Download The challenges to sustainable beef production in Botswana in the

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Agriculture wikipedia , lookup

Political economy in anthropology wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
The challenges to sustainable beef production in Botswana: Implications on rangeland
management
*Kutlwano Mulale* Department of Sociology, Iowa State University.
Abstract
The precursor to Botswana's present-day approach to pastoral issues took form in the
colonial period. The colonial period witnessed the fundamental transformation and
evolution of social relations, and the institution of market and infrastructure conditions,
which wrought the logic for present day policy toward livestock development (Lawry,
1983). Up till then, livestock practices were normally organized and operated under a
diversity of social and ecological conditions. The objective of this paper is to outline and
analyze the historical development of the cattle sector before integration into the world
trade system to present. Much of the data used here is from secondary sources. This
paper is guided by the hypothesis that, due to the integration of the beef sector into the
world trade system, the character of the interaction between cattle keeping and
ecological conditions changed considerably and has had consequent implications in the
construction of the livestock policy.
Introduction
There is mounting disapproval for developing countries’ rangeland livestock production
systems worldwide. Critics maintain that current practices are bad for the environment.
The livestock sector has come to be associated with overgrazing and desertification.
Mearns (1996) has argued that the environmental consequences of livestock production
differ extensively since production practices are contingent upon the options and
restraints afforded by different production systems, as well as institutional and policy
contexts. Nonetheless, with the growing commodification of beef, and its augmented
significance as an export commodity, the wide-ranging functions performed by cattle, in
Botswana, have been simplified or under-valued consequently prompting the
transformation of rangelands to monocultures. As a result of the integration of the cattle
sector into the world beef industry, the use value of cattle has declined. Customarily, the
utility of cattle for owners rested in their provision of milk and draught power, which,
among most pastoral farmers form the basis of their subsistence.
In Botswana, the strongest obstruction to the formulation of sustainable cattle sector
policies is the vested interest of a small but influential socio-economic elite, who have
gained and anticipate to continue doing so, from the cattle sectors’ integration into the
world trade system. The prevailing bias towards beef production is induced by the beef
protocol under the Lome Convention accorded to Botswana and other African, Caribbean
and Pacific (ACP) countries by the EEC, now EC. This protocol gave the ACP countries
access to the EC market on preferential terms. However, contemporary developments in
the world trade in beef products portray a rather gloomy situation for ACP countries as a
result of the growing EC surplus ensuing from subsidized production and exports under
the Common Agricultural Policy. Escalating EC beef exports have had precisely harsh
consequences on ACP beef exporters who now have to compete against EC beef dumped
on their alternative markets. Under these circumstances, the ACP beef exporters turn out
to be progressively dependent for export sales on their preferential access to the EC
market. At present, with changes in the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)
and the World Trade Organization (WTO) which include trade liberalization and
dismantling of preferential trade terms, Botswana and other ACP beef exporting countries
are fated to stumble upon intense competition in their formerly protected markets.
At the national level nevertheless, instead of broadening horizons in the face of this
reality, policy makers in Botswana disregard these threats and are pushing harder for the
commercialization of the beef sector as a means of increasing productivity. To this end
the Government of Botswana is resolute on shifting the use over vast tracts of communal
land from communities to individuals, setting up fenced farms to operate in beef
production. Ecologists have maintained that the fencing policy is not compatible with the
dynamic “drought driven” Kalahari ecosystem that covers much of Botswana (Albertson,
1998). Research findings point to the decline in wildlife populations as fences disrupt
migratory routes of wildlife. Additionally, cattle keeping within private enclosures
displace peasants and hunter-gatherer communities. With negligible industrial
development to provide alternative employment for displaced people, the social costs of
farm development in Botswana will be high, exacerbating poverty and in turn
environmental degradation.
In the pre-colonial era, Schapera (1943) noted that most cattle-owners in Botswana sold
only one or two cows/oxen at a time to purchase essential goods, particularly grain during
deficit years. For this reason, the primary purpose for keeping cattle was to obtain a
means of subsistence livelihood - a safety net. Enhanced market conditions upheld by the
colonial administration and continued by the present government turned a century-old
pastoral subsistence society towards market oriented farming. As has been the case
worldwide, the prices paid for livestock products fail to reflect fully the environmental
costs associated with their production. The artificial attractiveness of the cattle sector has
been encouraged through government subsidies of various kinds, which have distorted
market prices.
In response to the cattle inclined policies, Botswana's national cattle herd grew from a
few hundred thousand cattle in 1950 to close to three million today. The growth in cattle
numbers culminated in an intense debate among ecologists who remain divided on the
issues and the causes of range degradation. On the one hand the cattle industry is accused
of causing range degradation, while on the other, the role of cattle in range degradation is
down played and instead amplifying the role of natural phenomenal forces, like drought.
A number of authors have articulated the view that Botswana’s rangelands have been
severely degraded over the past few decades (Campbell and Child, 1971; Van Rensberg,
1971; Van Vegten, 1981; Arntzen and Veenendaal, 1986; Ringrose and Matheson, 1986).
It is important to note that very little, if any, research has been conducted on the level of
degradation within the freehold farms for comparison with the communal lands.
However, the governments’ reaction to rangeland degradation has been to insist on the
privatization of communal land under the pretext of avoiding the “tragedy of the
commons.” While in reality, the privatization of land is viewed as a recipe for efficient
beef production from a purely productivist perspective.
