Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Modelling future urban and rural water requirements in a CGE framework Glyn Wittwer1 Centre of Policy Studies Monash University Keywords: structural change, technological growth, environment, water allocation, hydrology Abstract: Water is increasingly being treated as a tradable commodity. This paper describes our efforts to include water accounts in a multi-regional CGE model. In order to understand the conditions under which water trade might occur, we need to add a number of features to the model and scenarios. These might concern structural change in the economy, differences in yield functions between different crop types, dynamics and hydrology. Each of these features requires substantial theoretical and database additions. As a first step, we consider the first of these, structural change, by projecting the model forwards to the point in the future at which Australia has 25 million people. We use this application as a platform for discussing further possible changes to the model. 1 The author is grateful to Ejaz Qureshi for helpful comments. 1 1. Water trading Water allocation has become an increasingly important issue in rural areas as irrigation regions are being opened up to water trading. The aim of trading is to allocate water to optimise its use in the economy. Improvements in allocation have become essential due to a significant expansion in irrigation areas. Policy makers are seeking to divert water to the environment to improve both the health of wetlands and sustainability of irrigation. The links between environmental degradation and consequent losses in productivity are well documented (for example, Hajkowicz and Young, 2002). The introduction of water trading may lead to another possibility. The price paid per kilolitre by irrigators is much lower than that paid by most other users, and we anticipate that the populations of major urban centres will continue to grow over the next few decades. Therefore, the potential exists for urban users to purchase water from rural regions. This sort of scenario has a potentially heated political dimension. Regions heavily reliant on irrigation agriculture at present may feel either that future growth and prosperity will come under threat, or that declines in some rural towns may be even more marked than they are at present. Irrigators may have invested in what, in the short- to medium-term, appears to be sunk capital. Any attempt to divert their water entitlements to other regions might be perceived as a potential blow to their profitability. Over time, although larger regional towns have grown, their populations may have aged more rapidly than the national population. Some smaller towns have shrunk, while health, education and banking services have diminished. Irrigation water supply authorities and private irrigation districts are concerned that water trading will result in reduced economies of scale and thereby place companies and shareholders at risk. Water reforms may have proceeded slower than otherwise as a consequence of fears about the future of local regions. As part of the process of policy formulation, it is helpful to have at our disposal a model that helps predict the economic impacts of water movements between regions. The objective of this paper is to model the impacts of water trading on the national and regional economies of Australia, taking account of estimated structural changes in the next few decades. We are using a multi-regional CGE model, TERM (The Enormous Regional Model), which includes water accounts linked to each economic activity. Our approach allows us to consider a number of elements of structural change over time, each of which potentially may impact on the demand for water. That is, relatively rapid urban population growth acting alone may lead to an increase in the urban share of a fixed water allocation if we allow trading. As we shall see, other elements of structural change work in the opposite direction, increasing the share of water used by irrigators in the economy. 2. Features of TERM. TERM is a multi-regional model of the Australian economy, based on a master database including 167 sectors and 58 regions. Versions of TERM have also been devised for other nations, including Brazil, Japan and Korea, with a version for China under construction (see http://www.monash.edu.au/policy/term.htm). We are indebted to Mark Horridge, of the Centre of Policy Studies, who created TERM. He introduced a number of innovations among some old ideas to the model. 2 The common proportions assumption One old idea, the common proportions assumption, allows TERM to solve more rapidly than some previous CGE models of the “bottoms-up” type, and indeed was introduced to the multicountry GTAP model at an early stage (Hertel, 1997). “Bottoms-up” models treat each region of the model as a separate economy, including their own input-output-based data and behavioural equations. Inter-regional trade matrices link each region to others within the model and to the rest of the world. Such models contrast with the “tops-down” approach, in a which a single national database and national equations are represented in detail, while regions are represented as mainly exogenous shares of national activity. While “tops-down” models provide limited representation of regions, they are much smaller than “bottoms-up” models containing a similar number of sectors. The advantage of the TERM approach is that more regions can be represented in a “bottoms-up” manner than previously has been possible. This is particularly helpful in the context of the present study, in which we wish to model both irrigation regions and urban centres in different states. The USE matrix in the TERM database includes details of the sales of all commodities to industries (i.e., intermediate sales) plus final users (i.e,. households, investment, exports, government spending). The only information it includes on sourcing is domestic v. import origin. It includes information on the destination of the sale, but not the regional origin. A separate matrix, the TRADE matrix, provides details of regional origin and the regional destination, but not the user of each commodity. In order to match the USE