Download Principles of Economics, Case and Fair,9e

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup

Business cycle wikipedia , lookup

Keynesian economics wikipedia , lookup

Fiscal multiplier wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
PowerPoint Lectures for
Principles of Economics,
9e
; ;
By
Karl E. Case,
Ray C. Fair &
Sharon M. Oster
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
1 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
2 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory
The level of GDP, the overall price level, and the
level of employment—three chief concerns of
macroeconomists—are influenced by events in
three broadly defined “markets”:
Goods-and-services market
Financial (money) market
Labor market
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
3 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
PART V The Core of Macroeconomic Theory
 FIGURE III.1 The Core of Macroeconomic Theory
We build up the macroeconomy slowly. In Chapters 8 and 9, we examine the market for goods and services.
In Chapters 10 and 11, we examine the money market. Then in Chapter 12, we bring the two markets
together, in so doing explaining the links between aggregate output (Y) and the interest rate (r), and derive
the aggregate demand curve. In Chapter 13, we introduce the aggregate supply curve and determine the
price level (P). We then explain in Chapter 14 how the labor market fits into the macroeconomic picture.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
4 of 27
PART V THE CORE OF MACROECONOMIC THEORY
23
Aggregate Expenditure
and Equilibrium Output
Prepared by:
Fernando & Yvonn Quijano
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
PART V THE CORE OF MACROECONOMIC THEORY
23
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
Aggregate Expenditure
and Equilibrium Output
CHAPTER OUTLINE
The Keynesian Theory of Consumption
Other Determinants of Consumption
Planned Investment (I)
The Determination of Equilibrium
Output (Income)
The Saving/Investment Approach to
Equilibrium
Adjustment to Equilibrium
The Multiplier
The Multiplier Equation
The Size of the Multiplier in the Real
World
Looking Ahead
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
6 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
aggregate output The total quantity of goods and
services produced (or supplied) in an economy in
a given period.
aggregate income The total income received by
all factors of production in a given period.
aggregate output (income) (Y) A combined term
used to remind you of the exact equality between
aggregate output and aggregate income.
In any given period, there is an exact equality
between aggregate output (production) and
aggregate income. You should be reminded of this
fact whenever you encounter the combined
term aggregate output (income) (Y).
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
7 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
The Keynesian Theory of Consumption
consumption function The relationship between
consumption and income.
 FIGURE 23.1 A Consumption
Function for a Household
A consumption function for an
individual household shows the
level of consumption at each level
of household income.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
8 of 27
Chapter 22 Figure
22-3
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
A Plot of the Consumption Function
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
The Saving Function Is the Mirror
Image of the Consumption
Function
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
Chapter 22 Figure
22-4
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
The Keynesian Theory of Consumption
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
With a straight line consumption curve, we can use
the following equation to describe the curve:
C = a + bY
 FIGURE 23.2 An Aggregate
Consumption Function
The aggregate consumption
function shows the level of
aggregate consumption at each
level of aggregate income.
The upward slope indicates that
higher levels of income lead to
higher levels of consumption
spending.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
11 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
The Keynesian Theory of Consumption
marginal propensity to consume (MPC) That
fraction of a change in income that is consumed,
or spent.
marginal propensity to consume  slope of consumption function 
C
Y
aggregate saving (S) The part of aggregate
income that is not consumed.
S≡Y–C
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
12 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
Economists are very fond of marginal analysis and
margin means change (especially small change).
Change, you should recall, is also how we measure
a line’s slope (change in Y axis over change in X
axis between two points). So, margin is the same
thing as slope. This concept is very useful for
economists. For example, from microeconomics: the
slope of total cost is marginal cost, and the slope of
total revenue is marginal revenue; and from
macroeconomics: the slope of the consumption
function is the marginal propensity to consume, and
the slope of the savings function is the marginal
propensity to save. The sooner you learn this, the
easier your time as a student of economics will be
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
13 of 27
The Keynesian Theory of Consumption
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
identity Something that is always true.
marginal propensity to save (MPS) That fraction
of a change in income that is saved.
MPC + MPS ≡ 1
Because the MPC and the MPS are important
concepts, it may help to review their definitions.
The marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is the
fraction of an increase in income that is
consumed (or the fraction of a decrease in income
that comes out of consumption). The marginal
propensity to save (MPS) is the fraction of an
increase in income that is saved (or the fraction