The World Systems Theory and the Dependency Theories has been employed to help
understand the historical development of the cattle industry in Botswana. Polanyi (1944)
noted that, no society could, live for any length of time unless it possessed an economy of
some sort; but previously to our time no economy has ever existed that, even in principle,
was controlled by markets. Wallersten (1984) argued that to understand the internal class
contradictions and political struggles of a particular state, we must first situate it in the
world economy. The international system shapes and constrains national development
strategies. Furthermore, the peripheral countries’ earlier association with core nations in
the form of colonialism set conditions for a dependency relationship commonly referred
to as neocolonialism. Dos Santos (1970) defined dependency as a situation in which the
economy of certain countries is conditioned by the development and expansion of another
economy to which the former is subjected.
Historical background of the cattle sector
Pre-colonial
Traditionally, areas outlying from the fields and village were designated grazing land.
Various wards were apportioned grazing rights in a single large block, for which an
overseer was appointed. One of the responsibilities of the overseer was to ensure that
only ward members established cattle-posts in the designated land area. He also
encouraged sufficient spacing of cattle-posts. However, there is no information on
whether the overseer also regulated the aggregate stocking rate or directed the grazing
patterns of individual herds (Lawry, 1983). Cattle numbers fluctuated according to
disease and drought incidences. In the wet summer months, with water lying in riverbeds
and pans, cattle could be trekked out to graze in the sandveld, retreating again to the
perennial water places for the winter and spring. The poorer the pasturage within reach of
perennial water the fewer the cattle could survive to the next season. Hence the amount of
dry season grazing around perennial water points was the long-term determinant of cattle
numbers, with shorter term fluctuations induced by disease, epidemics and drought
(Hubbard, 1986).
Describing the pre-colonial economy of the Ngwato Kingdom (of Botswana), Parsons
(1977:114) outlined their system of cattle holding as follows; “it was based on the mafisa
system, characteristic of Tswana and Sotho societies, whereby the ruling class loaned
cattle to clans or families, who became herdsmen holding royal property in a sort of
feudal system.” This setup has led to the conclusion that in contrast to other parts of
Africa, where land has greater commodity value as a means of production, here cattle
were the particular commodity with the same significance in the feudal political economy
(Hubbard, 1986). Cattle were both a production good (as draught power, transport and
calves) and a consumption good (as milk, meat, and hides) and as a form of saving for
future consumption and production (Hubbard, 1986).
The pre-colonial system of grazing land management based upon the overseer has all but
disappeared (Hitchcook, 1980) and the basis of the system of mafisa was altered with the
transition to private ownership of cattle, which appears to have taken place in the mid-to
late nineteenth century. The transition to private ownership did not mean that the mafisa
system ended, but it became a loaning of cattle by individual owners instead of the chief
alone (Hubbard, 1986). The holder of such cattle enjoyed certain rights, e.g. consumption
of milk and using them as draught power. The owner also could expect to increase his
cattle, because in general, calves born belong to the owner. The holder had rights to
ownership of one or more of the offspring. Mafisa contracts were a major opportunity for
the many farmers without sufficient draught power to operate as subsistence farmers
(Mthethwa, 1982).
Colonial: 1889 - 1966
The colonial period brought more water-points, opening the grazing wealth of
unexploited lands for perennial use, and veterinary medicines leveled out fluctuations due
to disease (Hubbard, 1986). As a result there was evident increase in cattle population
and off-take numbers and in the number of water points in the geographical spread of
cattle across the country. The country was fenced into separate veterinary compartments
(Hubbard, 1986). All these have been the most visible changes on the ground in
Botswana’s cattle production. Colonizers treatment of agroecosystems has often aimed at
increasing short-term outputs, with no awareness or concern about depletion of the very
resources that produced the bounty (Flora, 2001).
The alteration of the world beef trade in the late 1950’s created new openings in the
British market resulting from the rising US beef shortfall, causing New Zealand and
Australia to switch their supplies from the UK to the more attractive US market. The gap
in the British frozen beef market, which, was opened, privileged peripheral
Commonwealth suppliers specifically. This was facilitated by the prior existence of
commonwealth preferences in the form of exemption from the heavy tariff on imports of
boneless and canned beef (Hubbard, 1986). Until this time, Botswana’s beef industry was
confined to the regional market outlets of the mining complexes of the Witwatersrand in
South Africa and Central African Copperbelt (Perkins, 1991). In the late 1950’s volume
restrictions on Bechuanaland Protectorate's (now Botswana) exports in regional markets
tightened while preferential opportunities opened up in the British market (Hubbard,
1986).
The most significant demonstration of Britain’s new post-war colonial policy investment
in colonial production was the Colonial Development Corporation (CDC). The British
Secretary of State for the colonies sent the following message to the colonial
governments in commencing the CDC in 1947; “The functions of the CDC which will be
under me will be to initiate, finance and operate projects for agricultural or other
development in the colonial empire…Need for such expansion (of colonial production) is
of course very much in public minds at this moment owing to the prospect of continuing
shortages of certain commodities and increasing difficulty in obtaining adequate supplies
of dollars for purchase of raw food and raw materials from America…” (Hubbard, 1985).