matrix, summed across all users, to the TRADE matrix plus the TRADMAR matrix (containing details of trade plus transport markups), summed across origins, the common proportions assumption is used. That is, all users of a particular commodity in a particular region source that commodity from regional origins in common proportions. This assumption is commonly used in SAM-based tables. Consider a case in which we have 40 sectors, 18 regions and 2 margins in the database. The USE matrix (commodity x dom/imp source x user x regional destination) will have dimensions of 40 x 2 x (40+4) x 18. The TRADE matrix (commodity x dom/imp source x regional origin x regional destination) will have dimensions of 40 x 2 x 18 x 18. The TRADMAR matrix, in the case of two margins, will be twice as large as the TRADE matrix. A further matrix describing the supply of margins, SUPPMAR (margin x regional origin x regional destination x regional margin supplier), has dimensions 2 x 18 x 18 x 18. This representation of the database results in considerable compression as the number of regions or margins increases, relative to providing origin and destination information in the same matrix. Contrast this with the data matrices in MMRF, contain both the origin and destination. This greatly increases the size of the database, once a given ingaggregation contains more than a couple of regions, as can be seen in table 1 in a comparison of the number of database cells for a given dimension of each model. As a consequence, TERM solves much more rapidly than a version of MMRF covering the same number of sectors and regions. An enhancement in TERM is that the supplier of margins need not be located in the same region as the destination (as in MMRF), or either the origin or destination (as in FEDERAL, Madden 1992). That is, a transport company located in the Wimmera statistical division could transport goods between the Mallee and Western Districts of Victoria. 3 Table 1. Comparing core database sizes in MMRF and TERM COM IND MAR REG MMRF database cells TERM MMRF database database cells Mb TERM database Mb Ratio MMRF/TERM 48 38 48 38 2 2 20 45 4318080 13445730 420320 905220 17.27 53.78 1.68 3.62 10.27 14.85 20 30 140 144 20 30 140 144 2 2 2 5 2 2 2 2 13760 29040 566720 982656 6448 13268 246688 260648 0.06 0.12 2.27 3.93 0.03 0.05 0.99 1.04 2.13 2.19 2.30 3.77 20 30 140 144 20 30 140 144 2 2 2 5 8 8 8 8 148160 313440 6144320 11098368 31648 61808 1027168 1084160 0.59 1.25 24.58 44.39 0.13 0.25 4.11 4.34 4.68 5.07 5.98 10.24 20 30 140 144 20 30 140 144 2 2 2 5 30 30 30 30 1836000 3888000 76356000 140175360 199200 351900 4407600 4637160 7.34 15.55 305.42 560.70 0.80 1.41 17.63 18.55 9.22 11.05 17.32 30.23 The TRADE matrix and the Horridge procedure We have reasonable information on the commodity demands and supplies in each region of Australia, based on industry employment data, regional mining data, agricultural data (from ABS AgStats) and household expenditure surveys. For Australia, hardly any detailed data on inter-regional state trade are available. Horridge used the gravity formula (trade volumes follow an inverse power of distance) to construct trade matrices consistent with pre-determined row and column totals. In defence of this procedure, note that: • Wherever production (or, more rarely, consumption) of a particular commodity is concentrated in one or a few regions, the gravity hypothesis is called upon to do very little work. Because the master database sectoral classification was so detailed, this situation occurred frequently. • Outside of the state capitals, most Australian regions are rural, importing services and manufactured goods from the capital cities, and exporting primary products through a nearby port. For a given rural region, one big city is nearly always much closer than any others, and the port of exit for primary products is also well defined. These facts of Australian geography again reduce the weight borne by the gravity hypothesis. For a particular commodity the traditional gravity formula may be written: r≠d V(r,d) = λ(r).μ(d).V(r,*).V(*,d) /D(r,d)2 where V(r,d) = value of flow from r to d (corresponding to matrix TRADE in Fig. 1) V(r,*) = production in r (known) 4 V(*,d) = demand in d (known) D(r,d) = distance from r to d The λ(r) and μ(d) are constants chosen to satisfy: ΣrV(r,d)= V(*,d) and ΣdV(r,d)= V(r,*). For TERM, the formula above gave rather implausible results, especially for service commodities. Instead Horridge set: V(r,d)/V(*,d) ∝ V(r,*)/D(r,d)k r≠d where K is a commodity-specific parameter valued between 0.5 and 2, with higher values for commodities not readily tradable. Diagonal cells of the trade matrices were set according to: V(d,d)/V(d,*) = locally-supplied demand in d as share of local production = MIN{ V(d,*)/V(*,d),1} x F where F is a commodity-specific parameter valued between 0.5 and 1, with a value close to 1 if the commodity is not readily tradable. Horridge then scaled the initial estimates of V(r,d) (using a RAS procedure) so that: ΣrV(r,d)= V(*,d) and ΣdV(r,d)= V(r,*). Transport costs as a share of trade flows were set to increase with distance: T(r,d)/V(r,d) ∝ D(r,d) where T(r,d) corresponds to the matrix TRADMAR in Fig. 1. Again, the constant of proportionality is chosen to satisfy constraints derived from the initial national IO table. All these estimates are made with the fully-disaggregated database. In many cases, zero trade flows can be known a priori. For example, ABS data indicate that rice is grown in only four of the 58 statistical divisions. At a maximum disaggregation, the load born by gravity assumptions is minimized. The common proportions assumptions need not prevent us from including additional information in cases in which it is available. The key to including such information in the master database is to prepare it at a sufficient level of disaggregation for such detail to be included. 3. Variants of TERM and previous applications The variable aggregation facility of TERM means that the number of sectors and regions are tailored to the focus of a particular study. Variants of TERM have been created in response to demand in various applications. Different versions include: • Basic comparative static version; • Water accounts in comparative static model; • Recursive dynamics; and, in the present application, • Water accounts with smooth growth assumption dynamics. 