Download Ch 16

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Marginalism wikipedia , lookup

Externality wikipedia , lookup

Market (economics) wikipedia , lookup

Perfect competition wikipedia , lookup

Supply and demand wikipedia , lookup

General equilibrium theory wikipedia , lookup

Economic equilibrium wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Chapter 16
General Equilibrium, Efficiency,
and Equity
McGraw-Hill/Irwin
Copyright © 2008 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All Rights Reserved.
Main Topics
The nature of general equilibrium
Positive analysis of general equilibrium
Normative criteria for evaluating
economic performance
General equilibrium and efficient
exchange
Equity and redistribution
16-2
The Nature of General Equilibrium
 Already studied competitive equilibrium in a single
isolated market: partial equilibrium analysis
 Useful when supply and demand for a good are largely
independent of activities in other markets
 However, markets are often interdependent (e.g., if
complements or substitutes)
 General equilibrium analysis is the study of
competitive equilibrium in many markets at the same
time
 Allows us to understand the consequences of interdependence
among markets
 Factors that affect supply and demand in one market can have
ripple effects in other markets
 Accounts for feedback between markets
 Markets can be linked because the price or production of one
good affects the demand or cost of another….think substitutes
or complements.
16-3
Figure 16.1: General Equilibrium
Above is the general equilibrium in the markets for Pie
and Ice cream. Both equilibriums take the other product
(and product price) into account in identifying its own
16-4
product clearing price and quantity.
Positive Analysis of
General Equilibrium
 General equilibrium analysis can provide more
accurate answers than partial equilibrium analysis
does to positive questions
 Examine the effects of a sales tax on ice cream
 Assume pie and ice cream are complements
 Assume no supply linkages
 General equilibrium effects of the tax include:
 Demand curve for pie shifts downward, so price of pie falls
 This produces a feedback effect on the ice cream market
 Effects of the tax ripple back and forth between the markets
 Need a new tool to determine the prices that will
prevail in both markets in a general equilibrium
16-5
Market-Clearing Curves
First step in identifying a general equilibrium is
to find the market-clearing curve for each good
Shows the combinations of prices for that good and
related goods that bring supply and demand for the
good into balance
Prices of the goods are on the axes
For two goods that are complements, the
market-clearing curves will be downward
sloping
Example: an increase in the price of pie reduces the
demand for ice cream, which lowers the partial
equilibrium price of ice cream
For substitutes, the curves will be upward
sloping
16-6
Figure 16.2: A Market-Clearing Curve
Slide A shows the ice cream curve with 3 different
demand curves that correspond to different prices for
pie. Slide B is the general equil. market-clearing curve for
16-7
both products.
Figure 16.2: A Market-Clearing Curve
Slide A shows the pie curve with 3 different demand
curves that correspond to different prices for ice cream.
Slide B is the general equil. market-clearing curve for
both products.
16-8
General Equilibrium in
Two Markets
If a price combination lies on both marketclearing curves, then both markets are in
equilibrium
This is a general equilibrium
Find a general equilibrium by plotting both
market-clearing curves on the same graph
Horizontal axis shows the price of one good;
vertical axis shows the price of the other good
Intersection of the two market-clearing curves
reveals the general equilibrium prices
The two goods markets clear at these prices
16-9
Figure 16.4: General Equilibrium
Price Combination
General
equilibrium prices
are $12 per pie
and $6 per gallon
of ice cream
Pie and ice cream
markets both clear
at these prices
16-10
Effects of a Sales Tax:
Partial Equilibrium
Continue the ice cream example
Examine effects of $3 per gallon sales tax on ice
cream
Begin from initial equilibrium price of $6 per gallon,
25 million gallons
Tax shifts supply curve upward by $3
New partial equilibrium is at intersection of the
new supply curve and initial demand curve
Price of pie held constant at $12 per pie
(Consumer) Price of ice cream rises by $1.67
per gallon, less than the amount of the tax
16-11
Effect of a Sales Tax:
Gen. Equilibrium
Need new market-clearing curve for ice cream,
to find general equilibrium effects of tax
Tax shifts market-clearing curve for ice cream
upward
New curve lies exactly $1.67 above the old one
Magnitude of the shift equals partial equilibrium
effect of the tax
Look for intersection of new market-clearing
curve for ice cream and old market-clearing
curve for pie
Shows new general equilibrium
Pie price is $11 per pie, ice cream price is $8 per
gallon
These prices clear both markets
16-12
Effect of a Sales Tax:
Gen. Equilibrium
16-13
Sales Tax Effect : General Equilibrium
As a result of the tax, demand curves for both
goods shift
Sales tax on ice cream reduces the price of a
pie by $1
Because pie and ice cream are complements
Partial equilibrium analysis understates the
effect of the tax on the price of ice cream
Based on partial anal., ice cream prices rise only by
$1.67, but based on general equil, prices rise by $2.
Lower pie price leads to greater demand for ice
cream
Reinforces pressure for ice cream price to rise