A colonial development and welfare grant of 400 000 pounds was made available to the
Bechuanaland Protectorate explicitly for drilling boreholes. The drilling went ahead on an
unparalleled scale, contributing to the 34% increase in the cattle population between 1949
and 1959. Veterinary expenditure was expanded greatly following the restitution in 1955
of the UK grants-in-aid to balance the colony’s budget. Initial plans for the operation was
to build a herd of 356 000 over twenty years (Hubbard, 1986). The lack of water supplies
was perceived as limiting expansion in the livestock sector, and was also seen as reducing
carrying capacity of the range. For this reason the CDF/CD&W grants for borehole
drilling, totaling over 850 000 pounds between 1935 - 1965, proved to be a direct and
essentially important subsidy to the livestock sector in the protectorate. By 1965,
however, a transformation had occurred in the role of water provisioning for livestock
production in the protectorate and livestock water development was most intense in the
sandveld areas by private livestock holders (Hubbard, 1986). The skewed distribution of
livestock holding and borehole ownership grew through mutual reinforcement over time
(Emery, 1980).
Skewed patterns of ownership, originating in customary relations in cattle were preserved
and reinforced as market relations in cattle became more valuable. The less advantaged
had two alternatives:
a) arable crop production
b) labor migration - normally to mines in South Africa.
Mine labor returnee's invested part of their cash earnings in procuring of one or two head
of cattle. This was because, for households occupied in subsistence crop production,
ownership or at least access to cattle was necessary to successfully cultivate the arable
field (Lawry, 1983).
Post-colonial: 1966 - present
The skewed patterns of livestock ownership have given rise to a divergence of production
aspirations and successively having implications toward influencing the construction of
the livestock policy. It is estimated that 15% of the farmers own 75% of the estimated
national herd. This group is quite small but includes some wealthy individuals including
key political leaders. The small farmers (within 10 heads or less), including those without
cattle, put emphasis on subsistence crop production. For the big cattle barons, arable
production is not important. Whatever government assistance program has been accorded
to these small arable farmers, it has been limited to maintaining their status as subsistence
farmers (Lawry, 1983) and to keep them in the rural areas, to curb rural-urban migration
and the resultant urban unemployment problems.
During the colonial period government revenues from cattle were usually more than
double government recurrent expenditures on the industry. By contrast, in the postcolonial era, state expenditures on the industry began to exceed tax revenues from it
(Hubbard, 1986). Amin (1976) has argued that, historically, nations first penetrated by
colonial expansion experienced a period of surplus in their balance of payments. This
began to slowly deteriorate as unfavorable terms of trade evolved to the advantage of
manufactured goods and to the detriment of peripheral exports. The shift in the fiscal
position of the industry, post 1970, reflects the alteration in the industry’s status from
being the leading sector overall in the economy while remaining the hub for private local
investment (Hubbard, 1986). The result is that the industry has contributed a declining
proportion of public revenue while attracting an increasing amount of public expenditure
as infrastructural support for the private investment -veterinary fences, stock route
maintenance, breeding and management research, bull purchase subsidy, and artificial
insemination subsidies etc (Hubbard, 1986).
When the UK (Botswana’s European export market) joined the EEC in 1975, Botswana’s
beef exports were threatened by two impending obstacles. Firstly, the tariff and quota
barriers and secondly, the satisfaction of European beef quality standards since the EEC
Veterinary Commission replaced the UK Ministry of Agriculture as the licensing
authority for meat imports. Botswana was thus negotiating both for favorable access and
acceptance of her ‘veterinary credentials' (Hubbard, 1986). However, Botswana did
manage to gain reasonably favorable access for her beef to the EEC markets in a special
concession appended to the Lome Convention Agreement (Hubbard, 1986).
Theoretical Framework
The features and dynamics of the global system - imperialism, colonialism, the world
market, foreign trade, flows of capital investment, and Multi National Corporation
(MNC) investments are viewed as forces influencing the socio-economic development of
nations (Jaffee, 1998). The Dependency Theory for instance, was developed in response
to modernization and economic growth models that accentuate internal national, rather
than external international effects on development. International-level models tend to
focus on the interaction between nation-states and the political-economic forces that
regulate these interactions. Trade lies at the center of these models because the exchange
of goods raises questions about international specialization (international division of
labor based on David Ricardo’s (1933) law of comparative advantage), methods of
production, export vulnerability, and the balance of payments and the terms of trade
(Jaffee, 1998).
Wallerstein (1975) rejects the view that national development can be explained by
examining the internal characteristics of nation states. Instead nations are seen as systems
that are heavily influenced by economic forces and patterns of exchange at the
international level. Like individuals in a stratified society who occupy social-class
positions, nations occupy class-like structural positions in the world economy. These
three major positions are the core, the semi-periphery, and the periphery (Wallerstein,
1975).
Since the colonial era, food and agricultural systems across the world have gone through
constant reorganization as they have been integrated into capitalist market relationships.
Peripheral countries’ specialization in extractive raw material and the agricultural
commodity production forced on them during the colonial and post-colonial period,
helped integrate rural social systems within the broader market and political relations of
the world economy. The state of Third World agriculture cannot be understood outside
this world historical context. Already weakened peasant agriculture has experienced
further marginalization and deterioration as market forces have claimed rural resources
such as land, labor and government subsidies (McMichael and Reynolds, 1994).
