Download Introduction to Applied Economics: Resource allocation, production

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Participatory economics wikipedia , lookup

Steady-state economy wikipedia , lookup

Production for use wikipedia , lookup

Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup

Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup

Economic democracy wikipedia , lookup

Đổi Mới wikipedia , lookup

Economic calculation problem wikipedia , lookup

Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup

Free market wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
MBA 814
Introduction to Applied Economics: Resource allocation, production,
and human choices
A. Overview: Scarcity and the price system
Economics is the study of allocation of scarce resources in society. Without scarcity there
is nothing to study. Every individual would satiate their ``wants.'' Such an environment may
characterized as a ``Garden of Eden'' economy, in which resources are unlimited (except of course
for apples), and people live forever. For all practical purposes, scarcity always exists. Among the
most important of these resources, our time, is scarce because we live lives of finite length. When
resources are scarce, the problem faced by individuals, firms, and society becomes how do we
allocate those resources among their most ``valued'' uses?
This question beckons another important question: as ``valued'' by whom? By individuals?
By the managers of multinational corporations? By government policy makers? In a
market-oriented economy, these values are determined largely by consumers and workers.
Consumers base their purchases on their assessments of the alternative values of goods or services
in consumption. Workers decide whether to ``supply their labor'' to a firm based on their
assessments of the value of alternative uses of their time. Notice that in both of these instances
there is no explicit dollar amount placed on these values. For example, the value of homes is
almost certainly larger than the price paid by homeowners or more precisely the price that
homeowners could receive if they sold their homes. Similarly, if parents decide not to work, but
instead to stay home and care for their children, we only know that the value to parents of raising
their own children must be at least as large as the wage or salary less the cost of child care that
they would have received from working. These consumption and labor supply decisions result
from individuals' values and ultimately determine the allocation of resources in society. They
determine who works, what is produced, and how the output of society is distributed among its
members.
At its most fundamental level economics is the study of human choices. In a
market-oriented economy, the functioning of the price system reflect these choices. A price is the
value placed on a good or service by those consumers who are just indifferent between buying
that good or service or some other alternative. Even in situation in which a producer ``sets'' or
``fixes'' a price for the product, there exists some consumer who is approximately indifferent
about purchasing the product and buys it, and another who also is just indifferent about buying
the product and does not buy it. If this producer were to reduce its price, additional consumers
would buy the product. But what does the price system have to do with resource allocation?
Because when these additional consumers purchase the producers' product, they are now NOT
buying the products of other producers. This change in consumption changes how resources such
as labor, materials, natural resources, and entrepenerial skills are allocated among producers.
The price system, therefore, signals to economic ``agents'' how their resources (ie. their
time, their natural resources, their capital) are valued by others who have used the marketplace.
If the transmission of information were costless, we would know that the current (market) price
represents the highest value of a particular resource by an alternative user. When the price rises
1
MBA 814
2
above an individual's own value for a product, that individual should sell it.
A striking example of this choice facing individuals has arisen recently in the wine market
for fine Bordeaux wines. In recent years average wine prices have approximately doubled and the
prices of some wines have gone up by even more. Wine connoisseurs are now faced with the
dilemma that $30 bottles of wine that they had purchased as their ``pizza'' wine is sometimes
selling at auction for nearly $100 a bottle. The question is what is the cost of drinking this wine
with their Domino's Pizza or a plate of spaghetti? Is it the $30 that they paid for the wine in the
first place (the historical cost) or is it the $100 that it is currently fetching at auction (the
replacement cost)? Some wine connoisseurs report that they no longer can afford to drink the
wine stored in their own cellars!
Because of the central role that the price system plays in allocating resources in
industrialized economies, this course amounts to a course in ``price theory.'' The objective of this
course is that you understand (i) the important role of a well functioning price system in
allocating resources in a market economy; (ii) how to use the analytical tools developed in this
course to examine broader questions of economic policy; and (iii) how to apply these tools to
problems facing the firm.
B. A Historical Perspective:
The problem of resource allocation is an old problem that has attracted the attention of
philosophers for at least three millennia. Economic and political writings from ancient China
document early interest in the role that production and exchange play in the ``wealth of nations.''
