Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
GRAVITY MODEL AND THE COUNTRIES CLASSIFICATION Elżbieta Czarny, Jerzy Menkes, Katarzyna Śledziewska SUMMARY We discuss the gravity equation based on Helpman’s theorem (1987) using the approach of Debaere [2005]. Unlike Debaere, we do not constrain our analysis to the split into OECD and non-OECD, but we propose an alternative division. We argue that the division of countries: OECD and non-OECD is not an appropriate representation of extracting developed from less developed countries. Instead, we propose non-OECD countries division into two groups: the first one consisting of non-OECD countries fulfilling membership criteria and the second one not fulfilling these criteria. In our setting, the less developed countries are collected only in the last group, whereas OECD and non-OECD countries fulfilling membership criteria are the developed ones. We analyze trade between pairs of countries and aggregate the results to illustrate trade between three above mentioned groups of countries in the period of 28 years (1977-2005). We show that the Helpman’s theorem designed to explain trade among developed countries still does not find much support among less developed ones unless the last group is properly extracted. As expected, in our test we got confirmation of the Helpman’s theorem for the developed countries and only a very week confirmation in the group of the less developed ones. However, surprisingly intensive is trade between developed and developing partners. This might be a result of growing intensity of trade in intermediate products in the last decades and international trade liberalization (especially under WTO auspices after 1995). Keywords: International trade, gravity models JEL classification: F15 1. Introduction During the last decade international cooperation has changed. The position of the Asian countries in world trade improved rapidly. Many countries intensified their trade with the world thanks to international trade liberalisation (especially under WTO auspices). Below we examine whether the changes in the world economy are compatible to the established theoretical settings. Especially, we check whether the Helpman’s theorem [1987] is still valid only for the developed countries, as it was originally meant, or it can be applied (at least to some extent) for the less developed ones1. We argue, that some surprising results indicating growing intensity of trade between less developed countries (for non-OECD countries see e.g. Hummels and Levinsohn [1995]) are (at least partly) consequence of improper extracting of developed and less developed countries. Especially, the most favored division of countries into OECD and non-OECD is not a proper approximation of a division into developed and less developed ones. We propose an alternative. We divide the nonOECD countries into two groups: the first one consists of non-OECD countries fulfilling membership criteria and the second one of countries not fulfilling these criteria. We argue that the less developed countries are collected only in the last group, whereas the first one consists of the developed ones. In our analysis we cover all countries in the world. We analyze trade between pairs of countries and aggregate the results to illustrate trade among three groups: OECD-members, non-OECD countries fulfilling membership criteria and other nonOECD countries. We proceed as follows: in section 2 we write about rationale for our countries’ classification, in section 3 we present theoretical background of our analysis, in section 4 we discuss the results of our empirical findings, and section 6 consists of conclusions. 2. OECD in territorial division of the world Territorial division of the world subjects to evolutionary changes. Geographical extension and composition of territorial units is affected by many factors, including social, cultural and economic ones. Fundamental importance got those, which constitute a capacity to provide a state security through participation in setting up the international security community. 1 We divide countries into developed and less developed ones not in line with the established split into developed and developing countries originating in the World Bank. Even ignoring this precise definition of World Bank we find our intuitive split best fitting with analytical purpose if this paper. Political boundaries are artificial, as they do not constitute an integral part of the physical world map. A territory may be perceived as a unit, or as a multiplicity of interdependent territories indistinctly divided by natural elements. From the point of view of economics the world coherency is still visible, though geophysical criteria of a territory differentiation are not as important as before. Historically, criteria of marking the second level in a ternary division into: I. states, II. continents and III. the globe, have been determined by geographical closeness, creating interdependency on one side, and natural obstacles preventing contacts, on the other. Geographical discoveries and resulting