The central historical fact of the colonial era was the violent incorporation of colonial
lands and people into an expanding world capitalist economy driven by the process of
commodification (McMichael and Reynolds, 1994). The cumulative effect of colonialism
was to generate a pattern of world economic specialization whereby agriculture, and
agricultural exports, became the defining specialty of the region that became known as
the Third World. This condition continues even today (McMichael and Reynolds, 1994).
Amin (1976) introduced the concept of disarticulation in his theory of peripheral
capitalism and underdevelopment. Disarticulation refers to missing or nonexistent links
between segments of the economy. DeJanvry (1981) makes a useful distinction between
social disarticulation and sectoral disarticulation. Sectoral disarticulation (associated with
multiplier effect) refers to an economic structure that lacks forward and backward
linkages between productive sectors. Sectoral disarticulation has negative economic
consequences because the relatively dynamic economic activity in one sector does not
spill over and stimulate economic activity in other domestic sectors. This is due to the
fact that the other sectors that supply the inputs and receive the output from the extractive
sector do not exist within the peripheral economy, but is, located in the industrialized
center states.
Social disarticulation (associated with accelerator effect - a rise in consumer demand)
refers to the situation where the relationship between the capacity to produce and the
capacity to consume is weak and tenuous. The concept of social disarticulation is a useful
tool for understanding the relationship between the world-economic orientation and the
political practices carried out in peripheral nations. In peripheral states, internal demand
is not the driving force for production. The capacity to produce in peripheral economies
depends on foreign exchange revenue derived from export trade. Because of social
disarticulation, foreign exchange levels depend on the level of demand in the world
economy.
The combination of state neglect and national and international competition has fuelled
the long-term historical decline in Third World peasant agriculture. The
commercialization of agriculture has undermined the viability of household food
production as a livelihood strategy for peasant populations and a subsistence base for the
rural poor (Barkin, 1987). Due to the restricted employment options and resultant poverty
of displaced peasants, the process of de-peasantization has in most parts of the world
been associated with growing misery and hunger.
The organization and mobilization of the subordinate classes to counter the growing
injustices against their lot can be facilitated by the existence of an organized civil society.
Civil society associations provide the opportunity for interaction and communication
among the subordinate social classes. The ability of mobilized and organized segments of
the population to have an impact on the openness of political institutions is further
contingent upon the existence of a "potentially autonomous” state. The final factor
shaping the prospects for democracy is the “transnational structure of power.” This takes
us back to the international level of analysis with a focus upon the position of a nation in
the international division of labor and the geopolitical and economic relationship between
nations (Jaffee, 1998).
Discussion
As earlier on indicated, it was the introduction of the borehole technology, which brought
marginal land under full production. The diverse ecological conditions that shaped the
land use patterns in Botswana prior to colonialism were ‘homogenized’ for cattle
production. Cattle production could now take place at any place within the country as
water has been made available even within the Kalahari Desert. The diversity that existed
was systematically eliminated as it posed as a restraint to the growth of the beef industry.
Rangeland Degradation
The increased role of cattle as a commodity of exchange has shaped subsequent
rangeland utilization and management policies. The industry has attracted participation
by both the upper and the emerging middle class sectors of the local population, who
operate as absentee managers. This socio-economic elitist interest group has over the
years been pushing through their agenda of privatizing communal land, and subsequently
grabbing it for their individual benefit. The formulation of the Tribal Grazing Land
Policy (TGLP) in 1970 and of late National Policy on Agricultural Development (NPAD)
in 1991 and the resultant land grab by the elite, demonstrates the ability of the elite to
desist policy and allocate resources to its own advantage (Parsons, 1981 ; Picard, 1980).
Hardin's (1968) model of 'the tragedy of the commons' forms the basis for the
conceptualization of the defunct Tribal Grazing Land Policy (TGLP) and of late, the
National Policy on Agricultural Development. One of the major components of these
policies advocates for the fencing of communal rangeland by individuals, groups or
communities. The proposed fencing under NPAD will be on those areas where the land
use is predominantly livestock grazing and where there are existing boreholes.
Individuals, groups and communities will be allowed to fence 8km by 8km radius around
their boreholes. It is important to note that there are few, if any, community boreholes in
the communal grazing areas and that large cattle farmers own most of these boreholes.
According to this policy, the owner of two or more boreholes in the communal grazing
area may be allowed to develop up to a maximum of two farms.
The drive towards privatization of communal land has been interpreted in the light of
Hardin’s (1968) hypothesis of the general conclusive assumption that natural resources
should either be privatized or controlled by a Central Government Authority to ensure
sustainable use. The interpretation is silent on the possibility of communal management
of the commons or rather visualizing a community as a private entity. Furthermore,
NPAD does not have any comprehensive strategy on how the remaining communal
rangeland is to be managed. Unless institutions are in place to help regulate communal
rangeland utilization, the communal land will continue experiencing degradation, as users
of such land are not clearly defined, resulting in the dual grazing rights enjoyed by the
farm owners. The solution to communal rangeland degradation does not lie in the
privatization of the communal land, but in the revitalization of local institutions.