Consider the following excerpts from two different ancient texts.1
When Duke Tai (ca. 1122 - 1078 B.C.E.) arrived in his country [Qi], he improved
government, conformed to the [local] customs, simplified the rites, extended the work of
merchants and artisans throughout the country, and facilitated the making of profit from fish and
salt. Thus, people came to Qi in large numbers and the Qi became a great country.
Author unknown, from the Shi ji 32/3a
The marketplace determines the value of goods. Hence, if goods are kept cheap, there will
be no [exorbitant] profits. If there are no [exorbitant] profits, production will be well organized,
and if it is well organized, expenditures will be properly controlled. Now production materializes
through planning, succeeds through diligent attention, but fails through negligence. Without
planning it will never materialize, without diligent attention it will never succeed. However,
unless there is negligence, it will not fail. Therefore it is said that the marketplace may know order
or disorder, abundance or scarcity [on its own]. There is a proper way to manage [markets and
production].
1
See Guanzi: Political, Economic, and Philosophical Essays from Early China, W. Allyn
Rickett, translator, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 9, 118. (The Guanzi is believed to
have been written or compiled around 250 B.C.E. Italics are added for emphasis).
MBA 814
3
Attributed to Guan Zhong, ca. 645 B.C.E.,
In particular in the second excerpt notice the author's view of how ``value'' is determined.
Economists today would be comfortable with this proposition. However it is important to
recognize that the ancients' understanding of economics differed considerably from our own. This
point can be understood from the origins of the word itself. ``The word 'economics,' Greek in
origin, is compounded from oikos, a household, and the semantically complex root, nem-, here its
sense of `regulate, administer, organize.' '' (A simpler translation of these words might be
``household management.'') For more approximately two millennia the standard work on
economics, Oikonomikos, was written by the Greek philosopher, Xenophon during the 4th
century B.C.E. ``In Xenophon, however, there is not one sentence that expresses an economic
principle or offers any economic analysis, nothing on efficiency of production, ``rational'' choice,
the marketing of crops.''2 By our understanding today, his was a work on ethnics, and not
economics. This emphasis continued into the 18th century and is seen even in the work of
Francis Hutcheson, Adam Smith's teacher, in his book entitled Short Introduction to Moral
Philosophy.
During the 18th century, the subject of economics as we understand it today began to take
form culminating in the publication of the Wealth of Nations in 1776. This important book was
part of a growing body of literature characterized by the French as l'economie politique which
dealt with issues such as money, trade, national income, and economic policy. For more than a
century the term political economy was understood to refer to the ``science of the wealth of
nations.'' The term ``economics'' did not come into common use until after the publication in 1890
of the Principles of Economics, by the British economist, Alfred Marshall.
The important contribution of Smith and others and their intellectual departure from the
work of previous scholars is that they developed a conceptual framework for understanding a
wide range of economic activities such as farming, manufacturing, labor, finance, taxation,
money, and so on. More recently, the ``economic'' activities examined using by this framework
have been expanded to include marriage, addiction, suicide, fertility, the forming of firms,
organizations, associations, or clubs. This framework is what is often referred to today as
microeconomics.
C. The Modern Economy in a Dangerous World:
Given the historical roots of the subject as the science of the wealth of nations, it is
appropriate to begin our examination of price theory or microeconomics looking at the national
economy. A useful fact to take away from this course is that the U.S. economy produces
approximately $8 trillion worth of goods and services each year. This figure known as the ``gross
domestic product'' or ``GDP'' is a measure of the value of all goods and services produced and sold
in the market place each year. To appreciate the relative size of this output, 25 percent of world
output is produced in the United States. As shown by the pie chart, Japan and Germany generate
13 and 8 percent of world output, respectively. Thus, together these three countries generate
2
see M.I. Finley, The Ancient Economy, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1973,
pp, 17 - 19.
MBA 814
4
approximately 45 percent of world output. (By contrast, they constitute less than 10 percent of
the world's population.)3
But why is this $8 trillion figure so useful? One way think about this figure is to recognize
that it approximates the productive capacity of the economy. Consider the graph discussed in
lecture that sometimes is referred to as the ``production possibility frontier.'' Individuals in a
society have choices about how to employ their resources to produce final products. In the
simplest of cases we can think of the economy as producing two types of goods ``guns'' and
``butter.'' At some point if existing technology is being used effectively, decisions must be made
that involve trading off guns and butter. In the graph, we can think of the slope of the line as
representing the relative price of guns and butter: an extra gun costs so many sticks of butter.