from them transcontinental empires tightened intra-imperial tights, even those trans-continental, making them stronger than tights among one continent empires. In the 18-th century Spain of Charles II, the first “Empire on which the sun never sets”, economical, social and cultural distance from Spain to its American possessions was shorter than the remoteness of Catholic Spain from Protestant England. Simultaneously, starting with 17-th century, alongside with establishing by a method of coordination, a modern international community, states regard international law norms as one of the tools of implementing their national interests corresponding to the adopted values. Making international law norms, states agree to restrict their liberties considering the norms to be a protective umbrella and an instrument to engage other states in cooperation towards non-antagonistic targets. An increasing number and scope of norms is visible in the process of international law making. But yet what has been a novelty of 20-th century and what characterises currently entered agreements is the increasing complexity of regulated matters. Agreements not only specify the trade terms but also provide space for common political, social and economic interests and generally in constituting international organisations institutionalising cooperation at the very moment of being established. Participation in international organisations and agreements creates new form of closeness of states. Numerous criteria allow to isolate as level II territories in the above mentioned ternary division such communities as: EU/EC, OECD, NAFTA and NATO. Undoubtedly, not only political, social, cultural and economic distances from Warsaw to Minsk are bigger than those to Lisbon, Washington or Sydney. Distance in km from Seoul to Phenian is misleading to anyone who knows the world not only from the globe reading. Within Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD), as in other above mentioned groups of states, cooperation is a function of communication and mutual opening of autonomous sub-systems within a pluralistic one (Deutsch [1964,58]). Below it is shown that the fundamental OECD principles allow to divide the world states into those meeting criteria of the organisation membership and those who do not fulfil them, considering this division as an approximated split into more and less developed states (below we name them developed and developing countries). OECD2 is a transcontinental space, in geophysical sense, being at the same time economically, legally and politically homogeneous. From its very beginning it made a cornerstone of peaceful order construction and economic and social prosperity of Western European countries, being the European component of the Western Hemisphere. Not only open market economy, relatively high level of development and OECD legal instruments implementation but also pluralistic democracy and human rights respect are sine qua non conditions of its membership. OECD analysed by its aspiration and ability to broaden its membership, is characterised by weighty time caesurae. The first stage of the Organisation construction was the period 1961-69, although it was formally established in 1961. Its members were: Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, France, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, United Kingdom and the United States. This stage extension till 1969 was caused by politically conditioned Italian (1962), Japanese (1964) and Finnish (1969) accessions. The second stage falls on years 1971-73 marked by plumping the borders meaning a “small enlargement” with Australia (in 1971) and New Zealand (1973) who became joiners confirming their uninterrupted presence in trans-Atlantic area and choosing to directly participate in the Organisation further developments. The third stage falling on mid 90-ies of the 20-th century 2 OECD was transformed from OEEC (Organisation for European Economic Co-operation) established in Paris on April 16, 1948. OEEC was a frame for the European Recovery Program (ERP) transferring resources to facilitate recovery and reconstruction of European economies and their cooperation with the USA in efforts to revitalise the continent. OEEC has connected Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, United Kingdom, Trieste and German western occupation zones (the Federal Republic of Germany joined in 1949). The organisation formula has directly linked the mentioned states with the USA and Canada. OEEC has began the process of the “Atlantic bridge” construction. In 1959 OEEC was joined by Spain, 1954 united Yugoslavia and in 1957 Finland got the observer statute. All the previously mentioned countries, jointly with the USA and Canada, founded OECD by the agreement from 14 December 1960. OECD is active since September 30, 1961. consisted in the Organisation expansion and repelling the Soviet influence space. Under the US political pressure a long prevented OECD opening towards new members took place. Former member states of the Council for Mutual Economic Aid (CMEA) joined