostering low
CSIP
NOTES CSIP Notes appears on an occasional basis. It is prepared under the auspices of the Center for the Study of Innovation and Productivity within the FRBSF’s Economic
Research Department.
FRBSF Economic Letter
and stable inflation in addition to strong economic
growth) as well as a reduction in labor adjustment
costs. It is worth noting that the authors’ finding
that reduced labor adjustment costs may have played
an important role in the Great Moderation is
consistent with evidence, discussed below, provided
by the paper of Davis et al., which explores the
secular decline in labor market volatility.
The role of technological change
Several papers ascribe a key role to technological
progress in explaining declining volatility.The first
of these papers, by Koren and Tenreyro, looks at
how development of new technologies affects both
the rate of growth and the volatility of growth
in an economy. Their model posits that, just as
households benefit from investing in a diversified
portfolio of stocks (smoothing their returns and
minimizing losses stemming from shocks to specific
assets), having a larger and more diverse “menu” of
technologies available to firms in a country means
that each specific technology plays less of a role
in production.The diversification of technologies
in an economy makes it easier for firms to offset
price or supply shocks to specific inputs (oil, for
example) by substituting with other technologies
that rely less on those inputs. In this way, technological advances reduce firm-level volatility, which
consequently reduces overall volatility.Technological
change also boosts the level of growth, since it
allows firms to move to a new technology before
reaching the point of diminishing returns in their
old technology.While sensible and consistent with
data that Koren and Tenreyro bring to bear, this
finding contrasts sharply with the conclusions of
previous research, which point to an explicit tradeoff between risk (volatility) and return (fast growth).
Comin and Mulani also examine the effects of
technological change on economic growth and
volatility and, similarly, find that technological
change leads to both faster growth and lower
volatility. But in contrast to the previous paper,
Comin and Mulani argue that this good result
holds only for the national, or macro, measures.
Indeed, predictions from their model suggest that
firm-level, or micro, volatility should increase as
the pace of technological innovation increases.To
get this result, they consider an economy with two
types of technologies: general innovations (GIs),
which are not patentable and are used by all firms
in the economy, and research and development
innovations (RDI), which are patentable and used
by a limited number of firms.They then assume
2
Number 2008-06, February 15, 2008
that GIs are produced by large, stable firms and
RDIs are produced by smaller, more volatile firms.
Under these conditions, they show that increases
in RDIs (for example, due to government research
and development (R&D) subsidies) lead to market
“shake-up,” whereby smaller firms gain market
share and perhaps even leapfrog ahead of the
previous market leaders. Since GI activity relies
on the presence of stable market leaders, this shakeup creates both firm-level volatility and lower GI
activity.The decline in GIs, which by definition
help all firms, reduces the comovement between
firms in the economy, ultimately reducing the
volatility of aggregate outcomes. Said more simply, if the increase in the innovative activity comes
from small firms jockeying for position in the industry, aggregate volatility will go down, as winners
and losers will offset each other, but microvolatility
will rise, as losing firms compete to get back on
top. Comin and Mulani provide empirical evidence
showing that increased R&D activity in the U.S.
has coincided with increased volatility in sales
and market shares for publicly traded firms, reduced
comovement across industries, and reduced volatility in aggregate economic growth.
Turning to the purely micro data, Brynjolfsson et
al. analyze the impact of information technology
(IT) on industry volatility or turbulence. Use of
IT allows an innovation to diffuse rapidly throughout a firm, increasing productivity and market share
faster than was previously possible. Although first
movers on an innovation are able to gain market
share quickly creating the opportunity for concentration, the speed of diffusion that IT affords
also enables new entrants to leapfrog ahead of
leaders in a given sector, thus increasing sectoral
turnover rates (turbulence). Empirically, IT-intensive industries have indeed experienced both
greater concentration and turbulence.This evidence
is consistent with the findings of Comin and
Mulani that firms in more R&D-intensive industries tend to have more volatile sales and market
shares, since there is a strong correlation between
an industry’s R&D intensity and its IT intensity.
Supply chain management
The role of supply chain management in the Great
Moderation is the subject of a paper by Davis
and Kahn as well as one by Irvine and Schuh.
Davis and Kahn argue that dramatic technologydriven improvements in supply chain management
in the durable goods sector, combined with a
secular shift away from domestic durable goods
FRBSF Economic Letter
manufacturing and toward services, is the explanation for the decline in aggregate volatility.They
suggest that changes in monetary policy, on the
other hand, played a minimal role. Their model
of the firm’s inventory decision process mirrors
observed declines in output and sales volatility, as
well as the sales-to-output ratio, and the authors
suggest that a shorter lead time for materials orders
(more precise inventory control) is the key mechanism through which this change has occurred.
Irvine and Schuh also find that improvement in
supply chain management likely played the predominant role in reduced aggregate volatility. Using
a multi-sector, vector-autoregression empirical
model, they find that a decline in the comovement
of output among inventory-holding industries (for
example, manufacturing and wholesale trade) can
explain a substantial share of the decline in aggregate output volatility.Their model suggests that
a change in structural relationships between inventory-holding industries seems to be the cause
of this decline, and industries in which firms share
supply and distribution chains exhibited the largest
decline in covariance in volatility. As in Davis and
Kahn, Irvine and Schuh find little evidence that
changes in monetary policy or “good luck” are
major factors behind the Great Moderation.
