Download “Exergy, Work and Economic Growth – Past and Future” Keynote

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
“Exergy, Work and Economic Growth – Past and
Future”
Keynote address
Third Global Conference on Global Warming
Lisbon, July 10-14, 2011.
Robert U. Ayres
INSEAD
Abstract
Conventional economic growth theory assumes that technological progress is exogenous, that
resources are “produced” by capital and labor and that resource consumption is a
consequence, not a cause, of economic growth. It also assumes that growth will continue
regardless of energy availability. Economists who have considered the costs of global
warming and the benefits of abatement start from this position. It seems to follow that the
costs will be felt primarily in the agricultural sector, also a comparatively small fraction (in
the OECD countries) and some damage from coastal storms and sea-level rise. Abatement is
thought of in terms of cutting GHG emissions by improved energy efficiency, and
supplementary investment in carbon capture and storage (CCS). The costs, based on this
calculus, appear to be one or two percent of global GDP. The reality is rather different and
more complex because cutting GHG emissions means drastically cutting energy consumption
(at least the fossil fuel component) which will necessitate drastic increases in energy prices.
In fact, energy is more important to the economy than the neoclassical theory admits, and the
consequences of radical supply decreases and price increases due to abatement, not to
mention the coincidental advent of “peak oil”, will be to sharply cut global growth. – with
huge social and political implications.
Energy and production
It is obvious today that energy is essential to all economic activity, and specifically to the
production of material goods and services. For hundreds of years, sunlight, wind, and flowing
water were free gifts of nature. The fact that the essence of all of these natural phenomena is
what we now call ‘useful energy’ was not understood, even by physical scientists, until the
last years of the 19th century. The word Aenergy@ was more widely used in a literary or
metaphorical sense, not in the physical sense as the fundamental Astuff@ of the universe, as
physicists and cosmologists now understand it to be. When Albert Einstein first stated the
identity between mass and energy it was headline news and, of course, the first clue to the
possibility of nuclear weapons and nuclear power.
But meanwhile, it has become clear that what really drives every action, every motion
and every physical or chemical process is useful energy in some form. It is traditional to
characterize energy as thermal (heat), kinetic (motion), chemical or electrical. Heat from
nuclear reactions might be added. Capital equipment, such as tools and machines, without
energy to activate them are inert mass. Passive forms of capital, such as buildings and roads,
produce nothing in and of themselves, however important they may be to support other
productive activity. More important, when economists speak of “labor productivity”, what
they mean is economic output (GDP) in dollars, divided by the quantity of human labor
(usually man-hours). The false implication is that rising productivity is due to better training
or better organization. The truth is that most of the past and current gains in productivity have
been and still are due to the substitution of machines (including ICT) for human and animal
muscles. More recently, machines also begin to replace human brains. The machines are
driven by cheap energy, mostly from fossil fuels, water power or nuclear reactors.
Not all energy is potentially useful. The ocean contains a lot of heat, compared to
outer space, but it is not useful or potentially useful to us. Steam is potentially useful because
it is a lot hotter than the ocean, whence there is a temperature difference. From a technical
thermodynamic perspective, work means exerting force to overcome inertia or some kind of
of resistance. It may be lifting a weight, winding a spring, pumping a fluid through a pipe,
propelling a projectile (or a vehicle) through air or water, driving an endothermic chemical
reaction or driving an electric current against a voltage.
The difference between work, in the technical sense, and useful work, arises from the
existence of human intention and control. The expansion of the universe constitutes work
against the force of gravity. Similarly, the evaporation of water from the oceans, the eruption
of volcanoes, the rise of mountains and the carving of valleys are other examples of work
done by natural forces. But those forms of work are not Auseful@ in the economic sense.
Work is useful to us humans only insofar as it is productive – which economists take to mean
contributing to GDP -- and contributes to human utility or welfare.
To extract useful work (or any kind of work) from a reservoir of some energy carrier
(e.g. fuel) energy there must also be a disequilibrium that can be exploited, because natural