of a decrease in income that comes out of saving).
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
14 of 27
The Keynesian Theory of Consumption
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
 FIGURE 23.3 The
Aggregate Consumption
Function Derived from the
Equation C = 100 + .75Y
In this simple consumption function,
consumption is 100 at an income of
zero.
As income rises, so does
consumption. For every 100 increase
in income, consumption rises by 75.
The slope of the line is .75.
AGGREGATE
AGGREGATE
INCOME, Y
CONSUMPTION, C
(BILLIONS OF
(BILLIONS OF
DOLLARS)
DOLLARS)
0
100
80
160
100
175
200
250
400
400
600
550
800
700
1,000
850
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
15 of 27
The Keynesian Theory of Consumption
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
 FIGURE 23.4 Deriving the Saving
Function from the Consumption Function
in Figure 23.3
Because S ≡ Y – C, it is easy to derive the
saving function from the consumption
function. A 45° line drawn from the origin can
be used as a convenient tool to compare
consumption and income graphically.
At Y = 200, consumption is 250. The 45° line
shows us that consumption is larger than
income by 50. Thus, S ≡ Y – C = -50.
At Y = 800, consumption is less than income
by 100. Thus, S = 100 when Y = 800.
Y
-
AGGREGATE
INCOME
(Billions of
Dollars)
C
=
AGGREGATE
CONSUMPTION
(Billions of
Dollars)
S
AGGREGATE
SAVING
(Billions of
Dollars)
0
100
-100
80
160
-80
100
175
-75
200
250
-50
400
400
0
600
550
50
800
700
100
1,000
850
150
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
16 of 27
The Keynesian Theory of Consumption
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
Other Determinants of Consumption
The assumption that consumption depends only
on income is obviously a simplification. In practice,
the decisions of households on how much to
consume in a given period are also affected by
their wealth, by the interest rate, and by their
expectations of the future. Households with higher
wealth are likely to spend more, other things being
equal, than households with less wealth.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
17 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
B. Investment
1. Investment—spending on new housing, plants and
equipment, and additions to inventories is the second
major component of aggregate demand. It is important
not only for its role in determining aggregate demand
but also for its relationship to the stock of capital, the
long-term growth of the economy, and aggregate
supply.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
18 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
2. An important determinant of investment is the overall
level of output or GDP in the economy. Firms are more
likely to invest in new plant and equipment if managers
believe there is a strong market for their
products. Hence if the economy is growing and sales are
rising, firms are more likely to invest.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
19 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
3. A second important determinant of investment is cost.
Because capital equipment usually lasts a number of
years and is expensive, firms typically finance investment
projects by borrowing. Therefore, interest rates are an
important cost associated with investment. An additional
cost factor related to investment is the corporate tax
levied on firms by the government. Taxes decrease
profits, thereby decreasing the attractiveness of
investment projects. Alternatively, investment tax credits,
given by the government, may encourage firms to
expand investment.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
20 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
Planned Investment (I)
 FIGURE 23.5 The Planned
Investment Function
For the time being, we will
assume that planned investment
is fixed.
It does not change when income
changes, so its graph is a
horizontal line.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
21 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
Planned Investment (I)
planned investment (I) Those additions
to capital stock and inventory that are
planned by firms.
actual investment The actual amount of
investment that takes place; it includes
items such as unplanned changes in
inventories.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
22 of 27
Chapter 22 Figure
22-10
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
Investment Depends upon Interest
Rate
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
Chapter 22 Figure
22-11
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
Shifts in Investment Demand
Function
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
Planned Investment (I)
Behavioral Biases in
Saving Behavior
Economists have generally
assumed that people make
their saving decisions rationally,
just as they make other
decisions about choices in
consumption and the labor market. Saving decisions involve
thinking about trade-offs between present and future consumption.
Recent work in behavioral economics has highlighted the role of
psychological biases in saving behavior and has demonstrated
that seemingly small changes in the way saving programs are
designed can result in big behavioral changes.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
25 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)
equilibrium Occurs when there is no tendency for
change. In the macroeconomic goods market,
equilibrium occurs when planned aggregate
expenditure is equal to aggregate output.
planned aggregate expenditure (AE) The total
amount the economy plans to spend in a given
period. Equal to consumption plus planned
investment: AE ≡ C + I.
Y>C+I
aggregate output > planned aggregate expenditure
C+I>Y
planned aggregate expenditure > aggregate output
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
26 of 27
The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
TABLE 23.1 Deriving the Planned Aggregate Expenditure Schedule and Finding Equilibrium