the Organisation: the Czech (in 1995), Hungary and Poland (1996) and Slovakia (in 2000). The accession, was intentionally designed by its American originator as a reiteration of the way of both victorious and defeated states of Western Hemisphere towards “security community” full membership. OECD accession has to be, and in fact has been, the beginning of the “Royal Road” of the new members towards European (EU) and transatlantic (NATO) institutions3. Through the OECD threshold open for Central European states passed also Mexico (in 1994) and South Korea (in 1996). Their long lasting will and readiness had previously encountered a barrier of OECD institutional and functional inability to adopt new members. The OECD, who derives from and promotes vicinity, delimits with outer boundaries the coherent space, distinguished by important institutional, legal and economic factors, significantly different from the out of area space. Currently, OECD members are thirty states joined by common acceptance for democratic rules and open market economy. Still, many countries formally meeting the membership criteria stay outside the Organisation4. Even the EU members (meeting institutional, legal and political terms underlying the OECD), not only new states (since January 2001) such as Bulgaria and Romania, but also Cyprus, Estonia, Lithuania, Latvia, Malta and Slovenia members since May 2004, have not acceded OECD. Additionally, the Organisation maintains close relations with over 70 countries of all continents (25 states got the status of a permanent or a full participant of at least one of the OECD Committees, while 50 states cooperate with OECD in many fields). All those states are member candidates and for institutional and political reasons stay outside the Organisation. Political readiness of some of the states faces lack of OECD reaction. 3 Still, public opinion and politicians in transforming states interest in participation in Western Hemisphere institutions has focused on NATO and EU/EC accession, while other organisations and institutions membership was considered merely as means towards the final aim of target institutions membership and thus underestimated (that was the case of OECD as well as the Council of Europe membership). 4 In May this year OECD decided to open for potential accession of Chile, Estonia, Israel, Slovenia and Russia, as well as to intensify cooperation oriented towards future accession of Brasil, China, India, Indonesia and South Africa. Within the adopted presumptions, those non–OECD countries meeting the formal accession criteria and not able to join because of the Organisation inability to expand, should be in parallel to the OECD member states, treated as a separate group. As this group is more like the OECD countries than the ones not sharing the OECD fundamental principles and not meeting economic criteria underlying the accession, it is a mistake to group them among the ones not sharing OECD principles and not to the group consisting also in the OECD members. 3. Theoretical Background In the simplest form of the gravity equation, it is expected that bilateral trade between two countries is directly proportional to the product of the countries’ GDPs5. The further expectation is that bigger and more similar countries tend to trade more intensively with each other than the smaller and differentiated ones. Such gravity model with its more sophisticated versions has been for years “the workhorse for empirical studies” in international economics (Eichengreen, Irwin [1997]). In this setting, the trading countries produce differentiated goods for international monopolistic competitive markets and trade freely with varieties of many final products. Each country specializes in production and export of different types of final products. The demand is assumed to be identical and homothetic across analyzed countries. Every good produced in any country is – by assumption – shipped to all other countries in quantities proportionate to GDP of the purchasing country (it is in fact similar to the standard macroeconomic idea of marginal propensity to import6). We test the implications of the monopolistic competition model for the aggregate international trade pattern basing on Helpman [1987]. We use multicountry framework in which: – i, j=1,….,C denote trading countries, 5 This model can be seen as a simplified form of a general equilibrium trade model explaining the typical level of trade between countries. It can be supplemented with dummy variables introduced into the gravity equation to account for deviations from the simple setting (and therefore from the typical level of trade) that are difficult to be measured quantitatively (e.g. the impact of common language or border, participation in a preferential trade agreements). 