Download DMF model and exchange rate overshooting

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Foreign-exchange reserves wikipedia , lookup

Purchasing power parity wikipedia , lookup

Fixed exchange-rate system wikipedia , lookup

Currency intervention wikipedia , lookup

Exchange rate wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
DMF model and exchange rate
overshooting
Lecture 1, MSc Open Economy
Macroeconomics, Birmingham, Autumn
2015
Tony Yates
Motivation
• Dornbusch (1976) writing shortly after demise
(1973) of fixed exchange rate system agreed at
Bretton Woods
• Era of exchange rate volatility [that continued
of course]; fluctuations seemed to exceed
what was sensible from fundamentals
• ‘Overshooting’ provided the answer.
RER=changes in real purchasing power. Note less volatile in Gold Standard and
Bretton-Woods periods.
Source: ‘Real exchange rate volatility….’, IMF wp, 1998, by Hong Liang.
Source: ‘Real exchange rate volatility….’, IMF wp, 1998, by Hong Liang
Motivation and context - recap
• Nominal exchange rate very volatile
• Leads to volatility in the real exchange rate
• That real exchange rate volatility is considered
harmful and costly.
The DMF model equations
it1 i e t1 e t
Uncovered interest parity
m t p t it1 y t
Money demand
q e p  p
y dt y 
e t p  p t q
,  0
Defn of the real exchange rate
Aggregate demand. q_bar is RER
when ag demand=natural rate.


p t1 p t 
y dt y
p t1 p t 
Open economy Phillips Curve

p t e t p t q t
p_tilda is price that would emerge if
output=natural rate.
Explaining the model equations
• Let’s take each equation and explain what it
says and where it comes from.
• We’ll also go through the equilibrium
concepts, the letters with ‘bars’ over them.
Explaining money demand
m t p t it1 y t
LHS, m-p= real balances. The amount of goods you can buy with the money in
your pocket.
These said to i) fall as the opportunity cost of holding them [the interest rate on a
bank account, say] rises; ii) increase as expenditure increases.
This is the same as the demand for any other good that you might eat, which has a
complement. So if the price goes up, you eat less; and if you expect to eat more of
the complementary good, you will eat more of this one.
Explaining UIP
• UIP=uncovered interest parity
it1 i e t1 e t
A gap between interest rates at home and abroad must be compensated
for by an expected change in the exchange rate in the future.
If interest rates are lower than abroad, it must be that at the end of the
period we expect to be able to buy more foreign currency with our home
currency.
If this wasn’t the case, people would sell the home asset, driving the home
currency down, which would then mean it was expected to go up later!
This condition very controversial in empirical macro. See eg Meese and
Rogoff on reading list for later lecture.
Explaining the RER
• RER=real exchange rate:
q e p  p
RER would be 1 if:
the exchange rate e was such that when you sold a Big Macg in China, for
Yuan,
then swapped Yuan for dollars at a Travel Bureau
Then used the dollars to buy a Big Mac in New York, you ended up with the
same amount of money [0!] as you started with.
Explaining RER/ctd…
• We will study this in detail later in the course,
but….
• RER might not be 1 because of:
– Transport costs
– Non-traded inputs
– Barriers to arbitrage, like tarriffs, lack of information,
costs of search….
– See the Economist’s ‘Big Mac’ index!:
– http://www.economist.com/content/big-mac-index
Explaining agg demand
y dt y 
e t p  p t q
,  0
In the long run, y_d given by the natural rate of output, y_bar.
That’s the output governed by population, capital, working hours,
technology, and frictions in the labour market.
In the short run, if something makes foreign goods cheaper [if the real
exchange rate rises above its long run q_bar]…
Consumers will feel richer and want to buy more.
Explaining the OE Philips Curve


p t1 p t 
y dt y
p t1 p t 
Just as each market has a demand and a supply curve, so for the whole economy.
This is the supply curve for the whole, open economy.
Firms will produce in the long run the natural rate of output y_bar.
But in the short run if demand rises above the natural rate, they will produce
more, but this will lead to an expected increase in prices [see the LHS].
They will also produce more if there is an expected increase in the equilibrium
price….. So let’s look at what that eqm price is.
Explaining the eq’m price

