Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Università Commerciale Luigi Bocconi Econpubblica Centre for Research on the Public Sector WORKING PAPER SERIES The Italian pension system in the European context Roberto Artoni and Alessandra Casarico Working Paper n. 75 April 2001 www.econpubblica.uni-bocconi.it The Italian pension system in the European context* Roberto Artoni Alessandra Casarico Istituto di Economia Politica Istituto di Economia Politica Università Bocconi Università Bocconi Via Gobbi 5 Via Gobbi 5 20136 Milano, Italy [email protected] 20136 Milano, Italy [email protected] This draft: April 2001 1. Introduction The aims of this work are to discuss whether there is an anomaly in the Italian pension system and, if there is, to investigate its causes and its influence on the future prospects of the system and on the debate on reform issues. In order to address these questions, we first provide an institutional and quantitative description of the main features of the current Italian pension system, highlighting the main changes from the recent past; we compare it with other European pension schemes in order to identify whether there are common/specific features; we then refer to the last projections of pension expenditure elaborated by the RGS (Ragioneria Generale dello Stato: Department of General Accounts) to show where the system is going. We finally conclude, summarising the main implications of our analysis and comparing more explicitly the UK and the Italian system, to see what lessons we can draw for the Italian pension reform debate. 2. Main institutional features of the Italian pension system Until 1992 the Italian public pension system was a defined benefit pay-as-you-go system with a very large number of funds and schemes, where contribution and benefit rules differed according both to the sector the worker belonged to (private and public sector or self-employed) and to the specific job the worker had (special provisions for railway, public utilities, air transport workers or industrial managers just to mention a few). A lump-sum transfer known as TFR (Trattamento di Fine Rapporto) and financed by a severance payment fund managed directly by employers complemented the public * Paper prepared for the Conference "The Welfare State, poverty and social exclusion in Italy and Great Britain" Certosa di Pontignano, Siena, April 6-8, 2001. 2 defined benefit pension. Income for retirement came also from means-tested benefits which provided coverage both to those who satisfied the minimum requirement on contributory periods and whose pension was below a minimum amount set by INPS (integrazione al minimo) and to those who did not fulfil the requirement but whose income satisfied the total income test (pensione sociale). The reforms in the 1990s remarkably changed the design of the Italian pension system: they tried both to adjust the traditional pay-as-you-go pillar and to introduce a private defined contribution component to provide additional coverage via the development of occupational and private pension funds. While the Amato Reform (1992) maintained the defined benefit formula to calculate benefits and promoted pension cost control and harmonisation measures, the main innovation introduced by the Dini Reform (1995) was the abandoning of the defined benefit pay-as-you-go system, where benefits depend on some formula related to the worker's earning history, and the adoption of a Notional Defined Contributions (NDC) pay-as-you-go system, where benefits depend on contributions paid during the working life, the conventional return earned on them and life expectancy at the time of retirement. The specific NDC pay-as-you-go system implemented in Italy requires wage earners to pay contributions based on a 33% fixed contribution rate until the age (after a statutory minimum which is set at 57) the individual chooses to retire and go towards paying the benefits of concurrent pensioners (this is the pay-as-you-go feature). The value of contributions is accredited the workers' notional accounts and the previous year’s account values are indexed annually with a nominal per capita GDP index. The benefit is then calculated by dividing the value on the account at the chosen time of retirement with a factor based on unisex life expectancy and a real rate of return of 1.5% calculated into the annuity. Pensions are then indexed to annual changes in prices. The introduction of a NDC pay-as-you-go scheme was accompanied by the choice of a flexible retirement age between 57 and 65 both for men and women, with the amount of the first pension increasing the closer one gets to 65; the reduction of the minimum contributory years to 5 in order to limit payroll taxes evasion -a rather widespread phenomenon in Italy- and to give occasional workers incentives to participate into the social security scheme; the removal of discretionary wage indexation of pensions which was left over by the Amato Reform and the elimination of the peculiar early retirement pension scheme for new workers. 3 Regarding the second pillar, the funds to finance the defined contribution component should come from two sources: tax favoured contributions by employers and employees and, for the largest share, the gradual channelling of contributions which have so far accrued to the separate severance payment fund known as TFR. At the time of retirement specified for the public component, the retirees are entitled to the payment of an annuity from the private funded pillar. The transition period before the system designed by the Dini reform is fully operative and involves all workers is very long (2036). In the meantime, income for retirement comes only partially from the defined contribution component while the old defined benefit pay-as-you-go system still plays a primary role together with the lump-sum transfer provided by the TFR. Income for retirement is currently provided in Italy also via means-tested benefits of two types: integrazione al minimo and assegno sociale. The former pays to those whose pension falls below the minimum set by INPS the difference