Volatility in the labor market
In the final paper of the conference, Davis et al.
establish and attempt to explain two interesting
facts from the data.The first fact is that volatility
of employment levels within firms, particularly
those not publicly traded, has declined over the
past 25 years.The second fact is that the flows of
individuals into unemployment have fallen over
time. In the early 1980s about 4% of employed
persons fell into unemployment (either voluntarily or involuntarily) in the average month; by the
early 1990s, this figure had dropped to just 2%.
The focus of their paper, then, is to investigate
whether the decline in volatility in employment
demand by businesses is responsible for the decline
in unemployment inflows. Using industry-level
data, they find a strong statistical association between an industry’s volatility in employment
demand, as measured by the variance in its job
3
Number 2008-06, February 15, 2008
destruction rate, and the industry’s unemployment
inflow rate (the rate at which workers in the industry go into unemployment in a given period).
They conclude that the decline in firm level
employment volatility likely has reduced flows
into unemployment.
Conclusion
While there is broad agreement that aggregate
economic volatility has declined over the last 25
years, the relative roles of economywide factors,
such as changes in monetary policy and technological change, remain topics of dispute. Also in
dispute is the extent to which this decline in
aggregate volatility is mirrored in microeconomic variables, such as income and employment.
Reductions in aggregate and firm-level volatility
do not necessarily translate into a reduction in
volatility at the individual level. Rather, some
studies argue that household consumption and
individual earnings have become more volatile in
recent decades, not less.The linkages between the
disparate trends in volatility at the aggregate level
and at the individual level remain important areas
of economic research.
Charles Notzon
Research Associate
Dan Wilson
Senior Economist
Conference papers
Brynjolfsson, Erik, Andrew McAfee, Michael Sorell,
and Feng Zhu. “Scale without Mass: Business
Process Replication and Industry Dynamics.”
Comin, Diego, and Sunil Mulani.“A Theory of Growth
and Volatility at the Aggregate and Firm Level.”
Davis, Steven J., and James A. Kahn. “Changes in the
Volatility of Economic Activity at the Macro and
Micro Levels.”
Davis, Steven J., R. Jason Faberman, John Haltiwanger,
Ron Jarmin, and Javier Miranda.“Business Volatility,
Job Destruction, and Unemployment.”
Galí, Jordi, and Luca Gambetti. “On the Sources of
the Great Moderation.”
Irvine, Owen, and Scott Schuh. “The Roles of
Comovement and Inventory Investment in the
Reduction of Output Volatility.”
Koren, Miklós, and Silvana Tenreyro. “Technological
Diversification.”
ECONOMIC RESEARCH
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF SAN FRANCISCO
PRESORTED
STANDARD MAIL
U.S. POSTAGE
PAID
PERMIT NO. 752
San Francisco, Calif.
P.O. Box 7702
San Francisco, CA 94120
Address Service Requested
Printed on recycled paper
with soybean inks
Index to Recent Issues of FRBSF Economic Letter
DATE
7/20
7/27
8/3
8/10
8/31
9/14
9/21
9/28
10/5
10/19
10/26
11/2
11/23
11/30
12/7
12/14
1/18
1/25
2/1
2/8
NUMBER
07-21
07-22
07-23
07-24
07-25
07-26-27
07-28
07-29
07-30
07-31
07-32
07-33
07-34
07-35
07-36-37
07-38
08-01
08-02
08-03
08-04-05
TITLE
What We Do and Don’t Know about the Term Premium
Regional Economic Conditions and Community Bank Performance
Trends in Bay Area IT Employment
Are Global Prices Converging or Diverging?
Changing Productivity Trends
Recent Financial Developments and the U.S. Economic Outlook
Changes in Income Inequality across the U.S.
Internal Risk Models and the Estimation of Default Probabilities
Relative Comparisons and Economics: Empirical Evidence
Corporate Access to External Financing
Asset Price Bubbles
Labor Force Participation and the Prospects for U.S. Growth
Financial Globalization and Monetary Policy
Fixing the New Keynesian Phillips Curve
The U.S. Economy and Monetary Policy
Sovereign Wealth Funds: Stumbling Blocks or Stepping Stones...?
Publishing FOMC Economic Forecasts
Publishing Central Bank Interest Rate Forecasts
2007 Annual Pacific Basin Conference: Summary
Prospects for the Economy in 2008
AUTHOR
Swanson
Furlong/Krainer
Hsueh
Glick
Trehan
Yellen
Regev/Wilson
Christensen
Daly/Wilson
Lopez
Lansing
Daly/Regev
Spiegel
Dennis
Yellen
Aizenman/Glick
Rudebusch
Rudebusch
Glick
Yellen
Opinions expressed in the Economic Letter do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank
of San Francisco or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.This publication is edited by Judith Goff, with
the assistance of Anita Todd. Permission to reprint portions of articles or whole articles must be obtained in writing. Permission
to photocopy is unrestricted. Please send editorial comments and requests for subscriptions, back copies, address changes, and
reprint permission to: Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco, CA
94120, phone (415) 974-2163, fax (415) 974-3341, e-mail [email protected]. The Economic Letter and other publications
and information are available on our website, http://www.frbsf.org.