TGLP has been evaluated and was found to be a failure since the expected improvement
in range management was not realized. In fact, some of the TGLP farm owners graze
their cattle in the communal rangeland, and when conditions deteriorate, they move their
cattle into their farms where they have exclusive rights. The dual grazing rights that farm
owners seem to posses worsens conditions within the communal grazing lands since such
farmers keep large herds of cattle. White (1993) has argued that, the poor performance in
TGLP ranches does not warrant such major changes in policy as envisaged by NPAD, for
there is no justification in expanding private farm areas.
TGLP, from a programmatic point of view, was silent on smallholder livestock
development. The advocates of NPAD and TGLP see these policies as symbols of
efficient, commercial beef production. In line with this school, Mazonde (1993) observed
that although cattle numbers have doubled since 1966, and whereas government has
heavily subsidized the cattle sector, production management indicators especially in the
communal (traditional) areas have not improved much, if at all. He concluded that cattle
management in the commercial areas has been relatively better. To support his argument,
he pointed out that while the commercial farming sub-sector records a calving percentage
of about 70%, by contrast the communal sub-sector records a meager 50% (Mazonde,
1993). Such Production biased statements have dominated the mainstream government
policy-making corridors and are used to sway policy towards privatization of communal
lands so as to increase production in the export-oriented industry.
Abel (1987) argued that policy makers seek evidence to support their political agendas.
Conservation and certain productivity arguments happen to coincide with, and are
therefore employed to back policies, which have their origins not in science, but in
ideology (Abel, 1987). In a desperate move seemingly aimed at preserving the communal
rangelands, reactionary elements have emerged, questioning the prevailing scientific
evidence that Botswana’s communal rangelands are degraded and disputing such
evidence. Abel (1987) has argued that the diagnosis of degradation has relied on the
discredited theory of vegetation change. He argues that this theory does not work where
rainfall is highly variable, mainly because this variation is more important than stocking
density in determining the composition, structure and productivity of vegetation in these
circumstances. His argument is that vegetation change in these environments does not
constitute environmental degradation.
Abel and Blaikie (1989) proposed the following definition of degradation; "degradation
has occurred only where there has been an effectively irreversible decline in the rate of
output of livestock products from the range under a specified system of management."
Abel (1987) argues that the ground may be barer, but if the range still produces the same
output per unit area, degradation, for that system of management, has not occurred. Abel
and Blaike (1989) simplified degradation to fit into some economic model, thus
undermining the intrinsic value of the environment and subjecting it to the whims of
man’s productive forces. The environment is here perceived as a resource, not as an
ecosystem and therefore can be exploited.
White (1992), like Abel (1987), has questioned and stood opposed to the privatization of
the communal rangelands. He supports a productivistic approach to communal rangeland
utilization. White has argued that "lowering the stocking rate raises productivity per
animal, but it does so at the price of reducing productivity per hectare" (White, 1992).
White (1992) argues that the above statement is based on the research findings by the
Animal Production Research Unit (APRU) and analyzed by Abel and Blaikie (1989).
The study found out that one of the primary plant responses to herbivory is to grow faster
- hence increased grazing pressure stimulates primary production leading to an increase
in secondary production. Kloppenburg (1991) has argued that what we know as scientific
knowledge has attained virtually undisputed intellectual hegemony though there could be
clear evidence that the basis of such science is politically or economically motivated.
Abel (1987) and White (1992) were responding to the evidence that in the communal
areas, the main vegetation changes consequent upon heavy grazing are bushencroachment and changes in species composition of grasses mainly from perennial to
annual species (Ringrose et. al. 1996). Darkoh, (1999) also observed that, in terms of
desertification, Botswana is one of the most affected countries in the Kalahari Region of
Southern Africa. Problems include overstocking, large-scale vegetation depletion and
changes, especially around livestock watering points, and accelerated soil erosion by
wind, sheet-wash and gulling. Recent satellite imagery reveals that there has been
considerable uncontrolled development of cattle-posts in areas set aside for wildlife
management, resulting in the emergence of land use conflicts and extensive degradation
of the tree savanna (Darkish, 1999).
Beef marketing
Botswana Meat Commission’s (BMC) near monopsony within Botswana imply that local
beef prices are by and large determined by BMC export prices. The export monopsony
together with the smallness of the domestic market, a result of a small population and of
what Amin (1976) referred to as ‘social disarticulation’, ensures that price decreases on
external markets can be passed on to the cattle production sector without reducing
abattoir throughput. For the BMC, increasing sales and ensuring product acceptability in
the EC market is the main concern. This is best exemplified by the efforts made to
maximize sales in Botswana’s best market (EC), the restructuring of the Lobatse abattoir
in the mid-1970’s to meet EC production requirements and adherence to EC veterinary
standards and regulations regarding cattle movement (Hubbard, 1986). These standards
have been met meticulously in spite of their environmental and social costs. This brings
into play the question of how autonomous peripheral state policies are from international
market forces. Once the cattle sector was integrated and propelled to the status of lead
industry, its vital role in the national economy and its dependence upon foreign demand,
served to subordinate the state to the market. Hence state policies regarding this sector to
some degree are not authentic, but indirectly determined by the market.
In Botswana, cattle are sold through a range of marketing outlets, including the BMC
which holds the monopoly of beef exports (69.7%), local butcheries (8.2%), traders (7%),
auction (6.7%), or other farmers (8.2%) (Arntzen, 1998). BMC is not a private, profit-
accumulating firm, but, is statutorily instructed to carry on business efficiently and
economically and in such a manner as to promote the interests of the livestock industry of
Botswana (Hubbard, 1986). Hence the BMC’s investments in processing and product
innovations at the Lobatse abattoir have since been geared more and more to the
requirements and standards of the export market. The proposal by UK veterinarians for
instance, with regard to the maximum veterinarily acceptable level of throughput and
alterations to equipment has been adhered to religiously (Hubbard, 1986).