p t e t p t q t
Equilibrium price:
The price that you would get if the real exchange rate were at its
equilibrium level q_bar.
So if this were to be expected to rise, then firms would be induced to
produce more.
What have we done?
• Explained why DMF model was constructed,
what it was for.
• Explained the DMF equations one by one.
• Now let’s derive the overshooting result.
Strategy to derive and study the
overshooting result
• Algebraic:
– Use model equations to form two difference
equations, in q and e.
– Solve them to find their steady states in terms of
exogenous money stock.
– Show that when we change money, e movement
initially exceeds eventual new steady state.
• ‘Intuitive’ [in quotes because even this is quite
mathematical.]
Intuition for overshooting: proof by
contradiction
• Let’s imagine an increase in the money stock
from m to m’
• Then suppose that there is no overshooting, so
that the short run value for e [while prices are
fixed] is the same as the long run value for e.
• Then study our model equations and see that this
assumption violates the equation that imposes
UIP.
• Hence overshooting must happen.
Overshooting intuition: 1
m t p t it1 y t
Money demand equation tells us REAL
balances will rise by m-m’ if money stock rises
from m to m’, since prices are fixed.

m m
From the aggregate demand curve below,
this is how much m-m’ increases aggregate
demand. ..
y dt y 
e t p  p t q
..because in LR we know e rises 1 for 1
with m, so we substitute m-m’ for e in
here to get the short run change in output.
Noting all other terms in the equation are
fixed.
Overshooting intuition: 2
m t p t it1 y t

m m
Take the money demand curve again, and
substitute in the change in demand we just
worked out, for y.
And this is what you get for the change in
money demand.
Because phi*delta<1, this means that money
demand is rising less than money supply,
which rises by m’-m.
In order for the money market to clear, this
means that the interest rate has to fall next
period in order to clear the market for
money. Yet this contradicts our model….
Overshooting intuition: 3
it1 i e t1 e t
Take the UIP condition, and rearrange it.
it1 i e t1 e t
If i_t+1 falls, this means that the LHS is –ve. Why?
Because i) we assume i=i_star in a world of stable
exchange rates. And i_star is fixed.
This means the RHS is –ive.
That means that e_t+1<e_t, which contradicts what
we said about e jumping to its new steady state
straight away.
If we work back from here, then we need that e
initially jumps HIGHER than its steady state, then
falls.
Recap on how we got overshooting
• We said what happens if money supply
increases from m to m’?
• We supposed that exchange rate e rises
straight away to its new long run level.
• We used that assumption to figure out how
much aggregate demand would rise…
• And we saw because of delta<1, that ag
demand rises less than the change in e,m.
Recap on overshooting
• We then fed the aggregate demand increase
into the money demand equation to see how
much the demand for real balances would
rise.
• This was even smaller still, since phi<1.
• We realised that this meant there would have
to be an expected fall in interest rates to
encourage real balance demand to rise by
enough to soak up the extra money supply.
Recap on overshooting
• But , for UIP to hold…
• this expected fall in the interest rate would
mean that the exchange rate would have to be
expected to RISE next period.
• This contradicts what we said at the outset,
which is that the ex rate moves straight to its
long run level.
• So there must be overshooting.
Assumptions required to get
overshooting
• Phi*delta<1 [?]
• Prices sticky for one period [ok]
• Perfect foresight rational expectations [in fin
mkts, maybe, but prob not]
• Particular conjectured functional forms for
money demand [this one ok], aggregate demand
[contestable], Phillips Curve [likewise].
• No microfoundations to assess whether these are
possible worlds.
• Empirically controversial model components.
Word on next lecture
• Controversial model with clear hypothesis:
money supply changes cause volatility in e.
• We will look at time series VAR techniques for
testing this and related models.
• Relies on deducing monetary shocks from long
run neutrality in how they affect real things.
• Then measuring contribution of monetary
shocks to everything.
Deriving overshooting analytically
• Derive 2 difference equations in e and q
• Solve our two difference equations by
repeated forward substitution.
• Substitute the solution for q into the solution
for e, which will be in terms of m.
• Then study dynamics of e in response to
change from m to m’, and prove conditions
under which e overshoots.
Getting our difference equation in q


p t1 p t 
et1 p t1 q t1 
e t p t q t 
p t1 p t 
y dt ye t1 e t
q t1 q t1 q t 
q t q
Defn of the change in the eq’m
price
Philips curve with this defn
substituted in, noting that p_star
and rer eq’m ,q_bar, are constant
Philips curve now with aggregate
demand and defn of rer
substituted in.
Getting our difference equation in e
p  y i 0
Simplifying asssumptions…
m t p t 
e t1 e t 
q t q
…substituted into money demand eq
…using defn of real er.
m t e t q t 
e t1 e t 
q t q
e t1  et 