5 The drought study The first study undertaken using TERM was of the regional economic impacts of the 2002-03 drought. Various Canberra-based agencies predicted that the drought would shave little more than 0.75% off drought at the time. On the other hand, Horridge et al. (2003) predicted a result (GDP = -1.6%) that accorded closely with the gap between pre-drought forecasts of GDP growth and the eventual GDP result for the year. In addition, this study predicted the impact at the state level with reasonable accuracy. In this study, estimation formulae were used to compute productivity losses due to the drought for each agricultural industry in each region. The formulae related the productivity losses to rainfall deficits in individual regions using data from the Bureau of Meteorology. Separate formulae were developed for different types of crops and for livestock. For example, for winter grains grown in southern Australia, Horridge et al. (2003) assumed that the productivity loss for the crop in a particular region was a progressively increasing function of the 3-month rainfall deficit, and was also affected to a lesser extent by the 6-month deficit: as the severity of the 3-month rainfall deficit increased, productivity losses were estimated to become increasingly greater at the margin. This approach is of relevance to water-related studies, as a further step in the use of water accounts in TERM will include the addition of response functions linking crop yields to water application. The addition of water accounts The detail in water accounts published by ABS (2004) is gradually improving. These accounts include details of users (industries plus households) in each state. One advance over the first release of the water accounts in 2000 was to include dairy cattle production as a separate entity. But we are hoping two main deficiencies can be redressed in future database preparation. One is that a relatively large sector, crops & livestock, includes a combination of broadacre and irrigation activities. The other is that water data by crop type at the statistical division level are not readily available. This matters less for rice and cotton in New South Wales than for cropping in Victoria, as rice and cotton are confined to one or two statistical divisions. In our first effort, we used ABS AgStats data on irrigation area by statistical division to supplement regional estimates of water usage. This is quite an unreliable method as the application of water per unit area may vary widely. Otherwise, we have assumed that the water intensity of a given activity in each state is the same across all regions in that state. In the absence of more detailed data, this is an assumption we will alter in preparing future databases, at least in Victoria: the Mallee region has a warmer climate and higher rates of evaporation than other regions (see Bureau of Meteorology, 2005). Therefore, we may have underestimated water usage in the Mallee. Consequently, we may overestimate the amount of water purchased by the Mallee in various hypothetical water trading scenarios in which water moves to optimise allocation as we ascribe shocks to the CGE model. In turn, we may underestimate the quantity of water purchased by other users. Early efforts at modelling with the comparative static version of TERM with water accounts typically entailed cutting back regional water entitlements (Wittwer 2003; Peterson et al., 2005). While this demonstrated that there are small welfare gains to be realised by opening water up to trade between regions, the finding that there was little impact on output in regions with net sales of water simply reflected that these were essentially small-change simulations. 6 Nevertheless, these first steps in running a CGE model with water accounts help point out various limitations with the present CGE approach. In particular, we noted that the CGE approach does not capture the volume of water trading that may occur. This was particularly so during the 2002-03 drought. Our out-of-model hypothesis is that most water trading was from growers of annual crops, who found it more profitable to sell water at high prices than to produce their usual crops in adverse seasonal conditions. Perennial crop growers, on the other hand, are concerned that their plantations and vineyards (which entail considerable investment and many years of potential income-earning) will be permanently damaged if they do not receive sufficient water in drought years. Therefore, they are likely to purchase a minimum amount of water with relatively inelastic demand. To capture the driver of water trades from annual crop growers to perennial crop growers, we would need to include crop response functions and recognise the minimum annual water requirements of perennials -- as we plan to do so in future research. Recursive dynamics Wittwer et al. (2005) detail an application of a dynamic version of TERM to a hypothetical weeds eradication program. There are many reasons why a move towards dynamic modelling is desirable for water. For example, in the drought study (Horridge et al., 2005) one of the difficult-to-measure impacts was that of destocking. Accelerated sales to abattoirs in response to drought are a form of disinvestment: that is, they may inflate output statistics in one year, but reduce the income-earning capacity of a farm in following years. A dynamic model contains both stocks and flows, and impacts such as destocking or plantation removal can be ascribed as exogenous reductions in capital stocks. Similarly, rainfall patterns over a number of years affect the stock of water available for economic and non-economic uses. Dynamics would be a desirable part of adding hydrological detail to a CGE model. Smooth-growth assumption dynamics In developing dynamic CGE models, researchers at the Centre of Policy Studies have focused on the impact of structural change on the economy over time. For example, technological change makes a large contribution to growth or decline in many sectors (Dixon and Rimmer, 2002, chapter 2). In addition, while agriculture’s share of GDP has shrunk steadily over the past 50 years, manufacturing’s share has halved over the past 30 years (ABS, 2005; Maddock and McLean, 1987). When estimating the future water demands of different industries, we need to consider structural change that may occur. Even in a model without recursive dynamics, we are able to ascribe shocks to the model to take account of growth in various macroeconomic levels. We can also ascribe productivity shocks and water-saving technological shocks where appropriate. This latter effect is among a number that will impact on relative water scarcity. Missing from this approach, as used in the projections detailed in sections 4 and 5, are year-by-year paths of adjustment in the labour market, and various stocks and flows including linkages between investment, depreciation and capital stocks. 