6 However, different marginal propensities to import express international differences in demand characteristics and are therefore more realistic than assumption of identical demand structures across analyzed countries. Further research of influence of differences in demand is presented in the new works of Feenstra and Venables. – k=1,…, N denotes products (we assume any variety of a good is a distinct product) i – y k denotes country i’s value of production of good k. In our framework, GDP of country i is a sum of values of production of all goods k (k = 1,…, N) manufactured in the analyzed country i (i = 1, …, C): N Y i yki (1) k 1 Consequently, the global GDP (Yw) is the sum of GDPs of all trading countries i: C Y W Y i (2) i 1 Further, we denote share of country’s i GDP in global GDP as si: si Y i (3) Yw If trade is balanced in every country i, then si denoting share of country’s i GDP in the global GDP influences intensity of bilateral trade between i and j. As we measure each country’s import as a fraction of its GDP, then with balanced trade it is equal to its partner’s export7. Therefore, export of product k from country i to country j equals to: X kij s j yki (4) Xkij in equation (4) depends on sj because export from i to j is equal to j’s import from i, and the latter one depends on GDP of country j. Summing up values of export of all products k manufactured in country i we get i’s total export to j. By assumption of balanced trade it is equal to i’s import from j and therefore to j’s export to i. We write this equation using equations (1) – (4) as: Y jY i X X s y s Y w s j s i Y w X ji . Y k 1 k 1 N ij N ij k j i k j i (5) 7 We analyze export of all countries, avoiding therefore disturbances resulting from the non-zero costs of international trade (e.g. tariffs and transport and insurance costs). Summing up the first and the last elements of the equation (5) we get the total trade of the analyzed pair of countries, defined as a sum of their exports (equal to the partner’s import): X ij X ji 2 w Y iY j Y (6) Formula (6) is the simplest derivation of the gravity equation. It shows that the intensity of bilateral trade depends on product of GDPs of both trading countries. The re-formulation of equation (6) with the use of the formula (5) confirms that size of the country and the difference between the trading partners matter: X ij X ji 2s i s jY w (7) A variable representing size of a country is a share of its GDP in the world’s GDP. Different values of these shares by trading partners express the differences in their sizes. According to the gravity approach, two countries of unequal sizes will not trade as intensively as two countries of similar sizes would do8. The extension of the gravity model we use, goes into evaluation of a role of the member countries in an economic region and evaluation of economic position of a region in the global economy. In the simplest setting we have two countries (i, j) constituting region A. GDP of A is therefore equal to: Y A Yi Y j (8) We define the relative shares of GDPs of every country in the regional GDP and the GDP of A relative to the global GDP as, respectively: s iA 8 Yi YA sA YA Yw E.g. if sizes of both countries are equal si = 0,1 and sj = 0,3, then their sizes influence bilateral trade with coefficient 0,064. If they were equal in size and would have exactly the same joint share in the world’s GDP as in the previous example si = sj = 0,2, then the respective coefficient would be bigger than before (0,08). If two trading partners would have shares s i = 0,1 and sj = 0,01, their sizes would influence bilateral trade with coefficient 0,024. In the last example we can see that smaller countries trade less intensively (though if they were equal si = sj = 0,055 their trade would be more intensive – coefficient 0,0605). Volume of A’s trade relative to A’s GDP depends on the position of every member country in the region and on the relative importance of the region’s GDP in the world’s one: ( X ij X ji ) / Y A 2s iAs jAs A (9) where: s iA s jA 1 because region A consists of just two countries. Reformulating the right hand side of the equation (9) we get: 2s iAs jA 1 (s iA ) 2 (s jA ) 2 (10) Equation (10) presents a simple version of Helpman’s theorem formulated under the following assumptions: both trading countries are fully specialized in their outputs, tastes in both countries are identical and homothetic, trade is free worldwide. The volume of trade relative to GDP is proportional to the dispersion index defined for the region A as: disp 1 ( s iA ) 2 iA (11) The relation presented in equation (11) is visualised in equation (12), which is a further reformulation of equations (9) and (10). In equation (12) volume of export from region A relative to A’s GDP depends on the share of A’s GDP in global GDP (sA) and on the size dispersion index of A’s members: XA s A (1 ( s iA ) 2 ) A Y iA (12) where N – number of countries in the region A (in our setting N = 2). The size dispersion index in brackets in equation (12) is maximized for countries of the same relative size (for a region consisting of two identical countries this index is equal to 0,5; in case of big dispersion the index is near to 0 - e.g. if one country’s share is 0, 99 and the other one’s is 0,01, the index is less than 0,02). Equation (12) shows that volume of trade in the region is also related