1
qt


q
mt

Rearranged to give us our difference
equation in e
Now we can solve these two difference equations to get steady state values of e
for different values of exogenous money, m. But let’s try to see how overshooting
comes about using some economic intuition.
The two difference equations for e and
q
q t1 q 
1 

q t q
et
e t1   

1
qt

q
mt
 
Solve e equation first, by forward
substitution
et
e t1   


1
qt

q
mt
 
First, unpack the
difference term…..
1
mt
e t q  1
e t1 q1 
q t q1


1 
m

e t1 q

q t q t
1 
1 
1 


1 
1 
m



e t2 q

q t1 q t1 

q t q m t
1  1 
1 
1 
1 
1 
e t q 
Then use the equation for e_t-q to substitute out for future terms. Here’s one
step, but we do it over and over until we spot the pattern…..
Solving forward the difference
equation for e_t

e t q 
1
1



1st m s
1
1


st
 st

qs
1

q
st
What we get by repeatedly substituting out for the e_t+n terms…
e t q m
1
1


 st

qs
1

q
st
Equation for e_t simplifies when we impose constant money supply m_bar.
Solving for e_t in terms of m and q.
q s q 
1 st 
q t q
e t q m
1
1 
qt

q
st
1
e t q m 1
q t q
Solution for q_t also got by repeated
forward substitution.
 st
st

1




1

Substitute this expression
for q_t into equation for
e_t, and then simplify….
….and we get this.
Deriving the overshooting result
• Now we have an equation for e solely in terms
of q and m.
• q is constant.
• So we can substitute in different values for m
and see what happens.
• Specifically, we derive the analytical condition
for overshooting.
• The lecture notes do this for you, but, next
slides recap and take you through it.
Deriving overshooting from our e
equation
e t m q
e m q
q 0 e 0 m
Initial steady state for e given by this [note p=m_bar]
New steady state, with higher money stock, rises to
e’.
Initially prices don’t move, so q_0 given by this
expression. [we substitute p_0=m_bar into the defn
of the real exchange rate…]
Finally, the condition for overshooting!
1
q 0 m m q 1
q 0 q
This is our solved difference eq for e, but having substituted out for e_0
on the right hand side.
Now we solve for q_0, then, given that solution, we find out what e_0 is,
and look to see what conditions make e_0>e’, the new long run value for
e with the higher money stock.
e 0 m 
m
1 
1

m

q
This is what we get, after a
few basic algebra steps.
And a few more steps yield this condition for overshooting.
We are done!! Not so hard, really!
Recap
• DMF model consisted of:
– Money demand relation
– Open economy Phillips Curve
– Aggregate demand equation
– Assumption of perfect foresight RE
Two strategies for deriving the
overshooting result
• First was to prove by contradiction
– We supposed that the short and long run e were
the same after an increase of m to m’
– And we realised this contradicted the UIP
condition
• Second was to solve algebraically, forming
difference equations in e and q, solving them
forward by repeated substitution.
Overshooting: so what? Why do we
care?
• DMF provided a rational for exchange rate
volatility seen in floating ex rate regimes.
• Suggests a route whereby we can get
significant welfare costs from unwarranted
monetary policy shocks.
• Shows the strengths and weaknesses of oldstyle macroeconomic RE modelling.
• S: powerful results. W: where do these
curves come from?
Next lecture: time series analysis and
overshooting
• DMF pointed the way to famous time series
VAR work on overshooting and the nonneutrality of monetary shocks on the real
exchange rate and output.
• Clarida and Gali.
• This is the [hard!] topic for the next lecture.
• Enjoy the exercises [!], and remember, that
they are mostly much harder than the
examined material.