In the first graph, this (relative) price is treated as a constant. But it is easy to imagine that
a more realistic characterization of technology is to assume that there are diminishing returns
associated with this tradeoff, so that extra guns ``cost'' an increasing number of sticks of butter.
We can also characterize the impact of technological change on an economy's productive
capacity by a rightward shift in the production possibility frontier. The implication of this shift is
that the economy can have both more guns and more butter. Because technological change allows
individuals to produce and consume more of all goods using the same resources, it is sometimes
referred to as the true ``free lunch'' in economics.
As the United States dramatically demonstrated to the rest of the world during World War
II, an economy can quickly shift along its production possibility frontier. Indeed, one can argue
that the Japanese decision to bomb Pearl Harbor in 1941 was one of the great military
miscalculations of the century. Why? Because the decision appears to ignore the implications of
the industrial capacity of the United States. True enough at the time the U.S. military was small in
size compared to other world powers and destroying the Pacific Fleet would seem likely to deliver
a crippling blow to the United States' ability to fight a war. However, the implications of the
diagram are that such an analysis was misguided because in the long run the bombing of Pearl
Harbor would have little consequence to the outcome of the war. What the Axis Powers needed in
order to achieve victory was to destroy the U.S.'s industrial capacity.
By contrast Winston Churchill appears to have understood completely the consequences
of the U.S.'s entry into the war. He recognized the economic impact that the U.S. would have on
war despite it having a relatively weak military. A story from the invasion of Normandy serves to
illustrate the point. During the initial hours of the invasion a U.S. navel intelligence officer
reported asking a colonel ``how things were going?'' The colonel replied, ``we are screwing up so
badly that you would not believe it, but you know we have so many ships, and so many tanks, and
so many airplanes, that it won't make any difference. The invasion will still be successful anyway.''
The economic impact of the U.S. participation in the war was decisive. Indeed, the outcome
became clear once the U.S. gained air superiority and was in a position to systematically destroy
3
For those who are following the debate on granting ``fast track authority'' to President
Clinton in order to extend NAFTA, approximately 2.5 percent of world output is produced in
Canada, and 5 percent of world output is produced by all of the remaining countries in the
Western Hemisphere. See Latin American View, Citicorp Securities, Inc., Global Research
Emerging Markets, September 1997, Issue 8.
MBA 814
5
not simply the military installations, but the industrial capacity of Germany and Japan.
Saddam Hussian provides a more recent example of a military ``strategist'' who probably
knew but could not comprehend what it meant for an economy to have an $8 trillion GDP. After
he invaded and occupied Kuwait, Hussian asserted that U.S. ground troops would not stand
much of a chance against his battle tested troops who had spent nearly a decade fighting a bloody
war with Iran. As evidence, he asserted that whereas his troops could live off the desert and
endure many hardships, ``soft'' American troops could never get by without their ``bottles of
Evian water.'' Of course Saddam may well have been right, but more importantly what he failed to
appreciate was that an $8 trillion economy can supply a 1/2 million troops with a bottle of Evian
each day and no one will notice! Similarly, an economy this size also can fly 2,000 ``sorties'' per
day over Baghdad without this activity measurably affecting day to day civilian life.
Finally, we can consider the economic lessons of the Cold War. Much has been written
about the consistent resolve of the U.S. and its allies during the decades long struggle with the
former Soviet Union having been an important factor in determining the outcome of the Cold
War. But clearly the most important factor was the substantial and growing difference between
the economic capacity of the U.S. and Western Europe and of the U.S.S.R and its allies. ``Glasnost''
and the fall of the Soviet Union revealed the reason for the Cold War's outcome. As shown by the
graph the industrial capacity of the U.S. economy meant that despite substantial expenditures on
the military, U.S. citizens could still enjoy an affluent lifestyle. The same could not be said of
citizens of the Eastern Block. Indeed as the Cold War dragged on the disparity grew, even during
the 1980s as the U.S. substantially increased its miliary expenditures.
Discussion Questions:
1. Suppose technological change affected only the production of butter. In other words a chemical
engineer designs a new process that yields more sticks of butter with the same resources. By
contrast, guns continued to be produced the same old fashion way. Given this form of unbalanced
technological change, would it still be possible for society to ``consume'' both more guns and more
butter?