7 One obvious deficiency of the smooth-growth assumption is that it cannot account for extraordinary destocking that may occur in response to a drought. In such circumstances, the time path of rainfall will result in outputs and investment that differ markedly from assuming “typical year” behaviour. 4. Estimating water allocation for an Australian population of 25 million Figure 1: Regions of Projecting 25 million study Figure 1 shows the regions in the study detailed in CSIRO (2006, forthcoming). As is usual in applications of TERM, both the regions and sectors have been aggregated from the master database to the focus of this study. In order to project the TERM database ahead 31 years from 2001 (i.e., the median projection of ABS is that Australia’s population will reach 25 million in 2032), we need to make a series of assumptions concerning how the economy will change. We make explicit these assumptions, and present our results in decomposition form, so that we can observe the contribution made to the water usage by each group of assumptions. 8 The shocks have been assigned to the following groups: (1) demand growth; (2) non-agricultural supply growth and consumer taste swings; (3) technological change (i.e., changes in primary factor requirements) in agriculture; (4) reduced water availability; (5) water-efficiency gains in agriculture, plus reduced pipeline leakage; and (6) changes in household requirements for water. Before examining the contribution of each group of shocks to projected changes in water usage, we will elaborate a little on groups (1), (2) and (3). Group (1) contains shocks to depict changes in the following: • • • • State employment and population; National consumption function shift to fit consumption target; Non-water household demand taste shifts; and Export demand shifts. Table 2. Regional macroeconomic outcomes, 2032 relative to 2001 (% change) SydneyNSW MrmbidgeeNSW MurrayNSW WestNSW RoNSW MelbourneVIC MalleeVIC RestIrigVIC RoVIC BrisMoretQLD BurnDarlQLD RoQLD AdelaideSA RoSA PerthWA RoWA TasNT ACT Aggregate consumption 36.2 34.2 33.8 42.9 34.9 38.2 32.4 34.6 61.4 61.1 65.9 14.1 10.3 16.1 42.2 61.3 34.4 12.4 Real GDP 36.3 34.4 33.9 43.0 35.0 38.3 32.5 34.7 61.6 61.2 66.0 14.2 10.4 16.2 42.3 61.5 34.5 12.5 Aggregate Employment 12.9 17.8 19.8 26.3 16.3 14.3 13.9 16.2 43.0 40.5 46.9 -4.9 -6.9 -4.2 24.1 32.1 19.5 -3.3 Population 20.2 25.5 27.6 35.6 24.2 22.3 21.5 23.9 53.6 51.5 54.2 5.2 3.8 6.6 34.9 43.3 18.6 7.7 Table 2 shows the changes imposed on macroeconomic variables in each region. Three of the columns, namely aggregate consumption, aggregate employment and population, are responsible for the effects shown under heading (1). Since we are interested in comparing national aggregate consumption (our measure of welfare) and regional employment in different scenarios, we want neither aggregate consumption nor employment to be exogenous. To allow various macroeconomic variables to be endogenous in different scenarios, we use closure reversals to position supply and demand curves. For example, the aggregate 9 consumption forecast implies a certain consumption function shift. In the scenarios, a shock is given to this shifter rather than aggregate household consumption. We can then compare macroeconomic household consumption to forecast for each scenario. Similarly, we accommodate our real GDP target with an all-industry technological shift (the effect of which appears under heading (2)). This technological shift becomes the shock in each scenario, so that again, we can compare our real GDP in each scenario to forecast, by ensuring that the demand and supply curves are the same in each scenario as in the base projection. In the case of the labour market, we allow real wages to differ between regions in order to meet regional labour force data projections. In effect, we are not allowing any regional labour market theory to operate (at least not in the base scenario). In addition to a macroeconomic technological shock, heading (2) (i.e., non-agricultural supply growth) also includes projected changes in industry-level technological changes outside of agriculture. Under heading (3), we get the corresponding technological changes for agriculture. While the effects under (1) may be understood reasonably well outside the economics profession, those under heading (2) and (3) are not so. Headings (1), (2) and (3) have a common impact: each increases demand for water. But the demand increases apply to different groups of users and these competing demands may confound our expectations concerning which users will be net buyers of water, as is evident from table 3. (1) Demand growth General economic growth is likely to increase the share of water demanded by non-agricultural users at the expense of agriculture. As per capita income grows, households spend more on relatively income-elastic services sectors than on food. Engel’s law applies. Population growth favours relatively non-traded sectors rather than relatively traded sectors, including agriculture. In the initial year of the database (2001), value-added activity in crops & livestock is $6.3 billion, in dairy cattle $0.7 billion, cotton $0.8 billion and rice $140 million. The crops & livestock sector therefore captures most agricultural activity, with the other three sectors represented separately due to their high water-intensities in production. Since the total water allocated in the 1st column of table 3 sums to zero, we