to the relative size of countries constituting the analyzed region. It is expected that with increasing similarity of trading partners their bilateral trade will intensify. Helpman [1987] tested and confirmed his theorem for OECD countries. His method was used by different authors. Hummels and Levinsohn [1995] first chose for their test not only OECD, but also non-OECD countries (the last group was meant as representation of developing countries for which one can expect low intra-industry trade (IIT)). They tested the following equation: ln X t X t ij ji ij ln (1 dispersion tij )(Yt Yt ) tij i j (13) They confirmed Helpman’s findings for OECD countries. However surprisingly, they found some support for Helpman’s theorem that was designed to explain trade among developed countries, also for trade among non-OECD countries representing the developing ones. Their result was revisited by Debaere [2005]. Building on Helpman’s idea, Debaere transformed Helpman’s equation (6) using the linear form of the equation (12): A i, j X ij X ji ln i j Y Y Yi ln( s i s j ) ln 1 i Y Y 2 j Yj i Y Y j 2 (14) Debaere analyzed the surprising results for non-OECD countries obtained by Hummels and Levinsohn. He argued that by using the equation (13) with Y on the right hand side Hummels and Levinsohn allowed size of a country to have an impact on the estimation. By use of different econometric techniques and different measures of GDP Debaere found that for OECD countries the coefficient of similarity index is significant and positive. As in the work of Helpman [1987] and Hummel and Levinsohn [1995] this coefficient was statistically different from its theoretical value of 1. In Debaere [2005] it varied from 0,25 to 1,57 depending on the econometric technique. In contradiction to Hummel and Levinsohn, Debaere proved that the index of similarity does not play a significant role in trade of non-OECD countries. We extend the work of Debaere testing his equation for differently constructed groups of countries. Building on our reflections about OECD and non-OECD countries in previous section, we divide non-OECD countries into two groups. The first one consists of countries fulfilling OECD membership criteria. In the second one are gathered all non-OECD countries which not fulfil these criteria. For extraction of the last group we consider three main criteria of OECD membership: pluralistic democracy and human rights respect, open market economy and high level of country’s development. The first one has non-economic nature, whereas the next ones economic. The first condition is democratic system and respecting human rights in a country. We treat membership in transatlantic institutions as sufficient condition of fulfilling this criterion. Membership in Community of Democracies (2000) is also the sufficient condition. However, because we want to cover with our analysis a relatively long period, we can’t constrain ourselves to the above mentioned sources. We supplemented them with the data published by the Freedom House. We have chosen this source of data because of credibility of this institution and availability of required data for relatively long period. The Freedom House presents a division of the world into free, partly free and not-free countries. We treat as democratic countries “free” and “partly free” in the classification provided by the Freedom House. The second criterion is membership in WTO (and its GATT predecessor). This is a proxy for a open market economy in an analyzed country. The third criterion is a level of development approximated by GDP per capita not lower than respective GDP of the poorest OECD – member in the year of reference. In this context we consider GDP per capita in PPP as best fitting with an idea of measurement of real development. We analyze trade between pairs of countries and aggregated the results to illustrate trade among three above named groups of countries (OECD, non-OECD fulfilling membership criteria and others non-OECD countries). We made tests with current GDP. 3. Empirical research We provide an econometric test of Helpman’s prediction for pairs of countries extending Debaere’s analysis on the third group of countries (non-OECD country fulfilling membership criteria). We test the gravity equation for available pairs of countries from all three groups as dependent variable. In our estimations we base on equation: X t ij X t ji ij ln( st i st j ) ln 1 dispersion tij ln i j Yt Yt (15) which is a reformulated version of Debaere’s equation (14). In formula (15) αij represents fixed effects and can account for bilateral transportation costs, language barriers, cultural barriers, tariffs or distances. Similarity index lnsim = ( ln 1 dispersion tij ) represents the impact of dispersion index on bilateral trade. It shows how the volume of trade is related to the relative size of countries (we assume that there are C countries in the analysed region). The size index lns = ( ln( st st ) ) represents the impact of countries’ shares i j on the intensity of trade. This index varies over time. We estimate the impact of