forces always act in such a way as to approach thermodynamic equilibrium. The existence of
disequilibrium is usually marked by a gradient of temperature, pressure, voltage, chemical
composition or gravitational field. The potentially useful component of energy is called
exergy while the non-useful component is called anergy
Energy per se is conserved in every process. That is the First Law of thermodynamics.
But exergy is not conserved; in fact, exergy is destroyed in every action or process. Yet,
when we speak of “energy” in everyday language B as in the context of heating a house or
driving a car, it is really exergy that we are talking about. The chemical energy embodied in a
fuel such as natural gas mostly exergy, while the heat energy in the ocean is mostly anergy.
Unfortunately energy, exergy, anergy and work are all measured in the same units as energy
(e.g. joules) and it is easy to confuse energy in the form of useful work with primary energy
in the form of wind, water or fuel.
Since inert structures and inactive muscles produce nothing, it is a short step to realize
that all economic production is really comprised of products made from materials
transformed by useful work, plus services generated by those products. This is even true of
information production, processing and transmission. Moreover, useful work is an essential
input to every economic activity, just as capital (in some form) and labor (in some form) are
thought to be essential. It can be argued that useful work is obtained from Araw@ or primary
energy by the application of capital and labor, but useful energy (exergy) is also essential for
that purpose. There is no way to produce useful work from inert capital and inactive labor
alone.
It follows that exergy or useful work should be regarded as Afactors of production@ in
the economic sense, along with traditional capital and labor. Yet it is a fact that most
economic models today still consider only capital and labor as factors of production, even
though the increasing productivity of labor is largely due to inputs of energy (exergy) that
drive the machines that continue to replace human labor. Yet in traditional economics the
benefits of increasing productivity are nevertheless allocated to labor. Traditional economics
still regards energy (or useful work) as an intermediate product of the application of capital
and labor. This tradition continues, even though capital and labor, without activating energy,
can produce nothing.
Energy/GDP relationship
As long as time series data has been available (since 1850) there has been a very close
correlation between global primary energy consumption and global GDP in purchasing power
parities (PPP).See Figure 1 {Bourdaire, 2003 #7087}. Up to 1973 the relationship was
essentially linear. But after 1973, there has been a slight decoupling, possibly triggered by the
succession of oil price shocks, starting in 1973, each of which has triggered a recession. The
latest example of an oil shock (not shown in the graph) was 2007-8 when the price briefly
reached $150/bbl and was followed by the global financial collapse in 2008 from which the
western countries, especially the US, have not yet fully recovered.
In view of the usual assumption that energy is not a factor of production, the high
correlation between primary energy consumption and GDP suggests (to most economists)
that global energy production is simply driven by global demand, which is driven by global
GDP. In other words, it is convenient to assume that there are no supply constraints. For
purposes of forecasting future energy needs, it follows that a GDP growth forecast, together
with a forecast of price and income elasticities, should be sufficient. This is exactly the
methodology employed by the IEA, the OECD, the US IEA and the IMF.
As it happens, the most commonly used production function of capital and labor takes the
form shown below:
Y = A(t) K(t)aL(t)b
where Y is output, K is the stock of capital and L is the stock of labor, while a and b are constants,
where a + b = 1 (to assure constant returns to scale). This form was suggested by Charles Cobb and
Paul Douglas back in 1927. It has the convenient mathematical property that output elasticities
(logarithmic derivatives) of the two factors are just the constants a and b.
A theorem called the Aincome allocation theorem@, also dating from a century ago, states that,
in a simple economy consisting of many small (Aprice taking@) competing firms producing a single
product from rented capital and labor (which are assumed to be freely substitutable), the equilibrium B
or profit maximization B condition requires that total labor requirements must be determined by the
marginal productivity of labor, which is the wage rate. Hence the total payments to labor must be equal
to the wage rate times the quantity of labor employed and the total payments to capital must be
determined by the marginal productivity of capital (the profit rate), times the quantity of capital
employed. It can be shown that, in this ultra-simple case, the output elasticity of each factor must be