2. One of the U.S. Congress's favorite activities is to prevent the closing of domestic military bases
and installations that the U.S. military has determined serve no strategic value. Congressmen (and
Congresswomen) argue that critics of their behavior ignore the beneficial impact that these bases
have on the number of jobs in their communities. Without these jobs, the economy would weaken
because fewer people would be working. Evaluate this argument of U.S. Congressmen.
D. The Role of the Market, the Firm, and the Household
To be sure, the $8 trillion GDP figure understates the true output of the U.S. economy
because it does not include the value of output and services produced and consumed by
households. For example, the value of meals prepared at home, child care by parents, house
cleaning, or home and appliance repair are not included in official statistics unless the household
hires or contracts others to perform these tasks. The implication of this accounting of GDP is that
as two earner couples become more common, GDP necessarily rises because households stop
producing these services on their own, and employ others to perform these tasks for them.
MBA 814
6
A simple way of thinking about the economy is to think of it consisting of two institutions:
firms and households; and two markets: final product and factor markets. It is useful to think of
the household as an enterprise or firm. Households consume final products, but they also supply
the factors used by firms to produce products. The most important factor is labor, but households
also own (either directly or indirectly) all capital, land, and other resources used in production.
GDP measures the value of those final products purchased by households.4
In his book entitled Price Theory, Milton Friedman describes the market sector as the place
in which the use and purchase of final products and of factors of production ``organize the use of
resources'' in a society. He goes on to explain that
(i)n its simplest form, ... an economy consists of a number of individual households, a
collection of Robinson Crusoes, as it were. Each household uses the resources it controls to
produce goods and services that it exchanges for goods and services produced by other
households, on terms that are mutually acceptable to the two parties to the bargain. It is
thereby enabled to satisfy its wants indirectly by producing goods and services for others,
rather than directly by producing goods for its own immediate use. The incentive for
adopting this indirect route is, of course, the increased product made possible by division
of labor and specialization of function. Since the household always has the alternative of
producing directly for itself, it need not enter into any exchange unless it benefits from it.
Hence, no exchange will take place unless both parties do benefit from it. Cooperation is
thereby achieved without coercion.
Specialization of function and division of labor would not go far if the ultimate productive
unit were the household. In an modern society, we have gone much further. We have
introduced enterprises that serve as intermediaries between individuals in their capacities
as suppliers of services and as purchasers of goods. We have introduced money to
facilitate exchange and avoid barter, thereby enabling the acts of purchase and sale to be
separated into different parts.5
E. The price system and the allocation of resources.
How does the market sector allocate resources? What are the dynamics that cause
resources in a market oriented economy to be allocated to their highest ``valued'' user? A dramatic
illustration of how this process works is seen in the aftermath of a natural disaster. The historic
flooding of the Red River in North Dakota during the spring of 1997 demonstrated how quickly
nature can affect both the level and allocation of resources in a community. Goods that one day
4
In reality there are two other important sectors: the government and the nonprofit sectors.
The government plays three roles: (i) it redistributes ``income'' among households; (ii) it produces
or supplies final products (ie. education or electricity) and (iii) it ``consumes'' final products (ie.
provision of national defense, or highways).
5
See Friedman, Milton, Price Theory, Chicago:Adline Publishing Company, 1976, pp. 5 - 6.
MBA 814
7
seemed ``plentiful'' such as drinkable water, the next were suddenly scarce. Did North Dakotan's
demand for drinkable water suddenly increase as a consequence of the flood? A common mistake
is to assert that it did, when it fact it probably declined to the extent that some members of the
community choose to leave the area and ``wait out'' the flood by staying with relatives and friends.
However, how does an economy provide drinkable water to those individuals who decide
to stay behind? There are essentially two approaches: (i) call in the National Guard and provide
every individual with a daily ``ration'' of water; or (ii) do nothing and allow market forces to
operate. But what do market forces have to do with floods? If drinkable water in an area suddenly
becomes scarce and demand for water stays constant what should happen to its price? The higher
price provides incentives to providers of drinkable water to ship water to the flood victims. Of
course, unlike the National Guard, providers of drinkable water are not likely to ship water for
``free.'' The flood victims must pay the higher price for their water.
Both approaches described above result in North Dakotan flood victims having fresh
drinking water. But do these two approaches result in the same outcomes? Experience suggests
that the public actually prefers the non-market approach to addressing the problem of scarcity
following a natural disaster. For example, long time residents of Northern climates know the
likely consequences for retailers who raise the price of their snow shovels following a blizzard.