In late 1973, Botswana found herself at a historical peak in her beef export marketing
opportunities; a result of a generalized shortage of beef, which had more than doubled in
price since 1971. In addition, shortages of beef were forecast to continue (Hubbard,
1986). The existence of such favorable conditions meant that the BMC could pick and
choose the best markets. However, since Botswana’s beef had been tied to the EC market
through preferential ‘privileges’, the BMC was obliged to continue supplying this market
despite the existence of other market opportunities. In a way, the preferential trade
agreement served as a constraint for Botswana’s beef to take advantage of the existence
of alternative markets, which may have been more lucrative.
Valuation of Cattle
Agro-pastoralism is the prevalent form of agricultural land use on communal lands and
consists of small-scale, low-input animal husbandry. It yields a range of direct use values,
including milk, live animal sales, meat, draught power, manure, as well as cultural nonuse values. Commonly associated with this is low-input, small-scale crop production
drawing on draught power from the livestock. Livestock are mostly cattle with some
goats, and crops are mostly millet, sorghum and maize/corn. These traditional agricultural
land uses are being simplified to beef production monocultures. Below is a discussion of
how some cattle use values have been undermined, as production effort is directed to beef
production.
Notwithstanding its high livestock population, Botswana imports large quantities of milk
and milk products. The common perception is that cattle are primarily kept for meat and
milking traditional cows is not systematically undertaken. However, there is evidence
indicating the existence of a dairy sector in the past. Abel (1987) noted that in the
Mathethe region, milk represented 65% of the energy output and 35% of the cash output
of livestock, and was more important than meat. Boitumelo (1993) observed that there
have also been some attempts to establish a dairy sector in communal areas close to urban
areas since cattle-posts are situated far from villages or towns. The milking of indigenous
cows within the communal areas, provides milk supplies for household consumption
during the rainy season (Milk consumption in the rural areas is/was usually seasonal.).
Most of the milk was sold in the village areas in the form of local milk products (madila sour milk - resembles cottage cheese). Often it was not possible to sell milk or sour milk
because of distance from villages or towns. In such instances, farmers often made cream.
The milk was collected and sold to a farmer who had a cream separator. The cream was
collected daily and stored in a cream can. After a week the cream can containing the sour
cream was taken to the nearest railway line to transport to a creamery. At the creamery
the acidity of the cream was neutralized, the cream was pasteurized and made into butter.
The production of cream earned Botswana half a million Pula of foreign currency in the
years 1975 - 78 (Konandreas, et al., 1983).
In some parts of the country, for example, the northeastern part, farmers in the
communal areas would in exchange for grazing permission for their lactating cows within
the neighboring Tati Company farms allow the farm owner to milk their cows. Today,
there is no creamery in Botswana, nor do the farmers still make any cream. The
importance of this occupation has declined in most areas, probably due to the more
favorable price of beef, thus the recognition that milk deprivation is responsible for
poorer calf growth (Konandrreas et al., 1983).
Cattle-Wildlife Conflict
Cattle spread further and further into the western and northern sandveld where they not
only had to compete for grazing with wildlife, but also depends increasingly on fragile
ecosystems with much lower and more variable carrying capacity (Cooke, 1985).
European meat import regulations require that fences be built to stop cattle from
contracting foot and mouth disease, which the cattle are said to contract from wild
buffalo. The ecological damage due to the beef industry on Botswana's wildlife has been
considerable because of the concentration of cattle and wildlife within the fenced areas.
According to Albertson (1998), vast areas of wildlife habitats have been degraded in
many parts of the country. The main cause is the expansion of the cattle industry.
There is mounting pressure from both local and foreign environmental groups for several
developed countries to deny Botswana cattle subsides under terms of trade agreed to
under the Lome convention. These subsidies, coupled with strict restrictions/standards on
imports, have led to the construction of veterinary fences in Botswana. If the veterinary
fences in Botswana remain, then it is likely that several species of wildlife will be
damaged, because their migration routes will be disrupted. Scientists invited by the
government of Botswana to study Botswana's cattle problems, concluded that "when the
interests of wildlife and cattle come into conflict, the wildlife loses" (Albertson, 1998).
Construction of veterinary disease control fences has intensified in the last two yearsmostly in response to an outbreak of Contagious Bovine Pleuropneumonia (CBPP) that
threatened to invade export-orientated beef commercial ranches. Veterinary control
fences, endorsed by the International Organization of Animal Health as "valuable tools in
disease control," are primarily intended to safeguard Botswana’s beef export industry.
However, the fences in question (erected without environmental, social or economic
impact assessments) mostly bisect huge wildlife areas with few or no cattle and, since
construction, have caused widespread damage to wildlife populations in many parts of
Botswana. Aerial surveys show conclusively, that where veterinary fences have been
erected, sharp declines in wildlife numbers follow.