equal to its cost share in the GDP (which is equal to the sum total of wages and profits, respectively.)
As it happens the cost shares of capital and labor, as defined above, have been relatively
constant over the years, which seems to fit the requirements of the Cobb-Douglas production function,
In 1956 and 1957, Robert Solow noted that increasing capital per worker but keeping the cost shares
constant did not explain US economic growth from 1909 to 1949 (the years he analyzed). But instead
of introducing a third factor of production he attributed most of the unexplained historical growth to the
residual multiplier A(t) that he characterized as Atechnical progress@. Now it is called Atotal factor
productivity@ or TFP.
An enormous amount of effort has been expended on trying to eliminate the unexplained
residual by introducing Aquality adjustments@ to labor and capital, while continuing to treat labor
productivity as the ratio between total output and labor input. Certainly education and increasing
literacy (and numeracy) would be a quality adjustment for labor, while technical performance
improvements should also be taken into account for capital. Unfortunately none of the proposed
adjustments are accurately quantifiable. Hence the usual approach is to assume a convenient
exponential form for A(t), with a constant annual growth rate, around 2 percent per annum. I repeat:
economic growth is assumed to continue, as in the past, with or without energy.
But even the standard theory cannot escape the implications for energy. The IMF has recently
forecast global economic growth of more than 4.5% p.a. for the years 2011 through 2016 (actually
accelerating from 4.4 % in 2011 to 4.7% in 2016). It assumes constant prices – hence no price effect -and an average income elasticity of 0.685, which means that 1 % increase in global GDP calls forth a
new supply of 0.685 %, whence a global growth rate of 4.5% implies an increase in global oil supply of
about 3% p.a. In terms of cumulative totals, this implies an increased global output of 17 mbd by 2016,
whereas there has been very little increase (3-4 mbd) since 2004 despite much higher prices. Where
will this new oil come from?
A recent post by blogger Stuart Stanisford {Stanisford, 2011 #7088} has pointed out that if the
constant price assumption is relaxed, and prices are allowed to increase just enough to cut consumption
growth from 3% p.a. to 2 % p.a. using the IMFs assumed price elasticity (-0.019) total new supply of
“only” 11 mbd will be needed in 2016. But, that, in turn, implies an annual price increase of 53% for
the next 5 years. This will not happen, of course, because a much smaller increase would stop economic
growth and bring on another recession or depression. If Stanisford (or the IMF) slipped a decimal point
and the price elasticity is -0.19% (much more likely) the annual oil price increase would still have to be
5.3%, and to keep global oil consumption constant (no increase) the annual price increase would (will)
have to be several times higher still – and the economic consequences would be severe.
It is also likely – in fact, certain – that the income and price elasticities will change over time.
(There is no theoretical reason why they should be regarded as constants.) The income elasticity will
probably decrease – by an unknown amount, to be sure – and the price elasticity must increase
considerably as the prices rise and as people (and firms0 learn how to find and use less energyintensive ways of doing things.
But the fundamental problem with the IMF’s economic model (and all the others) is the
assumption that energy is not a factor of production in the first place. If that assumption is modified,
one has a production function of three variables, rather than two. The third factor could be primary
energy E or (my preference) useful work U. Useful work is the product of E times energy (exergy)
efficiency f, viz..
U = fE
However, to eliminate the exogenous multiplier by including a third factor of production that is not
perfectly substitutable for the others, creates a problem. Perfect substitutability of capital or labor for
useful work would allow for the possibility of producing output from capital alone (and no labor or
useful work), or from labor alone with no capital or useful work, or from useful work alone, with no
labor or capital.
Clearly, none of the factors is a perfect substitute for either of the others. In fact, some
substitution is possible at the margin but the extent of substitutability is limited, and those limits can be
expressed as mathematical constraints on the profit maximization (equilibrium) condition. EulerLagrange optimization in the presence of a mathematical constraint on the possible relationships among
the factors introduces ALagrange multipliers@ that are interpreted as Ashadow prices@of the constraints.
If the constraints are not binding, the shadow prices will be zero, but what if substitutability is much
more limited than most economists assume? From this one can argue (as we have in the past) that the