can interpret movements as changes in shares of national water usage (this is the case for all columns other than the 4th, in which the total is the reduction in assumed water allocation). This explains why households, despite growth in aggregate consumption, suffer a small loss in share due to demand growth. Crops and livestock, dairy cattle, and various manufacturing, mining and service sectors increase their demand for water slightly more rapidly than households. The demand growth shown is slightly positive for dairy cattle both in terms of share of water usage (+43 GL, table 3, 1st column) and output (9.8%, table 4, 1st column) because a relatively high proportion of sales of dairy products is to domestic consumers, whose demand grows over time with income and population. Crops & livestock is relatively export oriented: the 1st column in tables 3 and 4 captures, among other demands, export price shifts, which tend to be negative. However, overall demand growth is sufficient for the share of water usage (99 GL) 10 and output (+8.2%) to be positive. Cotton and rice both suffer in terms of share of water usage (-433 GL and -196 GL respectively, table 3, 1st column) and output (-11.9% and -11.2% respectively, table 4, 2nd column). (2) Non-agricultural supply growth and consumer taste swings The impacts of changes in the supply side are shown in columns (2) and (3) of tables 3 and 4. As described in Dixon and Rimmer (2002, chapter 2), much structural change in an economy over time concerns productivity changes at the industry level and consumer taste changes at the commodity level. This heading captures such changes with two exceptions: it excludes agricultural productivity growth and water-saving technological change, as these appear under separate headings. Estimates of the supply shifts (technological changes) and demand shifts (taste changes) have been updated using Giesecke (2004). Households increase usage in the 2nd column rises (+69 GL), with income growth arising from productivity growth raising demand via the impact of rising income on household consumption. Primary-factor productivity increases in industries have the effect of raising the shadow price of water. Hence water becomes more valuable through the non-water productivity effect captured in the 2nd column of tables 3 and 4, so that non-agricultural industries (including downstream processors of agricultural products) increase their share of water usage at the expense of other water users. In the case of cotton and rice, productivity growth in downstream sectors has a weakly positive impact on their water shares (+14 GL for cotton, +30 GL for rice, table 3, 2nd column). (3) Agricultural technological change As already mentioned, despite agriculture contributing a shrinking proportion of GDP, agricultural production has grown relatively rapidly over time, with much of the growth explainable by productivity growth. Agricultural technological change, as with non-agricultural technological change, raises the shadow price of water (3rd column, table 1.3). The magnitudes are large enough to be quite critical in project ting future rural-urban water needs. This productivity growth favours relatively less water-intensive users at the expense of more waterintensive users. This occurs to the extent that the impact of productivity growth on some irrigation sectors is negative (-32.7% for cotton and -23.5% for rice, table 4, 2nd column), as primary factors plus water are diverted to crops & livestock. An increase in the shadow price of water draws water away from households (-91 GL). “Other” industries use more water, and increase output through this effect. Other industries include downstream processing industries that benefit from lower input costs arising from increased productivity in agriculture. In this base scenario in which we do not allow water trades between regions, the shadow price of water rises by $0.52/litre in the Murrumbidgee region, and $0.51/kl in the Murray region of NSW (table 1.3, 3rd column). These two regions account for most rice grown in Australia. This indicates that water will move to other activities, even on the same farm, in response to productivity growth in agriculture, as water becomes more valuable in less water-intensive activities with such growth. 11 (4) Reduced water availability We assume a 15% drop in water supply by 2032 relative to 2001 in all regions outside Western Australia, Tasmania and Northern Territory. The 4th column shows that reduced water availability through climate change or increased allocations to the environment is strongly negative for agriculture and negative for all other users. (5) Agricultural water-efficiency gains and leakage reductions The 5th column of tables 3 and 4 captures the effects of two forms of water savings: reduced requirements in agriculture per unit output, plus reduced pipeline leakage. We impose a 34% reduction on irrigation water requirements per unit of output, and a 22% reduction on pipeline leakage in the 31 year period. This reduces the share of water used in most agriculture, but results in the share of water used in the irrigation sectors and households growing. Irrigators, as the most water-intensive users among industries, gain the most from water-efficiency gains which have the effect of increasing the effective water endowment. For example, the effect on rice output is +61.2%, compared with only +21.9% for crops and livestock (table 4, 5th column). “Other” industries, includes the water & drains services sector, to which water leakage is allocated as usage. Therefore, reduced leakage reduces the water used by the water & drains sector, explaining much of the drop in “Other” industries water usage (-811 GL, table 3, 5th column). (6) Reduced household water requirements We do not have evidence in the historical simulations of Dixon and Rimmer (2002) and Giesecke (2004) that the volume of water requirements used by households is falling. This is because their estimates of an inward shift in demand for water are most likely based on the services component of water supply rather than water volume. Nevertheless, washing machines and dishwashers have become more water-efficient over time. In Sydney (for example), per capita water consumption has fallen considerably. Average water usage per capita at 412 litres per person per day in 2001-2002 was 23 per cent less than in 1980/81 when usage levels peaked at 530 litres per person per day. Sydney Water’s customer research has found that customers support water conservation. An example of this awareness and interest is the introduction of regular reporting on the evening TV news of the water levels in Sydney’s major dams (Barrett, 2004). In the 31 year period to 2032, we impose a 22% downward shift on household water requirements. The 6th column of tables 3 and 4 shows the impact of projected savings in household water usage. More water becomes available for non-household users as 362 GL is diverted from households (table 3, 5th column), resulting in output increases in agriculture (table 4, 6th column). 