General equilibrium analysis accounts for this
feedback; partial equilibrium analysis does not
16-14
Figure 16.6: Effects of a Tax, part 2
16-15
Normative Criteria for
Economic Performance
Economists have clear criteria for measuring
efficiency
Equity and fairness are more difficult to
determine and evaluate
An allocation of resources is Pareto efficient if
it’s impossible to make any consumer better off
without hurting someone else
Proposed by Italian economist Vilfredo Pareto
Assume each person knows what’s best for her
The utility possibility frontier shows the
utility levels associated with all efficient
allocations of resources
16-16
Figure 16.7: Pareto Efficient
Outcomes
Points on the
boundary are Pareto
efficient
Point A is inefficient
16-17
Equity
 Equity is harder to define and measure than efficiency
 Process-oriented notions of equity focus on the
procedures used to arrive at an allocation of resources
 Focus on what could be chosen instead of what is chosen.
 Is the free market a fair process?
 Outcome-oriented notions focus on whether the process
used to allocate resources yields fair results
 Some focus on the distribution of well-being, e.g., utilitarianism
(equal weight on w-b of every person)
 Rawlsianism – focus should be on the w-b of the worst-off member
of society
 Others focus on the distribution of consumption, e.g.,
egalitarianism (equal division of resources to every member of
society)
16-18
Social Welfare Functions
 Economists use social welfare functions to
summarize judgments about resource allocations
 For each possible allocation, the function assigns a number
that indicates the overall level of social welfare
 Higher numbers reflect greater social well-being
 First, assign utility levels to every consumer using
utility functions
 Second, apply a function that converts those utilities
into social welfare
 Higher levels of individual utility imply higher levels of social
welfare
 Can capture concerns for both efficiency and outcomeoriented notions of equity
Social Welfare  W U1 ,U 2 ,,U N 
16-19
Figure 16.8: Applying Social
Welfare Functions
 Indifference curves
farther from the origin
correspond to higher
levels of social welfare
 Point A is the best
possible outcome
 Since Point A is on the
utility possibility frontier,
it is Pareto efficient
 The social welfare
function reflects a
preference for efficiency
16-20
General Equilibrium in
Exchange Economies
 In an exchange economy, people own and trade goods but no
production takes place. This is a starting model to explain the
concept.
 An endowment is the bundle of goods an individual starts out with
before trading
 Simple example:
 Humphrey and Lauren are the only consumers
 Two goods: food and water
 Humphrey’s initial endowment is 8 pounds of food and 3 gallons of
water
 Lauren’s initial endowment is 2 pounds of food and 7 gallons of water
 If food sells for $1 per pound and water sells for $1 per gallon this
is not a general equilibrium
 Supply and demand for the two people match if food costs $2 per
pound and water sells for $1 per gallon
 This is a general equilibrium
16-21
Figure 16.9: General Equilibrium
in an Exchange Economy
16-22
The Edgeworth Box
The Edgeworth box is a diagram that shows
two consumers’ opportunities and choices in a
single figure
Often used for a simple exchange economy
Introduced by British economist Francis Edgeworth
in 1881
Each point describes an allocation of resources
between the two consumers
Dimensions of the box are determined by the total
amounts of each good available in the economy
When the economy is in general equilibrium
the points representing the two consumers’
choices after trading coincide
16-23
Equilibrium in an Edgeworth Box
 Point A represents initial
endowment
 Point C is the general
equilibrium resource
allocation
 Food costs $2 per pound
 Water costs $1 per gallon
 Notice how they coincide.
 Also, the curves are
opposite due to the
inverse nature of the graph.
16-24
The First Welfare Theorem
 First welfare theorem: in a general equilibrium with
perfect information the allocation of resources is Pareto
efficient
 Clarifies what Adam Smith mean by the “invisible hand”
 Use Edgeworth box to understand first welfare theorem
 At general equilibrium allocation, two consumers face the
same equilibrium prices
 Line representing these prices serves as the budget line for
both consumers
 Impossible to choose an allocation at equilibrium prices,
other than equilibrium allocation, that helps one
consumer without hurting the other
 The general equilibrium is Pareto efficient
16-25
Figure 16.11: First Welfare Theorem
in an Exchange Economy
They like points on the budget line equally. But the points of D and E
are not as well liked as choosing either of them would hurt the other
16-26
party.
Efficiency in Exchange
16-27
Efficiency in Exchange
 Whenever an allocation is inefficient, there are gains
from trade
 Whenever an allocation is efficient there are no mutually
beneficial trades
 The Exchange efficiency condition holds if every pair
of individuals shares the same MRS for every pair of
goods
 Holds as long as consumers’ indifference curves are smooth
and have declining MRS
 A test for existence of potential gains from trade between
consumers
 When consumers’ MRS differ, they can both gain by trading
 Contract curve shows every efficient allocation of
consumption goods in an Edgeworth box
 Starts at the southwest corner and ends at the northeast
corner
 Every allocation on the contract curve corresponds to a point
on the utility possibility frontier, and vice versa