In principle, such behavior makes sense from the point of view of both the retailer and society,
because it ensures that following a blizzard show shovels are allocated their highest valued users.6
The price system ensures that those persons or businesses who are willing to pay the most to
begin digging out from the snow storm receive the relatively scare resource.
Nevertheless, the public often refers to such pricing behavior in the aftermath of a natural
disaster as ``price gouging.'' Sometimes businesses that are alleged to practice such behavior are
threatened with law suits. Application 8 - 1 on pages 285 - 286 in the text illustrates this point
using the experience of Hurricane Andrew in 1992. But, if ``price gouging'' leads to an
``efficient'' allocation of resources, why does the public often object to it? The reason is that the
outcome - how the snow shovels are allocated in the aftermath of a snowstorm - does not seem
``fair.'' Some would assert that relying on the price system to allocate resources following a
natural disaster is ``crass'' and ``hard hearted.'' Critics of the market system correctly point out
that during these times of exceptional hardship the most vulnerable in society are least likely to
receive ``needed'' resources such as drinkable water and snow shovels. Individuals perceive that
the non-market solution - calling the National Guard - yields a fairer outcome. From a
normative standpoint, the non-market solution may be a ``good'' or the socially ``preferred
''outcome. Economic analysis does not help us understand ``right '' from ``wrong'' or ``good'' and
``evil.'' None the less, some economists might suggest that a more ``efficient'' way allocate
resources following a natural disaster is to allow market forces to operate and to ``subsidizes'' the
poor and needy so they can buy drinkable water or snow shovels.
6
Notice that the nature of the scarcity is different. By contrast to drinking water following a
flood, the ``supply'' of show shovels has remained the same. Instead the ``demand'' for snow
shovels has increased.
MBA 814
8
Discussion Questions:
1. Since 1981 in the United States, labor productivity has grown at historically unprecedented
rates in the manufacturing sector. (By contrast, labor productivity as measured in the services
sector has grown very slowly.) Starting in the 1920s and continuing until the 1980s, U.S. labor
unions have argued that wage increases for workers should be tied to productivity gains in the
industry. In the absence of unionization, would you expect that workers wage gains would be
proportional to gains in labor productivity? What would happen if manufacturing wages began
to rise relative to wages paid in the service sector? How are wages helping to allocated labor
resources? Is the union wage policy sustainable?
2. The United States often is on the front lines advocating ``free trade,'' especially in agricultural
products among other industrialized nations. French farmers, notorious opponents of free trade,
sometimes are signaled out as an example of an impediment to lower world prices for agricultural
products. At the same time, the United States has engaged in some inefficient and ``protectionist''
agricultural policies of its own. A good example, are laws governing the trading and pricing of
water rights in many western U.S. states. In California water is relatively cheap if used for
farming, but is expensive when used by urban residents for personal use.7 Could this outcome
result from market forces? In general what should be the price difference between water used for
farming and water used for residential consumption? Given the existing price differential
between water used by farmers and urban residents, what are the consequences of the resulting
allocation of resources for the prices of agricultural products? For housing prices in Los Angeles?
Why did I refer to these water rights laws as ``protectionist?''
3. Interest in the benefits of ``free trade'' dates back at least to the 18th century and indeed this
issue was one of the central purposes of the Wealth of Nations. More than 150 years ago,
economist David Ricardo rigorously analyzed the economic consequences of the British ``corn
laws.'' These laws amounted to significant import restrictions on agricultural imports into Great
Britain. The crux of Ricardo's analysis was that these laws had lowered national income and had
reduced growth. The question to be resolved was similar to that facing North American policy
makers today with NAFTA. The ``North-South'' question during Ricardo's time was the
industrialized United Kingdom and the relatively land rich Baltic countries. Ricardo successfully
argued that the corn laws distorted the allocation of British land and human resources and as a
consequence had hindered growth. Given the low cost of land in the Baltic countries, too much
British land was used for farming and too many British subjects were farmers.8
Although the economy of Ricardo's time was much different that ours today, the issues
that he addressed in his influential work on free trade are essentially the same as those
7
For a more technical treatment of this example see Application 18-2 in the text, pp. 679 -
681.
8
See Kouparitsas, Michael. ``Economic Gains From Trade Liberalization-NAFTA's Impact,''
Chicago Fed Letter, Chicago:The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 122, October 1997.