12 Table 3. Change in water usage, Base scenario, 2032 relative to 2001, GL CropsLivestk DairyCattle Cotton Rice Hou Other Total Demand growth (1) 99 43 -433 -196 -8 495 0 Non-agri Agricultural Water Non-h’hold Household supply tech. growth change availability water savings water savings (4) (5) (6) (2) (3) -623 1586 -815 -774 151 -73 -363 -701 219 112 14 -904 -596 785 77 30 -380 -448 337 56 69 -91 -142 244 -362 583 153 -479 -811 -34 0 0 -3182 0 0 Total -384 -714 -1081 -611 -310 -81 -3182 Table 4. Output, national, Base scenario, 2032 relative to 2001, % CropsLivestk DairyCattle Cotton Rice Demand growth (1) 8.2 9.8 -11.9 -11.2 Non-agri Agricultural Water Non-h’hold Household supply tech. availability water savings water savings growth change (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) -16.5 47.9 -9.1 21.9 1.7 -5.7 15.3 -16.8 40.9 2.6 0.5 -32.7 -17.6 63.2 2.2 1.4 -23.5 -26.1 61.2 3.4 Total 54.4 50.1 3.9 4.5 Table 5. Impact of each effect on shadow price of water, Base scenario, 2032 relative to 2001, $/kl SydneyNSW MrmbidgeeNSW MurrayNSW WestNSW RoNSW MelbourneVIC MalleeVIC RestIrigVIC RoVIC BrisMoretQLD BurnDarlQLD RoQLD AdelaideSA RoSA PerthWA RoWA TasNT ACT Demand growth (1) 3.77 0.61 0.61 0.75 1.15 2.73 1.18 1.25 1.27 2.93 0.74 1.06 1.61 0.81 4.34 3.13 1.93 3.81 Non-agri supply growth (2) 3.81 -0.17 -0.17 -0.55 0.14 2.39 -0.08 -0.02 -0.01 2.31 -0.11 -0.13 0.51 -0.07 4.61 1.44 0.16 2.55 Agricultural tech. change (3) -0.59 0.52 0.51 0.71 0.33 -0.22 0.84 0.62 0.58 -0.17 0.52 0.80 0.66 0.54 -0.17 1.76 1.11 -0.69 Water availability (4) 2.52 0.41 0.41 0.22 1.21 2.23 0.78 0.74 0.72 1.91 0.39 0.65 1.27 0.52 0.40 0.78 0.59 1.16 Non-h’hold water savings (5) -0.77 -1.12 -1.13 -1.43 -1.27 -1.39 -1.75 -1.50 -1.49 -1.07 -0.93 -1.49 -1.24 -1.09 -1.18 -3.45 -2.09 -0.22 Household water savings (6) -2.47 -0.05 -0.05 -0.05 -0.16 -1.15 -0.14 -0.15 -0.15 -1.28 -0.07 -0.09 -0.82 -0.09 -1.97 -0.53 -0.37 -3.80 Total 6.20 0.17 0.17 -0.34 1.44 4.41 0.85 0.98 1.20 8.51 0.80 0.30 0.11 0.46 9.47 4.23 1.49 1.95 13 Table 6. Decomposition of national results, Base scenario, 2032 relative to 2001, % Aggregate consumption Real GDP Aggregate Employment Population Demand growth (1) Non-agri supply growth (2) Agricultural tech. change (3) Water availability (4) Non-h’hold water savings (5) Household water savings (6) Total 14.7 15.0 21.3 21.2 1.1 1.1 -0.5 -0.5 0.6 0.7 0.1 0.1 38.4 38.0 16.4 27.1 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 16.4 27.1 Table 5 shows the impact of population growth and associated economic changes over time on the change in the shadow price of water, in the absence of inter-regional trading. Highlights include: • Each rapidly growing urban centre suffers major price hikes for water. In Sydney, the price increase is $6.20/kl, in Melbourne $4.41/kl, in Brisbane & Gold Coast $8.51/kl and Perth, $9.47/kl. In regions containing the largest users of water, namely rice, cotton and dairy cattle, the impact of agricultural productivity growth on the shadow price of water is large. For example, in WestNSW, this affect alone raises the price by $0.71/kl. The link between productivity growth and the rising price of water is simple enough to explain. As labour and capital in a given industry become more productive, the marginal output of relatively fixed factors, namely water, will increase. Therefore, the price of water should rise. There must be some uncertainty as to where water will move following the opening up of water trading. The present set of assumptions appears to favour movement of water to urban areas. However, only a fraction of this potential movement arises from increased household demands. In Sydney, for example, demand growth alone induces a $3.77/kl hike in the price of water, while non-agricultural productivity and import supply growth induces a further increase of $3.81/kl (table 1.3). Similarly, the extent to which water conserving measures are taken by households, has a marked effect on the price, with our present assumption concerning such savings reducing Sydney’s shadow price in this scenario by $2.47/kl. Perhaps the main insight from table 6 is that economic growth is partly attributable to population and employment growth, as shown in column (1), and partly to growth in capital stocks and technology change, the effects of which are included in column (2). Changes in water availability have relatively limited impacts at the national level. 14 5. Other scenarios Other scenarios are detailed in CSIRO (2006, forthcoming). Rather than present the results in the same detail here, we will summarise. Scenario 2 concerns projecting to 25 million, while allowing inter-regional trade of water. In some urban regions, water price increases are greatly alleviated when we allow such trade. In Brisbane & Gold Coast, instead of the price hike being +$8.51/kl, it is only +$1.23/kl, via water trading with Darling Downs/Wide Bay-Burnett. Significant reductions are also apparent in Melbourne, the price hike falling from +$4.41/kl to +$0.37/kl, through water trading with the Murray-Darling Basin regions. In Sydney, water trading with the remaining coastal regions of NSW reduces the hike from +$6.20/kl to +$1.48/kl. Less dramatic is the fall in Perth, from $9.47/kl to $4.80/kl. A tentative conclusion from this scenario is that water trading alone could satisfy Melbourne’s future water needs, but significant upward price pressures on water remain in