between their own pension and the set amount, provided they satisfy the test on total income. This means-tested benefit will disappear once pensions will be entirely paid by the NDC system. The latter is paid to people above 65 whose total income satisfies the means-test and it provides a minimum income to those who do not have other sources of income support and it is characterised by a 100% withdrawal rate. 3. Searching for the Italian anomaly Now that we have described the main features of the Italian pension system as designed by the Dini reform and highlighted that current and future pensioners during the transition will only be mildly affected by the changes it introduced, we provide some figures on pension expenditure and its composition, trying to identify what elements have contributed most to the current pension system's stance. In 1999 the old-age function of the social protection accounts absorbed about 13% of GDP. Old-age pensions (stricto sensu) are the main component and reach 10% of GDP. Notice that one fifth of these old-age pensions is represented by the first type of meanstested benefits we have described above, that is by integrazioni al minimo which are not classified separately. Disability pensions paid to people aged 60 and above are also included in the old-age function and they represent approximately 1,3% of GDP. Meanstested benefits (pensione/assegno sociale) are of modest amount in terms of GDP (0,2%): their share is however larger if we take into account the means-tested benefits classified as 4 old-age pensions. The whole amount of the TFR is included in the old-age function, although a significant share of this benefit is paid to people who have not reached yet retirement age. This tends to increase the amount of resources which supposedly go to old people. In Figure 1 we also indicate the expenditures attributed to other functions of the social protection system, namely survivors, disability and unemployment. While the survivors function absorbs over 2% of GDP, disability and unemployment expenditures are a very small share of GDP. To understand the current stance and the prospects of the Italian social security system, we try to compare the Italian data with those of other European countries, namely Germany, France and the UK. The analysis is based on the national data provided by Eurostat (2000a) which include entries up to 1997 and by Eurostat (2000b) which presents the 1998 data and an update of the 1997 data, on which we focus. Table 1a and 1b illustrate clearly the so called Italian anomaly in the social security system. Namely, if we sum expenditures for old-age and survivors, we can rank the four European countries we are focusing on in descending order in terms of the ratio of expenditures over GDP: focusing on 1998, we find that Italy spends about 15,6% of GDP for these two functions while the values for France, Germany and the UK are respectively 12,8%, 11,9% and 11,4%. The differences in expenditures are huge if we focus on these two functions, especially if we compare Italy and the UK. Notice also that we are considering countries with similar levels of income per capita. Moreover, according to Blondell and Scarpetta (1998) the average age of transition to inactivity among older males in 1995 is very similar in Italy and Germany, slightly earlier in France and later in the UK, where males leave the labour market when they are on average 62,5, two years older than in Italy and Germany. By the same token, although women abandon the labour market earlier in all countries, their average rate of transition to inactivity reflects the same pattern observed for men, with a delayed transition to inactivity for the UK (see Table 2). Given that the average rate of transition to inactivity is very similar among continental European countries, it might play a role only in explaining differences in expenditure between the UK and Italy. But this is hardly the end of the story. If we try to single out the causes of the Italian anomaly, we could first focus on the different institutional mechanisms on which social security systems in different countries are based. The different institutional features can give rise to heterogeneity in the classification systems and therefore the definitions of pension benefits do not coincide (in 5 which case the joint analysis of the various components of the social security system can offer a better representation of the transfer to the old than old-age pensions per se). Or, at a more substantial level, they can reveal structural differences among the national social security system, which are not eliminated once we correct for classification issues, and which can generate transfers of substantially different dimensions. In order to assess the role of classification issues in determining the Italian anomaly, we first observe that the level of disability and unemployment expenditure over GDP is lower in our country than in the other three countries we are considering. If we add these two functions with expenditure for old-age and survivors, the Italian anomaly looks less alarming: the difference is reduced to 1% with respect to Germany and France and to 2,5% with respect to the UK. However, one might wonder whether, both from an institutional and an economic point of view, it is legitimate to lump together the four functions mentioned above. The OECD paper by Blondell and Scarpetta (1998) helps us to partly address the question: if we focus on the main reasons for leaving last job or business, normal retirement is the main reason for Italy (where it explains 53,4% of the cases whilst in the UK it represents only 4,8%), while dismissals, disability and illness and early retirement explain a limited number of cases (2%, 5,2% and 9,2% respectively). The opposite holds for the UK for instance, where the last three causes mentioned above represent the main reasons for abandoning job or business. (See Table 3). The above observations indicate that, if we aim at measuring the amount of resources transferred to the old generation, the simultaneous consideration of the four