MBA 814
9
encountered with NAFTA and other ``free trade'' arrangements. That the debate still rages about
this topic after more than 200 years since the publication of the Wealth of Nations demonstrates
in part how difficult these issues are to understand and the point that not everyone benefits from
free trade.9
The question arises is why do trade agreements generate such heated opposition? Would
the nations of the world be better off with more protection? One way to understand protection is
that it prevents voluntary exchange among individuals who reside in different countries. In
other words, there are two individuals who would both be better off if they could trade. If two
citizens of the same country wanted to engage in a similar transaction most would agree that it
would be inefficient to prevent the exchange. (But see water rights discussion above.)10
If Country A can not successfully negotiate a free trade agreement with Country B, would
it still make sense for it to allow ``unfair'' trade between the countries? Consider the following
definitions:
Fair Trade:
Country A can sell its products to country B without barriers.
Country A can buy products from country B without barriers.
Unfair Trade:
Country A cannot sell its products to country B.
Country A can buy products from country B without barriers.
No Trade:
Country A cannot sell its products to country B.
Country A cannot buy products from country B.
9
A multi-country poll, conducted just prior to the 1997 G-7 conference in Denver, which
was hosted by President Clinton, revealed somewhat ironically that the greatest support for free
trade was among Russian citizens! In most of the G-7 countries substantial numbers if not
majorities opposed freer trade.
10
In the United States, the ``interstate commerce'' clause of the U.S. Constitution prohibits
states from establishing trade barriers. However, as a result of the repeal of prohibition in the
1930s, alcohol is exempt from this clause and states have in fact erected significant barriers to
trade. For example, Michigan has a state-owned monopoly on the wholesale liquor business.
Pennsylvania has a state-owned monopoly on the retail liquor business. (If you can imagine such
a thing wine made in Pennsylvania is exempt!) This year the Florida state legislator enacted a law
(allegedly to protect minors) making it a felony for individuals to receive liquor that they have
had shipped across state lines.
MBA 814
10
How would you rank each of these regimes? Why?
4. During the late 1980s, the U.S. and Canada successfully negotiated a free-trade agreement.
President Bush intended that the agreement would become a model that would subsequently
become the basis for NAFTA. An interesting obstacle arose during the negotiations when the U.S.
objected because the Canadians wanted to continue to subsidize their beer industry. The U.S.
argued that it would not be ``fair'' for Canadian producers to be subsidized after tariffs were
eliminated under the agreement. Disputes over a ``level playing field'' often arise in trade
negotiations. But the question is ``fair'' to who?
F. Tools of the trade: Supply and demand
In the previous section, we developed the tools of economic analysis without using any
explicit quantitative framework or apparatus. Now we turn to putting our discussion of these
economic concepts into the context of the familiar supply and demand framework. One of the
best places to start any analysis of prices is with agricultural markets. One reason for this is that
they often conform most closely to an economy consisting of many producers (suppliers) and
consumers (demanders). Under these conditions, the framework that we develop in this course
is the easiest to use and makes the strongest predictions.
Consider the graph showing the relationship between the quarterly demand for turkeys
and their price. Since scientific studies revealed the health benefits of eating turkey as opposed to
red meat, turkey is now consumed year round in the United States. However, the greatest demand
is during the fourth quarter of the year when American families often eat turkey during the
Thanksgiving and Christmas holidays. What appears to be the relationship between the quantity
consumed and the price of turkey? Once one understands that the consumption patterns differ
during the year, it is easy to see that there are two demand curves for turkey: (i) the fourth
quarter demand curve is ``shifted'' out to the right and is steeper; and (ii) the rest of the year
demand curve which is flatter. The data plotted in the graph appear to tell us something that
makes a lot of sense: the demand for turkey is greatest in the fourth quarter and consumers
exhibit less sensitivity to price during that period.11
The demand curve for turkey represents the amount of turkey that consumers are willing
to purchase at any given price. Therefore, the area under the demand curve would be the total
revenue that turkey producers would receive if they could price discriminate and charge each
consumer the maximum price he/she would be willing to pay for a ``unit'' of turkey. 12 If
consumers value turkey more, then the demand curve shifts to the right. Notice that this shift
implies that at any given quantity of turkey, the value placed on it by consumers has increased.