changing GDP shares on trade because 28 years covered by our analysis is sufficiently long period of time for these changes to be significant. The literature does not deliver any standard measure of GDP used to test gravity model. The authors use different measures of GDP, only rarely explaining why they choose just them. We use only current GDP in US$. We argue that because exports are reported in current prices, the most appropriate measure for the share of trade in GDP is GDP in current prices. We use this measure also for the sake of simplicity. The other researches also use GDP in PPP in current international $ but in our opinion this measure is improper. It is particularly unfavourable for developing countries whose GDP in PPP is bigger than GDP in current US dollars. We do the research using the data from Comtrade database for trade and WDI dataset for GDP. Because of poor data from earlier years we analyze trade flows in the period 1977 - 2005. We use the panel data techniques of estimation using STATA. In all cases a fixed effects model specification is preferred to a random effects model based on the Hausman test. We estimated an equation similar to the equation (14): A i, j Yi X ij X ji i j 1 i ln i ln( s s ) ln j j Y Y Y Y 2 Yj i j Y Y 2 ij (16) We analyze trade between pairs of countries and aggregate the results to illustrate trade among all groups of countries. We took into account three OECD membership criteria discussed above: democracy, WTO (earlier GATT) membership, GDP per capita measured in PPP at least as high as in the poorest OECD member (in last years it was almost always Mexico). We run regression for the OECD and countries fulfilling their membership criteria with democratic classified as “free” and “partly free” countries jointly constituting the group of developed countries. In table 1 we present the results for bilateral trade of developed and less developed countries. The results are organized as follows. In column (1) we present aggregated results for bilateral trade among developed countries. In column (2) we present trade among developed and less developed countries. In column (3) we show trade among countries not fulfilling OECD membership criteria. In the last column we analyse trade among less developed countries. Table 1. Estimation results (1) (2) 0.336 0.356 (11.83)** (15.73)** Lnsim 1.010 0.872 (46.56)** (57.72)** Constant 9.317 8.507 (65.67)** (68.02)** Observations 22929 55470 Number of group 1843 5684 R-squared 0.35 0.32 Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses ** significant at 1%; * significant at 5% Lns (3) -0.173 (4.81)** 0.081 (2.43)* 3.890 (15.74)** 23536 3478 0.02 Table 1 evidences that we got full support for Helpman’s theorem. It shows confirmation in the fact that β coefficient from equation 16 (Lnsim) is near to 1 for developed countries defined as OECD – members and countries fulfilling the three main membership criteria (with democratic defined countries “free” and “partly free” in the setting of the Freedom House). This way to extract developed countries seems to fit perfect with the theory of international trade. We got surprisingly high β coefficient in column (2) containing results for trade between developed and less developed countries, though significantly lower than we got in trade of developed partners. It can be explained with intensification of production fragmentation and consequently growing trade in intermediate goods. International trade liberalisation (especially under WTO/GATT auspices) results also in intensification of North – South type of international trade. Results in columns (3) also support the Helpman’s theorem as we got very low values of β for trade among less developed countries. As far as the size of a country is concerned, we got results compatible both with the theoretical predictions and the common sense. For the developed countries and the countries with different level of development, the trading country size is positively correlated with the intensity of bilateral trade (see Lns in columns (1) and (2)). Opposite we note in the case of the less developed countries. Their size is negatively correlated with the volume of bilateral trade (negative Lns in column (3)). It means that in the case of two less developed countries their size (measured with current GDP of respective countries) negatively affects potential trade. We obtained relatively big constant effects (αij). It can be the evidence of influence of price changes on intensity of trade. We additionally proved our thesis about division of the world into OECD and non-OECD countries as improper proxy for extracting developed and less developed countries testing the equation (16) for OECD and non-OECD countries. Results are reported in the table 2. Table 2. Results of estimation for OECD and non-OECD countries (1) Lns Lisim Constant Observations Number of group(k1 k2) R-squared 0.154 (4.33)** 0.955 (28.57)** 9.368 (61.91)** 8268 434 0.25 (2) 0.485 (21.31)** 0.963 (77.14)** 9.501 (85.51)** 51215 3825 0.45 (3) -0.013 -0.48 0.383 (15.51)** 5.29 (29.38)** 42452 4915 