Download Pro Murena

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Constitutional reforms of Sulla wikipedia , lookup

Alpine regiments of the Roman army wikipedia , lookup

Travel in Classical antiquity wikipedia , lookup

Ancient Roman architecture wikipedia , lookup

Military of ancient Rome wikipedia , lookup

Daqin wikipedia , lookup

Roman army of the late Republic wikipedia , lookup

Slovakia in the Roman era wikipedia , lookup

Food and dining in the Roman Empire wikipedia , lookup

History of the Roman Constitution wikipedia , lookup

Roman Republican governors of Gaul wikipedia , lookup

Roman command structure during First Mithridatic War wikipedia , lookup

Demography of the Roman Empire wikipedia , lookup

Roman historiography wikipedia , lookup

Pro Caelio wikipedia , lookup

Switzerland in the Roman era wikipedia , lookup

Education in ancient Rome wikipedia , lookup

Early Roman army wikipedia , lookup

Romanization of Hispania wikipedia , lookup

Senatus consultum ultimum wikipedia , lookup

Elections in the Roman Republic wikipedia , lookup

Roman funerary practices wikipedia , lookup

Roman technology wikipedia , lookup

Culture of ancient Rome wikipedia , lookup

Roman economy wikipedia , lookup

Roman agriculture wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
The View from the Top: the ‘Poor’ in Cicero’s Pro Murena
Rome of Cicero’s day would have been crowded and poor (Harris 2011; Holleran 2011),
but it was not bifurcated between an economic and political elite and the impoverished masses
(Jongman 2007; Scheidel 2006). Cicero, however, thought it was. In his defense of consul-elect
Lucius Licinius Murena, Cicero reduces the complex classification system of the Roman census
to a simple division between those in the senatorial and equestrian classes and everyone else. He
does not and perhaps cannot distinguish between the social strata of Roman society beyond those
sharing his own privileged status. From his precipitous perch, no matter how precarious his own
social position (Tatum 1988), he sees all as undifferentiated mob.
Although the culturally freighted vocabulary of poverty makes it difficult to speak
precisely about the poor (Morley 2006; Harris 2011), a younger Cicero offered a clear distinction
between rich and poor when he posited that fate made a man pecuniosus an tenuis (De. Inv.
1.25). As a consul defending his successor, Cicero deploys the term tenuis as an indication of
limited financial resources (Adamietz 1989:182). In the contentio dignitatis, he claims that
Servius Sulpicius Rufus, losing candidate and then prosecutor, undermined his campaign by
investing his time in preparing this very accusation. Cicero asserts that Sulpicius lost popular
support because he enraged the tenuiores with a law against electoral corruption that targeted the
plebs with a serious penalty (Mur. 47). The same law imposed exile on guilty senators, and these
two punishments reflect a simple division of Roman society into only two segments. Cicero
finds no rhetorical benefit in offering greater nuance to the political and economic elite of the
jury.
When he later addressed the specific charges of bribery leveled by Cato, Cicero consider
more extensively the inequality in Roman society and its political implications. Rejecting Cato’s
accusation that illicit money bought Murena his crowds of supporters, Cicero contends that a
traditionally reciprocal relationship balanced the generosity of the elite with the active
campaigning of the non-elite. In fact, he is clear that electoral support is the only avenue
available to homines tenues for maintaining that relationship (Mur. 70). When Cicero continues
that line of thought by stating that those of the senatorial and equestrian orders could not be
asked to invest entire days on campaign, he again divides Roman society into two, the elite and
all others. He encourages Cato not to steal from inferiori generi what they received from the
relationship, and he defines that lower order by their inability to function as elites (Mur. 71).
Cicero concludes this line of argument by justifying the acts of alleged bribery as commoda
tenuiorum (Mur. 73).
The modern reader might, then, have the impression that we are learning about the
relationship between Rome’s poor and its governing elite. That is unlikely (Mouritsen 2001).
Cicero had little regard for the poor (Wood 1988), but here he has subsumed under the term
tenuis a wider swath of Roman society. If the third and fourth classes of the census were not
routinely at risk of deprivation (Scheidel 2006), and if the fifth class seldom had an impact on
electoral outcomes (Mouritsen 2001), then Cicero has collapsed a more complex society into a
simple binary. This elision of the middling may not teach us about the reality of Roman society,
but it does teach us about the view of from the top.
Bibiliography
Adamietz, Joachim. 1989. Pro Murena. Texte Zur Forschung Bd. 55. Darmstadt:
Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft.
Harris, William V. “Poverty and Destitution in the Roman Empire.” In Rome’s Imperial
Economy. Twelve Essays, 27–54. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2011.
Holleran, Claire. “Migration and the Urban Economy of Rome.” In Demography and the
Graeco-Roman World, 155–80. Cambridge University Press, 2011.
Jongman, Willem M. “Gibbon Was Right : The Decline and Fall of the Roman Economy.” In
Crises and the Roman Empire, 183–99. Brill, 2007.
Morley, Neville. “The Poor in the City of Rome.” In Poverty in the Roman World, 21–39.
Cambridge University Press, 2006.
Mouritsen, Henrik. Plebs and Politics in the Late Roman Republic. Cambridge ; New York:
Cambridge University Press, 2001.
Scheidel, Walter. “Stratification, Deprivation and Quality of Life.” In Poverty in the Roman
World, 40–59. Cambridge University Press, 2006.
Tatum, W. Jeffrey. “Catullus’ Criticism of Cicero in Poem 49.” Transactions of the American
Philological Association 118 (1988): 179–84.
Wood, Neal. Cicero’s Social and Political Thought. Berkeley: University of California Press,
1988.