11
Thinking back to your time with Professor Rubin, how would you use your knowledge of
regression analysis to estimate the relationship between quantity and price?
12
This statement is approximately true if the good involved constitues a small portion of a
consumers' expenditures. More generally, this amount overstates the actual amount that
consumers are willing to pay for a good. For a technical treatment of this question see the
discussion in the text on pages 110 - 119, 134 - 136.
MBA 814
11
The ``slope'' of the demand curve tells us how sensitive consumers are to changes in price. A steep
demand curve means consumers behave as if price is NOT an important determinant of their
consumption decisions. By contrast, a flat demand curve, means consumers behave as if price is a
very important determinate of their consumption decisions. In this case, a modest rise in the
price of turkey would lead consumers to stopping purchasing turkey and instead purchase a
``substitute'' such as chicken.
As we will discuss in the next lecture, the demand curve represents the values that
consumers place on a good or service. By contrast, the supply curve represents the costs to
producers of producing a product. These costs reflect both the market prices for different factors
of production, and also the available technology for combining these factors and producing a
final product. Lets consider two supply curves: (i) the first represents a firm that buys factors in
competitive markets and uses a technology that exhibits constant returns to scale; and (ii) the
second supply curve represents either a firm buying factors in noncompetitive markets and/or
uses a technology that exhibits decreasing returns to scale. The first supply curve is flat: it says
that firms can produce an unlimited amount of turkey at a constant (marginal) cost. The second
supply curve is increasing: it says that firms can produce more turkey but only at a rising cost per
unit. Lower factor prices or technological change shifts the first supply curve down and the
second curve to the right.
The prevailing competitive price is characterized by the intersection of the demand and
supply curve. At this point, the value placed on the turkey by the ``marginal'' consumer exactly
equals the cost of production. If a rare disease were to ``hit'' turkey farms, the cost of supplying
turkey would rise. (The first supply curve shifts up; the second shifts back to the left.) As a
consequence, the price rises: turkey producers are not willing to produce turkeys at the low
pre-disease price, but some consumers continue to buy turkeys at higher prices. Notice that
consumers do not value turkey any more as a result of the ``supply shock'' on the turkey farm. But
the price has risen. The higher price tells us that the ``marginal'' turkey consumer values turkey
more than previously.
This framework helps us to understand questions of economic value that often puzzle
individuals without any economics training. Consider the following three questions:
(i) Everyone knows that water is essential to life and diamonds are frivolous. But why is
the price of water low and the price of diamonds high? Does this outcome mean that
something is wrong with the free market?
(ii) Everyone knows that teachers and police perform essential work, yet they are relatively
low paid. By contrast, Michael Jordan is an entertainer engaged in a frivolous or
non-essential activity and yet makes $36 million per year. Does this outcome mean that
something is wrong with the free market?
(iii) In April 1992, child care workers in Seattle, Washington went on strike for one day
protesting their low wages and poor benefits. They noted that while their hourly wages
ranged between $5 and $6 per hour, the wages of zookeepers in the Seattle zoo averaged
$12 per hour. Because care givers of children were being paid less than 1/2 the pay
received by care givers of monkeys and tigers, they argued that the ``free market'' was not
MBA 814
12
functioning in the child care industry. Does this outcome mean that something is wrong
with the free market?
In each case comment on the argument that the ``market does not work.'' These three questions
all ask the same thing. What do they have in common?
G. Economic v. technical efficiency
One confusing aspect about economics is that it uses an alternative definition of efficiency
than the one commonly used by the general public. 13 To most people, efficiency refers to
technical efficiency: how much output a person or firm can generate from a fixed set of
resources. An alternative definition of efficiency is based on the answer to the question are these
resources allocated to their highest valued user? If yes, then the outcome is efficient.
To understand this distinction more clearly consider our discussion above of water rights
laws. We could research the use of water by California farmers and determine that they make
efficient use of their water. However, from an economic standpoint, unless they sell their water
to urban users, their use of water is inefficient. Laws and regulatory practice prevent water from
moving to its most valued user! Because urban consumers are willing to pay more for water ``on
the margin'' it would be socially more efficient for them to consume more water. Such an
allocation means that it would be more efficient for Southern Californian homeowners to pay less
to fill their swimming pools or water their lawns and for everyone else to pay more for
agricultural products!