0.12 Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses ** significant at 1%; * significant at 5% In table 2 we present results for trade among OECD members (column (1)), trade of one OECD member with a non-OECD partner (column (2)) and trade among non-OECD partners (column (3)). In all cases we got results less fitting the theory. Especially, β coefficient for developed countries (Lnsim in column (1)) is lower than for developed and less developed countries (Lnsim in the column (2)). In this case we got confirmation of Helpman’s theorem not only for developed countries and trade between them but also (even more!) for unevenly developed countries. At the same time both coefficients are lower than respective coefficients in Table 1. The lowest β coefficient – as expected – we got for trade between less developed countries (however, it is significantly higher than in the Table 1). These results confirm our opinion that OECD is not an appropriate proxy for developed countries because it leaves aside many countries fulfilling membership criteria and not accepted by the OECD because of political and organisational reasons. The traditional division of countries makes both groups of countries more similar than the developed and less developed countries are in reality. This results in false confirmation of the Helpman’s theorem also for the less developed countries. Table 3. Tests of the gravity equation with value of (Trade/GDP) for pairs of countries as dependent variable (results reported for countries grouped depending of their level of development) Developed economies & Developed economies lns (GDP - current USD) 0.829 (25.83)** lnsim (GDP - current USD) Constant Observations Number of groups R-squared Absolute value of t statistics in parentheses significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%. Source: own calculation. 1.639 (61.36)** -0.544 (3.50)** 12566 1124 0.42 Developing economies & Developed economies Developing economies & Developing economies 0.414 0.087 (11.23)** (2.58)** 0.934 0.721 (34.17)** (22.65)** -4.939 -7.291 (23.33)** (30.47)** 27424 41235 3688 7670 0.41 0.15 Finally, in Table 3 we analyse bilateral trade between developing and developed countries (we use the respective World Bank classification). The results reported in Table 3 give confirmation of Helpman’s theorem not only for developed countries and trade between them. Interesting and compatible to the theoretical predictions is the β coefficient much bigger for developed countries then for other trade partners. Also the lowest β coefficient for trade between developing countries is important. That means that Helpman’s theorem is more meaningful for developed then for developing countries. However, also in this analysis we got results less compatible with the theoretical prediction than in our alternative test (Table 1). 4. Conclusions We got full confirmation of Helpman’s theorem for developed countries. However, in almost all analyzed cases we can confirm increasing similarity of trading partners (positive lnsim). Therefore we can expect trade expansion. This result is not surprising for trade between developed countries and less developed ones. Of course, our research proves that the developed countries become much more similar than other groups of partners and therefore they are expected to trade more intensively than any other pairs of countries do. In our opinion, increasing similarity even of very different countries can be the result a. o. of intensified cooperation in production between countries. It may change the characteristics and reasons for trade with growing intensity of trade in semi products. As for the theory, it can result in necessity of substituting the gravity approach with a new theory or supplemented gravity model with additional elements. Our division of countries proxing developed and less developed ones turned out to be better than the most used division into OECD and non-OECD countries. REFERENCE Debaere [2005], Monopolistic Competition and Trade Revisited: Testing the Model without Testing for Gravity, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 66, pp. 249-266 Deutsch K. [1964] Communication Theory and Political Integration, w: The Integration of Political Communities. Egger P. (2002) An Econometric View on Estimation of Gravity Models and the Calculation of Trade Potential, The World Economy, Vol. 25, Nr 2, pp. 297-312. Eichengreen B., Irwin D. [1997], The role of history in bilateral trade flows, in: Frankel J. (ed.) [1997, pp. 33˛-57], Frankel J. (ed.) [1997], The Regionalization of the World Economy, University of Chicago Press, Helpman E. [1987], Imperfect Competition and International Trade: Evidence from Fourteen Industrial Countries, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, vol. 1, pp. 62-81 Hummels D., Levinsohn J. (1995), Monopolistic Competition and International Trade: Reconsidering the Evidence, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 110, nr 3, pp. 799-836. The Integration of Political Communities [1964], P. E. Jacob, J. V. Toscano (eda.), Philadelphia.