16-28
Figure 16.13: Contract Curve
16-29
General Equilibrium and
Efficient Production
 If add production, competitive equilibria remain Pareto
efficient
 Exchange efficiency is not enough; production must
also be efficient
 Two requirements for production efficiency:
 Input efficiency
 Output efficiency
 Input efficiency: there is no way to increase any firm’s
output of one good without decreasing the output of
another good
 Holding constant the total amount of each input used in the
economy
 Pareto efficiency requires input efficiency
16-30
Input Efficiency Example
 Two inputs:
 Labor, total of 50 workers
 Capital, total of 25 machines
 Two firms:
 MunchieCo, produces food
 CribCo, produces housing
 Use an Edgeworth box to illustrate allocations of inputs
between firms
 Allocations where two isoquants cross are inefficient
 At points where the two firms’ isoquants touch but do
not cross, the two inputs are allocated efficiently
 There is no way to increase the output of one good without
decreasing the output of the other
16-31
Figure 16.15: Input Efficiency
16-32
A Condition for Input Efficiency
 Production contract curve shows every efficient
allocation of inputs between two firms in an Edgeworth
box
 At efficient allocations, on firm’s MRTSLK is the same
as the other’s
 The firms’ isoquants lie tangent to the same straight line
 Slope of this line shows the rate at which both firms can
substitute labor for capital without changing their output
 Input efficiency criterion holds if every pair of firms
shares the MRTS between every pair of inputs
 As long as the firms’ isoquants are smooth and have declining
MRTS
 Allocations that satisfy this condition are efficient
 A test for existence of potential gains from trade between firms
16-33
Production Possibilities
 Production possibility frontier shows the
combinations of outputs that firms can produce when
inputs are allocated efficiently among them
 Given their technologies and the total inputs available
 Relationship between the PPF and the production
contract curve is the same as the relationship between
the utility possibility frontier and the contract curve
 Each input allocation on the production contract curve
is associated with a point on the PPF and vice versa
 PPF always slopes downward
 Upward slope would imply that, starting on the frontier, it’s
possible to increase the production of both goods without
changing the total amount of any input
 But this would mean that the allocation of inputs on the frontier
is inefficient and, by definition, the PPF includes only efficient
combinations
16-34
Figure 16.16: Production
Possibility Frontier
16-35
Marginal Rate of Transformation
 Downward slope of the PPF reflects tradeoffs involved in
production
 If we choose to produce more of one good, we must produce less of
another
 Marginal rate of transformation from good X to good Y is the
additional amount of Y that can be produced by sacrificing one
unit of X
 At any point on the PPF, the marginal rate of transformation is
equal to the slope of a straight line drawn tangent to the frontier
at the point, times negative one
 Marginal rate of transformation is also related to the firms’
marginal products
 Frontier gets steeper moving from left to right
 Marginal rate of transformation from X to Y rises
 Reflects decreasing returns to scale in the production technologies
16-36
Output Efficiency
 Output efficiency means there is no way to make all
consumers better off by shifting production from one
good to another
 Among allocations satisfying exchange efficiency and input
efficiency
 Achieve input efficiency by picking a point on the
production contract curve
 Equivalent to picking a point on the PPF
 To achieve output efficiency, need to pick the right point
 Allocation satisfies the output efficiency condition if,
for every pair of goods, every consumer’s MRS equals
the marginal rate of transformation
16-37
Figure 16.17: Output Efficiency
16-38
Justification for Free Markets
 Advocates of free markets argue that government
should not play a significant role in overseeing,
directing, or conducting economic activity
 Doctrine of laissez-faire holds that the government
should adopt a “hands off” approach to private
commerce
 First welfare theorem provides some support for this
position
 Says a perfectly competitive economy would produce an
efficient outcome
 Opponents have two main reservations
 Few economists describe the real economy as perfectly
competitive
 A market failure is a source of inefficiency in an imperfectly
competitive economy
 Many people express concerns that free markets can produce
inequitable outcomes
16-39
Equity and Redistribution
 First welfare theorem says that a competitive
equilibrium is Pareto efficient
 May not convince you that competitive markets are desirable
 Efficient allocations can be extremely inequitable
 Even if the competitive equilibrium is on the contract
curve, may be other points on that curve that are more
equitable
 Second welfare theorem says that every Pareto
efficient allocation is a competitive allocation for some
initial allocation of resources
 If the initial allocation of resources heavily favors certain
individuals, the equilibrium will favor them as well
 In principle, societies can use competitive markets to achieve
both efficiency and equity
 If society can redistribute the initial allocation of
resources appropriately, then competitive markets will
deliver the most equitable Pareto efficient allocation
16-40
Figure 16.20: Second Welfare
Theorem
16-41