Now consider an example that contrasts the labor intensity of hotel or commercial
construction in the United States compared with Mexico. In the United States, building
contractors construct multi-storied hotels with relatively little labor. Instead, they save on labor
costs by employing modern capital equipment. By contrast, their counterparts in Mexico use
relatively less capital and make heavy use of labor. Labor productivity is much higher in U.S.
construction firms. But are the U.S. firms more efficient? The answer is probably not. The
difference in labor intensity or the capital-labor ratio used in U.S. compared with Mexican
construction results from the differences in relative wages. U.S. workers are more expensive
because they have higher valued alternatives. As a result, it makes economic sense to employ
building (ie. production) technology that relies heavily on capital. The point is that even if a
Mexican construction firm were given the capital equipment, it would still be more ``efficient''
(and profit maximizing!) for it to continue to use the labor intensive mode of production and rent
the capital equipment to a construction firm in the United States!
The idea underlying the notion of economic efficiency is that all resources, whether they
be labor, capital, land, mineral resources, etc., have an alternative use. Thus, the real cost of
employing these resources to produce one good or service equals the value of the good or service
that would have been produced had these resources gone to that use. If the price system functions
well, this cost should equal the prevailing price for these resources. So if clerical workers in a
community receive $12.00 per hour, this wage implies that the alternative use of their time is
worth $12.00 per hour. In other words, if a clerical worker quit or was laid off from his/her job,
13
To make matters worse, statisticians have another important definition of efficiency.
MBA 814
13
he or she would expect to find another job paying approximately $12.00 per hour.
_________________________________________________________________________
Footnote
See Guanzi: Political, Economic, and Philosophical Essays from Early China, W. Allyn Rickett,
translator, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 9, 118. (The Guanzi is believed to have
been written or compiled around 250 B.C.E. Italics are added for emphasis).
2
see M.I. Finley, The Ancient Economy, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1973,
pp, 17 - 19.
3
For those who are following the debate on granting ``fast track authority'' to President
Clinton in order to extend NAFTA, approximately 2.5 percent of world output is produced in
Canada, and 5 percent of world output is produced by all of the remaining countries in the
Western Hemisphere. See Latin American View, Citicorp Securities, Inc., Global Research
Emerging Markets, September 1997, Issue 8.
4
In reality there are two other important sectors: the government and the nonprofit sectors.
The government plays three roles: (i) it redistributes ``income'' among households; (ii) it produces
or supplies final products (ie. education or electricity) and (iii) it ``consumes'' final products (ie.
provision of national defense, or highways).
5
See Friedman, Milton, Price Theory, Chicago:Adline Publishing Company, 1976, pp. 5 - 6.
6
Notice that the nature of the scarcity is different. By contrast to drinking water following a
flood, the ``supply'' of show shovels has remained the same. Instead the ``demand'' for snow
shovels has increased.
7
For a more technical treatment of this example see Application 18-2 in the text, pp. 679 -
681.
8
See Kouparitsas, Michael. ``Economic Gains From Trade Liberalization-NAFTA's Impact,''
Chicago Fed Letter, Chicago:The Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 122, October 1997.
9
A multi-country poll, conducted just prior to the 1997 G-7 conference in Denver, which
was hosted by President Clinton, revealed somewhat ironically that the greatest support for free
trade was among Russian citizens! In most of the G-7 countries substantial numbers if not
majorities opposed freer trade.
10
In the United States, the ``interstate commerce'' clause of the U.S. Constitution prohibits
states from establishing trade barriers. However, as a result of the repeal of prohibition in the
1930s, alcohol is exempt from this clause and states have in fact erected significant barriers to
trade. For example, Michigan has a state-owned monopoly on the wholesale liquor business.
Pennsylvania has a state-owned monopoly on the retail liquor business. (If you can imagine such
a thing wine made in Pennsylvania is exempt!) This year the Florida state legislator enacted a law
MBA 814
14
(allegedly to protect minors) making it a felony for individuals to receive liquor that they have
had shipped across state lines.
11
Thinking back to your time with Professor Rubin, how would you use your knowledge of
regression analysis to estimate the relationship between quantity and price?
12
This statement is approximately true if the good involved constitues a small portion of a
consumers' expenditures. More generally, this amount overstates the actual amount that
consumers are willing to pay for a good. For a technical treatment of this question see the
discussion in the text on pages 110 - 119, 134 - 136.
13
To make matters worse, statisticians have another important definition of efficiency.