Perth, and, to a lesser extent, Sydney and Brisbane & Gold Coast. Water trading also provided benefits at the macroeconomic level, with national aggregate consumption being 1.0% higher in scenario 2 than the base scenario without inter-regional water trading. After trading, in these projections, the output losses in some major irrigation regions are quite substantial. Real GDP falls in the Murrumbidgee (-4.6%) and Murray (-5.3%) statistical divisions of NSW, and West NSW(-11.0%) (combining Far West, North West and Northern NSW statistical divisions) relative to the base 25 million scenario. Either rice and cotton currently dominate water usage in these regions. Another region with a substantial economic decline relative to no water trading is Wide Bay-Burnett/Darling Downs in Queensland (-4.3%), as a consequence of water being acquired by Brisbane & Gold Coast. The regional declines are significant, though potentially not as small as if nothing were done to address environmental issues. Since desalination costs have fallen well below $2.00/kl, there may be a role for desalination to play in some urban centres. In addition, desalination may be a relatively low cost means of filling water supply needs in relatively remote coastal regions. Eyre Peninsula in South Australia is one example. Such relatively local possibilities for desalination are at a finer level of disaggregation in the regional dimension than we model in this study. Scenario 3 includes desalination plants in Sydney, Brisbane-Moreton and Perth, together with inter-regional water trading. In each of three urban regions, the plant has an annual capacity of 80 GL per annum with average costs of $1.50/kl. If projected water demands fall well below the additional capacity, average costs of supply will rise. The CSIRO study presents the results of a lower desalination price ($1.00/kl) combined with larger capacity (120 GL per annum) in a separate simulation. The desalination plants providing water at $1.50/kl lower the shadow price increase for water in Sydney (from $1.48/kl in scenario 2 to $1.24/kl), Brisbane & Gold Coast ($1.23/kl to $1.03/kl) and Perth ($4.80/kl to $3.11). Larger capacity desalination with lower unit costs, as in scenario 3a, lowers shadow price hikes further, to only $1.16/kl in Sydney, $0.96/kl in Brisbane & Gold Coast and $2.56/kl in Perth. 15 The macroeconomic effects of lower average desalination costs are minor. There is debate concerning whether desalination plants are appropriate for meeting future urban water needs. Desalination remains relatively energy-intensive. Alternative means of meeting water requirements include storm water capture, water recycling and further conservation measures. The costliness and practicality of these measures warrant further investigation. ABS population projections carry considerable weight when we consider future urban water needs. The very high employment and population growth rates projected for Perth and Brisbane & Gold Coast drive rapid increases in demand for water in these metropolitan regions, and consequently large increase in water prices. Scenario 4 is essentially a repeat of scenario 3, but this time, the inter-regional growth rate differentials are reduced by reducing real wage growth differentials between regions. But this effect raises rather than reduces employment and population growth in Sydney and Melbourne, because their baseline growth rates are smaller than those applying nationally. It also substantially increases Adelaide’s employment change relative to scenario 3. In scenario 4, there is a moderate alleviation of the shadow water price increase in Brisbane & Gold Coast due to slower population growth. In Perth, the effect is somewhat more substantial, as it applies to a higher shadow price hike. An important issue we can consider in the context of scenario 4 is the risk of investing in desalination in a region in which population growth turns out to be smaller than projected. In the case of Brisbane & Gold Coast, water trading plays a bigger role in alleviating water scarcities than desalination. However, the water price increase is still large enough with water trading that desalination appears to have a role to play in meeting future water needs. In the case of Perth, the water price hikes are so large in all scenarios that the issue appears not to be whether to have desalination plants to supplement existing water supplies, but rather the capacity such plants should have. This assumes that no other water sources are proximal to Perth: a recent finding that the capacity of an aquifer near Perth is sufficiently large to cater for Perth’s future water needs requires further analysis. 6. Planned modelling modifications: adding hydrological detail The projections summarised in this paper illustrate the potential role that water trading could play in meeting future water requirements in the economy. Projecting TERM ahead 31 years takes us further than comparative static scenarios and provides a number of insights not apparent from comparative statics. Notable among these is that with productivity growth in agriculture over time, the shadow price of water in irrigation regions will rise. In addition, productivity growth in other sectors also raises the shadow price. This implies therefore that households will not automatically “outbid” other users if rural-urban water trading proceeds.2 Another insight is that in one urban region (Melbourne), water trading may be sufficient to meet future water needs. The same result is not as clear in Brisbane & Gold Coast or Sydney, 2 The term “outbid” is somewhat misleading. As with all commodities in TERM, we assume that water is imperfectly substitutable. An intra-regional Armington parameter applies to households. In industries, the response is limited by the cost share of water. The smaller the cost share, the more inelastic is the demand for water. 