The Figures in Column 2 Are Based on the Equation C = 100 + .75Y.
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Planned
Unplanned
Aggregate
Aggregate
Inventory
Output
Aggregate
Planned
Expenditure (AE) Change
Equilibrium?
(Income) (Y) Consumption (C) Investment (I)
C+I
(Y = AE?)
Y - (C + I)
100
175
25
200
- 100
No
200
250
25
275
- 75
No
400
400
25
425
- 25
No
500
475
25
500
0
Yes
600
550
25
575
+ 25
No
800
700
25
725
+ 75
No
1,000
850
25
875
+ 125
No
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
27 of 27
The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
 FIGURE 23.6 Equilibrium
Aggregate Output
Equilibrium occurs when planned
aggregate expenditure and
aggregate output are equal.
Planned aggregate expenditure
is the sum of consumption
spending and planned
investment spending.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
28 of 27
The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
The Saving/Investment Approach to Equilibrium
Because aggregate income must either be saved
or spent, by definition, Y ≡ C + S, which is an
identity. The equilibrium condition is Y = C + I, but
this is not an identity because it does not hold
when we are out of equilibrium. By substituting C
+ S for Y in the equilibrium condition, we can
write:
C+S=C+I
Because we can subtract C from both sides of this
equation, we are left with:
S=I
Thus, only when planned investment equals
saving will there be equilibrium.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
29 of 27
The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
The Saving/Investment Approach to Equilibrium
 FIGURE 23.7 The S = I
Approach to Equilibrium
Aggregate output is equal
to planned aggregate
expenditure only when
saving equals planned
investment (S = I).
Saving and planned
investment are equal at Y
= 500.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
30 of 27
The Determination of Equilibrium Output (Income)
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
Adjustment to Equilibrium
The adjustment process will continue as long as
output (income) is below planned aggregate
expenditure. If firms react to unplanned inventory
reductions by increasing output, an economy with
planned spending greater than output will adjust to
equilibrium, with Y higher than before. If planned
spending is less than output, there will be
unplanned increases in inventories. In this case,
firms will respond by reducing output. As output
falls, income falls, consumption falls, and so on,
until equilibrium is restored, with Y lower than
before.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
31 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
The Multiplier
multiplier The ratio of the change in the
equilibrium level of output to a change in some
exogenous variable.
exogenous variable A variable that is assumed
not to depend on the state of the economy—that
is, it does not change when the economy changes.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
32 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
The Multiplier
 FIGURE 23.8 The Multiplier
as Seen in the Planned
Aggregate Expenditure Diagram
At point A, the economy is in
equilibrium at Y = 500.
When I increases by 25,
planned aggregate expenditure
is initially greater than
aggregate output. As output
rises in response, additional
consumption is generated,
pushing equilibrium output up
by a multiple of the initial
increase in I.
The new equilibrium is found at
point B, where Y = 600.
Equilibrium output has
increased by 100 (600 - 500),
or four times the amount of the
increase in planned
investment.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
33 of 27
The Multiplier
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
The Multiplier Equation
The marginal propensity to save may be
expressed as:
S
MPS 
Y
Because S must be equal to I for equilibrium to
be restored, we can substitute I for S and solve:
I
MPS 
Y
1
therefore,  Y   I 
MPS
1
multiplier 
MPS
, or
1
multiplier 
1 - MPC
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
34 of 27
The Multiplier
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
The Multiplier Equation
The Paradox of Thrift
The Paradox of Thrift
An increase in planned saving from
S0 to S1 causes equilibrium output
to decrease from 500 to 300. The
decreased consumption that
accompanies increased saving
leads to a contraction of the
economy and to a reduction of
income. But at the new equilibrium,
saving is the same as it was at the
initial equilibrium. Increased efforts
to save have caused a drop in
income but no overall change in
saving.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
35 of 27
The Multiplier
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
The Size of the Multiplier in the Real World
In considering the size of the multiplier, it is
important to realize that the multiplier we derived
in this chapter is based on a very simplified
picture of the economy.
In reality the size of the multiplier is about 1.4.
That is, a sustained increase in exogenous
spending of $10 billion into the U.S. economy can
be expected to raise real GDP over time by about
$14 billion.
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
36 of 27
CHAPTER 23 Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium Output
REVIEW TERMS AND CONCEPTS
actual investment
aggregate income
aggregate output
aggregate output (income)
(Y)
aggregate saving (S)
consumption function
equilibrium
exogenous variable
Identity
marginal propensity to
consume (MPC)
marginal propensity to save
(MPS)
multiplier
planned aggregate expenditure
(AE)
planned investment (I)
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
S≡Y−C
MPC  slope of consumption function 
MPC + MPS ≡ 1
AE ≡ C + I
Equilibrium condition: Y = AE or
Y=C+I
6. Saving/investment approach to
equilibrium: S = I
7. Multiplier 
C
Y
1
1

MPS 1 - MPC
© 2009 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall Principles of Economics 9e by Case, Fair and Oster
37 of 27