Conclusion
As already pointed out in the text, Botswana's communal grazing land problems are
primarily a question of identifying and promoting institutions capable of better regulating
communal rangeland use, and enhancing the utility value of cattle by emphasizing other
cattle use values than parochially be preoccupied with the export beef drive, which is
market driven and precarious. More often than not, livestock producers are criticized for
environmental problems that could be avoided with more appropriate institutional,
pricing and policy arrangements (Mearns, 1996). In Botswana for instance, besides the
privatization drive there is no mention of the need to empower local institutions to help
improve the management of the communal rangelands.
Private property is seen as a panacea for improved communal rangeland management and
increased productivity based on politicized science. Kloppenburg (1991) has advocated
for the reconstruction of an alternative science, an undertaking that will require the
recognition and legitimation of alternative sources of knowledge production for
agriculture - sources that now have no voice, or speak without authority, or simply are
not heard in contemporary agriscientific discourse. He observed that the revival of local
knowledge should be an essential part of such reconstruction.
Since the problems associated with cattle production require not only the efforts of the
farmers but also appropriate policies and product pricing, the participation of both civil
society, state and market actors seem most appropriate. Flora (2001) noted that the state,
like the market, is a dynamic, contested sector. Within the state sphere, which sets the
rules and conditions for the market and the safety nets for its citizens, the terrain is very
contested. In the case of Botswana, state actors have predominantly been the socioeconomic elite or are greatly influenced by this group. To this end, the state seems to be
devoted to its accumulation function at the expense of its legitimation functions. In the
context of Botswana, civil society is still not yet a well-developed sector, and the few
existing NGO’s seem not to have taken an interest in the cattle sector, except in their
opposition to its expansion into wildlife areas. Thus the fate of this sector appears to lay
in the hands of the producers, with little or no resistance from other sectors of society,
partly a result of lack of such a forum.
Communities are shaped by three sets of institutions: market, the state, and civil society.
These institutions influence the resources available to local people. Increasingly around
the world, landowners are not land managers, nor do they live in the community of place.
This separation of ownership and management, whether through rental agreements or
management contracts, puts more emphasis on financial capital and less on natural and
social capital. Though the state should make markets possible it has the additional
responsibility of providing for the public welfare (Flora, 2001). Buttel (1998) observed
that governments are simultaneously a fundamental force underlying environmental
destruction and the principal agent of sustainability reforms. Hence the state in fulfilling
its accumulation function should not neglect its legitimation function.
Civil society determines the common good. Groups in society, formal and informal, join
together around common interests or values. Through their organized activity they
influence the market and the state. When things are judged as moral because they are
profitable and the state therefore acts only to increase profitability, at the expense of the
other important roles - protecting those in society who cannot protect themselves and
protecting the environment. Healthy agroecosystems with multiple community benefits
are more likely to be sustainable than agroecosystems, which enhance only one of the
capitals (Human, Natural, Financial and Social capital)(Flora, 2001). Grazing systems are
usually geared to the production of multiple outputs, although ranching systems are
generally geared more narrowly towards meat production. Integrated crop-livestock
systems can be environmentally beneficial, as by-products from one production
component serve as input to other components (Mearns, 1996).
References
Abel, N., 1987 Carrying capacity, rangeland degradation and livestock development
policy for the communal rangelands in Botswana. Presented at a Conference on
Botswana's Environment. Kalahari Conservation Society. Gaborone, Botswana.
Abel, N. and Blaikie P. 1989. Land Degradation, Stocking Rates and Conservation
Policies in the Communal Rangelands of Botswana and Zimbabwe. Land Degradation
and Rehabilitation 1: 101 - 124.
Albertson, A. 1998. Northern Botswana Veterinary Fences: Critical Ecological Impacts.
Okavango Peoples Wildlife Trust. Maun. Botswana.
Amin, S., 1976. Unequal Development. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Arntzen, J. W. and Veenendaal, E. M. 1986: A Profile of Environment and Development
in Botswana, NIR, University of Botswana, Gaborone, 1-172.
Arntzen, J., 1998. Economic valuation of communal rangelands in Botswana: A case
study. CREED working Paper series No.17.
Barkin, David. 1987. The end to food self-sufficiency in Mexico. Latin
American Perspectives 14: 271-97.
Baron, M. and Barkin, D. “Innovation in Indigenous Production Systems to Maintain
Tradition” in Flora, C. (ed) 2001. Interactions between Agroecosystems and Rural
Communities. CRC Press, Boca Raton.
Boitumelo, W.S., 1993. "Peri-urban Small-scale Dairy Research Programme in
Botswana". In Kategile, J.A. and Mubi, S. (eds). Future of Livestock Industries in East
and Southern Africa. ILCA, Ethiopia.
Buttel, F.H., 1998. Some observations on States, world orders, and the politics of
sustainability, Organ. Environ., 11, 261.
Campbell, A. and Child, G. 1971. The Impact of Man on the Environment of Botswana.
Botswana Notes and Records 3: 91 - 110.
Cooke, H.J., 1985. The struggle against environmental degradation - Botswana's
experience. Desertification Bulletin 8, 9 -15.
Darkoh, M., 2000. Desertification in Botswana. RALA Report No. 200.
DeJanvry, A., 1981. The Agrarian Question and Reformism in Latin America. Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins University Press.
de Queiroz. J., 1993. Range Degradation in Botswana: Myth or reality? Pastoral
Development Network Paper No. 35b. Overseas Development Institute, London.