16 while it appears highly probable that Perth will require additional water sources as the city grows. With water trading, the potential exists for incomes earned in irrigation regions to fall markedly as agricultural production declines. Some income would be recouped from water sales, but in the event of the holder of a permanent water right selling that right and leaving the region, the income from the sale would not remain within the region. The inference is that water trading may not necessarily have a benign impact on regional incomes. There are a number of areas in which modelling could be improved. The first of these concerns hydrology. We have assumed quite simply in our projections that the water available for economic use declines by 15% in most regions in the 31 year interval. A model that depicts random year-by-year variations in water catchment (perhaps based on historical data) would provide additional insights. For example, Qureshi et al. (2005) examine environmental flows. An implication of their paper is that environmental flows discharged in years when water is relatively abundant due to widespread above-average rainfall will improve the health of ecosystems while minimizing the impact on regional economies. On the other hand, a severe drought might present water management issues that are not covered in forward projections of TERM based on the smooth-growth assumption. It appears desirable to develop a hydrological module in tandem with a fully dynamic multiregional CGE model. A dynamic version of TERM already exists, as noted earlier, but it does not include water accounts. Other issues will arise inevitably as we add hydrology to a CGE model. One stumbling block so far has been the perception that we ought to be attempting to replicate the behaviour of regional water managers, rather than using a model to explore optimal water allocation. Other stumbling blocks concern regional and time dimensions. ABS data particularly for agriculture are available only at the statistical division level, yet hydrological detail tends to be available in various combinations of Statistical Local Areas (SLAs), the next level of regional disaggregation down from statistical divisions. This is an issue that will need to be resolved in the course of the project. There are two types of hydrological models, as explained in Dixon et al. (2005). One type deals with regional water allocation. Typically, such models operate on a monthly basis, allocating water throughout the year, whereas dynamic CGE models typically run on an annual basis, presenting another dimensional inconsistency that we will need to deal with. The other type deals with the relationship between water use and crop yield. This second type reintroduces an idea used in the first application of TERM to drought (Horridge et al., 2003), in which rainfall deficits were linked to declines in crop output. A more ambitious vision for this project is that we start linking environmental outcomes to the CGE model. In one sense, this is appealing as results of particular policy measures could be presented as both environmental and economic outcomes. In another sense, it may be simpler to keep the results of CGE models separate from environmental outcomes. For example, Qureshi et al. (2005) tell an important story without quantifying environmental benefits. It may be that it is sufficient to communicate the economic implications arising from a particular volume of water being allocated to the environment in a particular year. This would leave the judgment of the environmental impacts to those with expertise in the area. 17 References ABARE (2004), Australian Commodity Statistics, Canberra. ABS (2004), Water account Australia, ABS catalogue no. 4610.0. ABS (2005), Australian national accounts, State accounts, ABS catalogue no. 5220.0. Adams, P., Horridge, M., Wittwer, G., (2002), MMRF-Green: A dynamic multi-regional applied general equilibrium model of the Australian economy, based on the MMR and MONASH models, Prepared for the Regional GE Modelling Course, 25-29 November. Barrett, G. (2004), “Water conservation: The role of price and regulation in residential water consumption”, Economic Papers, 23(3): 271-85, September. Bureau of Meteorology (2005), http://www.bom.gov.au/climate/map/evaporation/ evap_ann.shtml, accessed January 10, 2006 CSIRO (2006), Without water, (forthcoming). Dixon P. and Rimmer, M. (2002) Dynamic General Equilibrium Modelling for Forecasting and Policy: a Practical Guide and Documentation of MONASH, Contributions to Economic Analysis 256, North-Holland Publishing Company, Amsterdam. Dixon. P., Schreider, S. and Wittwer, G. (2005), “Combining engineering-based water models with a CGE model”, chapter 2 in Productivity Commission, Quantitative tools for microeconomic policy analysis, Conference Proceedings, 17-18 November, 2004, Canberra. Giesecke, J. (2004), “The extent and consequences of recent structural changes in the Australian economy, 1997-2002: results from historical/decomposition simulations with MONASH”, General Working paper no. G-151, Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University, http://www.monash.edu.au/policy/ftp/workpapr/g-151.pdf Hajkowicz, S. and Young, M. (2002), Value of returns to land and water and costs of degradation, Project 6.1 Final Report to the National Land and Water Resources Audit, CSIRO Land and Water. Hertel, T. (editor) (1996), Global trade analysis: modeling and applications, New York: Cambridge University Press. Horridge, M, Madden, J. and Wittwer, G. (2005), “Using a highly disaggregated multi-regional single-country model to analyse the impacts of the 2002-03 drought on Australia”, Journal of Policy Modelling 27(3):285-308, May. Madden, J. (1992), The theoretical structure of the Federal model, CREA Paper No. TS-02, Centre of Regional Economic Analysis, University of Tasmania, May. Maddock, R. and McLean, I. (1987), “The Australian economy in the very long run”, chapter 1 in The Australian economy in the long run, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge. 18 Qureshi, E., Connor, J., Kirby, M. and Mainuddin, M. (2005), “Economic assessment of environmental flows in the Murray basin”, CSIRO draft paper. Peterson, D., Dwyer, G., Appels, D. & Fry, J. (2005), “Water Trade in the Southern MurrayDarling Basin”, Economic Record, 81: S115-S127, September. Wittwer, G., Vere, D., Jones, R. and Griffith, G. (2005), “Dynamic general equilibrium analysis of improved weed management in Australia's winter cropping systems”, Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 49(4): 363-377, December. 19