output elasticity of energy (work) is much larger than the cost share.
But if that were true, it follows that energy is really more productive than its price suggests,
whence the optimum (profit-maximizing) consumption of energy (work) in the economy is actually
larger than current consumption. Can this possibly be true? Most economists will say “no”, whence the
traditional cost-share assumption may be OK.
In fact, there is plenty of evidence (a) that firms use too much – not too little – energy, The
evidence is plentiful that firms consistently neglect cost-saving investments in energy conservation,
with very high returns, in favor of investments in marketing, new products or capacity expansion.
Governments and consumers behave in roughly the same way, preferring to spend on current
consumption goods or services rather than investment in future cost savings. (The health-care dispute is
a good example.) What that means is that the profit-maximizing or cost-minimizing optimum energy
consumption level is actually considerably lower than the current level, as a number of studies have
indicated.
Does this mean that energy or work can be neglected as factors of production, as most models
have assumed? If so, continued economic growth can safely be assumed and higher energy prices don’t
really matter much after all. I don’t believe it. But I don’t know how to explain the associated
implication that, if energy is a more important factor of production than current theory says, we should
be using more of it, not less. .
Setting this question aside, we can now postulate specific functional forms for the output
elasticities, with appropriate asymptotic behavior, such that realistic physical constraint requirements,
plus the constant returns to scale condition are satisfied. This was done some years ago by Kuemmel et
al (1986). Without going more deeply into mathematics, one of the simplest functional forms that meets
this requirement, with U as the third factor, is known as the LINEX (Linear-Exponential) function,
which looks like this:
Y(t) = U exp{a(2-b) - a(L-U)/K + ab(L/U)}
Here U refers to useful work and Y, U, K and L are functions of time, while a and b are constants. In
principle, we have time series for U, K and L and the constants a and b have to be determined
econometrically, i.e. by finding the best fit between Y as calculated and actual historical output (GDP).
In practice, K and L are available from official sources, but U is not, and it must be estimated. For the
US this has been done, approximately, for the years 1900-1998 by Ayres et al (2003) and subsequently
updated and extended to several other countries.
Figure 3 shows the results of comparing the best fit with a three-factor Cobb-Douglas
production function, assuming constant output elasticities, vs the best LINEX fit with variable output
elasticities. The LINEX fit is obviously better. Moreover, it does not require an exogenous multiplier
A(t) to explain past growth. However, it must be acknowledged that the fit is not very good after the
1980’s. There are several possible explanations. One explanation, due to Bourdaire is that the US GDP
was artificially inflated during the 1990s, due to a series of unseasonably warm winters, the use of
“hedonic” pricing for computers or higher margins based on cheap imports – attributable to the everincreasing trade deficit with China {Bourdaire, 2003 #7087}. In effect the US was, and still is,
consuming goods that are produced elsewhere with borrowed money.
However, we think the rapid introduction if new information and communications technology
(ICT) may be the missing link. It suggests a modified production function in which capital is split into
“normal” and ICT components. Results are shown below.
During recent decades information, computer and telecommunications (ICT) technologies have vastly
increased in importance. To reflect this shift, we have subdivided capital stock into two components,
‘physical capital’ and ICT capital. Since ICT capital was essentially negligible before 1975 we can also
assume that the impact on GDP was also negligible before 1975, but has since become increasingly
important. Let δ stand for ICT capital, whence K - δ refers to ordinary physical capital. It is plausible
that information technology effectively increases the productivity of human labour, while
correspondingly reducing the productivity of other exergy services. We postulate a modified form of
the LINEX function, as follows:

l

 u l 
y  q0 exp 2  a
  ab  c 
u
l
 k  

(11)
It is evident that the modified form reduces to the original form in the limit as δ approaches
zero. This suggests the possibility of using a functional version of the familiar Taylor
expansion, viz.
y  y (0)  y0    2 y0   

l
u l 
y (0)  q0u exp  f  a
  ab 
u
 k 


u l
c
y   y   a
 
2
 k    l 
 u  l c
y0  y 0  a 2  
k
l

(12)
Giving the 1st order approximation as,

u  l  c

y  y0  1     a 2   
k  l


This production function will be referred to as the ICT adjusted LINEX.
(13)