Dos Santos, T., 1970. "The structure of Dependence." American Economic Review 60:
231 - 236.
Emery, R., 1980. Development of livestock, agriculture and water supplies in Eastern
Botswana before independence: A short history and policy analysis. Rural Development
Committee, Center for International Studies, Cornel University. New York.
Flora, C., “Shifting Agroecosystems and Communities” in Flora, C. (ed) 2001.
Interactions between Agroecosystems and Rural Communities. CRC Press, Boca Raton,
London, New York and Washington D.C.
Hardin, G., 1968. 'Tragedy of the Commons.' Science 162: 1243 -1248.
Hitchcook, R., 1980. 'Tradition, Social Justice and Land Reform in Central Botswana'.
Journal of African Law 24 No.1, 1 - 34.
Hubbard M. “Botswana’s Beef Export Industry: the issue of the proposed northern
abattoir” in Harvey C. 1981. Papers on the economy of Botswana. Heinemann. London,
Nairobi and Ibadan.
Hubbard, M., 1986. Agricultural Exports and economic growth; A study of the Botswana
Beef Industry. KPI Limited. London, New York and Sidney.
Jaffee, D., 1998. Levels of socio-economic development theory. Praeger publishers.
Westport, Connecticut and London.
Kloppenburg, J. (Jr.) Social Theory and the De/Reconstruction of agricultural science:
Local knowledge for an alternative agriculture. Rural Sociology 56 (4), 1991, Pp 519 548. Rural Sociological Society.
Konandrreas, P., Anderson, F.,Trail, J., 1983. “Economic trade-off between milk and
meat production under various supplementation levels in Botswana” in ILCA Research
Report. No. 7 - 12. Addis Ababa. Ethiopia.
Lawry, S., 1983. Land Tenure, Land Policy and Small-holder livestock development in
Botswana. Land Tenure Center. University of Wisconsin - Madison. No. 78.
Mazonde, N. “Food Policy and agriculture in Botswana” in Mukandawire, R. and
Matlosa, K. (eds) 1993. Food Policy and agriculture in Southern Africa. SAPES Books.
Harare. Zimbabwe.
McMichael, P. and Reynolds, L. “Capitalism, Agriculture and World economy” in Leslie
Sklair (1994) Capitalism and Development. London and New York. Routledge.
Mearns, R.,1996. When Livestock are Good for the Environment: Benefit-sharing of
environmental goods and services. Invited paper for the World Bank/FAO Workshop,
“Balancing Livestock and the Environment”. Washington, D.C., an associated event to
the Fourth World Bank Conference on Environmentally Sustainable Development.
Mthethwa, J., 1982. Man and cattle in Africa; A study of social change in pastoral
societies in Botswana. Verlag breitenbach Publishers. Saarbrucken. Fort Launderdale.
Parsons, N., 1977. 'Economic History of Khama's Country in Botswana 1844 - 1930'. In
Palmer, R. and Parsons, N. (eds) 'The Roots of Rural Poverty in Central and Southern
africa', Heinemann.
Perkins, J.S., 1991. The impact of borehole dependent cattle grazing on the environment
and society of eastern Kalahari sandveld, Central District of Botswana. Ph.D Thesis
(unpublished), University of Sheffield.
Picard, L., 1980/1979. 'Bureaucrats, Cattleand Public Policy: Land Tenure Changes in
Botswana'. Comparative Political Studies., Vol. 13 No.3.
Polanyi, K. 1944. The Great Transformation. Farrar and Rinehart, Inc. New York.
Ricardo, D., 1933. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. London: Dent(1817).
Ringrose, S., Chanda, R., Musisi, N., and Sefe, F.,1996. Environmental change in the
Mid-Boteti area of North-central Botswana: biophysical processes and human
perceptions. Environmental management 20 (3), 397 - 410.
Ringrose, S. and Matheson,W. 1987. Desertification in Botswana: Progress towards a
Visible Monitoring System. Desertification Control Bulletin 13, 6 - 11.
Roep, D. and Bruin, R. "Regional marginalization, styles of farming and technology
development."in Van der Ploeg and Long (eds). Born from Within . Assun: Van Gorcum.
Pp. 217 - 227.
Schapera, I., 1943. 'Native Land Tenure in the Bechuanaland Protectorate'. Lovedale.
Van Rensberg, H.J. 1971. Range Ecology in Botswana. FAO Technical Document No.2.
UNDP/SF/359 (Bot1), Rome.
Van Vegten, J.A., 1981. Man-made vegetation changes: an example from Botswana's
Savanna. Working Paper No.40, NIR., Gaborone.
Wallerstein, I. "The Present State of the Debate on World Inequality," in I. Wallerstein,
ed., l975. World Inequality. Montreal: Black Rose Books, 9-28.
White, R., 1993. Livestock Development and Pastoral Production and communal
Rangeland in Botswana. Botswana Society, Gaborone, Botswana.
White, R., 1992. Is the Livestock Industry the enemy of the Environment? Paper
presented at a conference on the future of Botswana's environment. Kalahari
Conservation Society, Gaborone.
Kutlwano Mulale
Iowa State University
107 East Hall
Ames, IA 50011
Phone: (515) 294-2882
Fax: (515) 294-3180
Affiliation: North Central Regional Center for Rural Development
Theme: Engaging Stakeholders in Support of Small Farms