functions offers a better representation. Adding them up is justified by the fact that the systems seem to differ in their institutional structure, with different weights given to different portions of the social protection system and with different implicit and explicit goals given to each functions. While for a country it is enough to focus on the old-age function to measure the transfer the old generation receive, for another country the inclusion of the disability function is essential. It is worth mentioning that the overall size of the social protection system in Italy is however limited if compared with the other countries here examined (about 25% of GDP against 30% in the other countries). In Italy the social protection system is mainly financed by social contributions, which represents 15,2% of GDP, while general taxation revenues are 9,7% of GDP. In the UK, the social contributions' level is very close to the Italian one, but general taxation is higher (namely, 13,9% of GDP). In France and Germany the level of general taxation is slightly lower than in Italy but social contributions are much higher (See Table 4) 6 Eurostat data raise further problems with respect to the definition of pensions and the extension of the pension system. For instance, private funded social benefits are an important feature of the pension system in the UK while they play a very marginal role in Italy. According to the UK National Accounts (1999), if we distinguish between the two components of private funded social benefits, private pensions (which we interpret as occupational pensions) in the UK in 1997 amounted to about 24500 billions pounds corresponding to 3% of GDP and pensions by life companies were 20400 billions pounds, the 2,5% of GDP. These amounts do not seem to be entirely included in Eurostat statistics. For instance, in the Introductory Notes to Eurostat (2000a and 2000b) we read that Appropriate Personal Pension Schemes are not included. However, any comparison on transfers to old-age which (partly) omits this component seems inadequate. This is more so if we recall that the Italian TFR is entirely included in old-age pensions, also when paid to people below retirement age. One additional component which contributes to the total amount of resources devoted to old-age people in the UK is represented by other non contributory benefits like income support, social housing and tax relieves, which are granted both to elderly and to other disadvantaged people and which are not present in the Italian social protection system. Taking into account the different components of the UK social protection system which we believe go to old-age, we calculate the UK transfers to oldage in Table 5. Transfers to the retired are larger than the ones resulting from Eurostat data. Also the extension/coverage of the pension system can contribute to generate social security systems of different dimensions. For instance the coverage of self-employed workers is very different across the pension systems of the countries here examined. While Italy has a fully fledged system, in Germany the participation to the public system is voluntary and modest but compensated by the concession of fiscal rebates. We try to summarise these observations in Table 6, indicating which share of the total pension expenditure on old-age and survivors goes to private and public sector employees and to the self employed. For the UK all of the old-age and survivors benefits paid by the national insurance fund are attributed to either private or public sector employees because we are not able to identify the exact amount going to the self-employed. For the UK we also indicate the expenditure on personal pensions by life companies. Our table suggests that, indeed, the share of expenditure going to the self-employed is higher in Italy than in 7 the other countries where the comparison is feasible. However, the share of old-age and survivors pensions going to workers in the private sector is not very different across countries, while the Italian anomaly seems partly explained by the higher amount of expenditure going to central and local governments’ employees. The last issue which we believe to be relevant in cross country comparisons and which can contribute to reduce the differences between Italy and the other countries here examined is the taxation of pension benefits. Adema (1999) shows that the direct taxation of these benefits in Italy is particularly high, as one can see in Table 7. This result is confirmed by calculations based on 1999 national tax schedules for three of the four countries under analysis (See Econpubblica [2000]): as Figure 2 shows, the Italian average tax rate is systematically and significantly higher than the ones observed in the other countries. Now that we have highlighted some of the specific and some of the common features of the pension systems under analysis, what can we conclude on the Italian anomaly? Table 8 summarises the implications we derive from our analysis. The first row reports Eurostat data on old-age and survivors pensions: the Italian anomaly is fully evident. The second row is based on our reading of the national account statistics. Namely, for Germany we shift anticipated pensions from the unemployment function to old-age; for the UK we draw from Table 5. The amount of expenditure for France and Italy is basically unchanged. The differences are reduced but the Italian case still stands out. Still considering the total of old-age and survivors pension payments, we can take into account direct taxes paid on benefits: if we do this we obtain the data reported in the fourth row, where the difference between Italy and the UK and France is about 1% while it is larger between Italy and Germany. If we finally take into account the two complementary functions, that is, disability and unemployment, Germany and Italy are aligned on a lower level of expenditure over GDP than UK and France. Our conclusions are certainly influenced by our assumptions (which we nonetheless consider reasonable) and by the lack of adequate information. It is however fair to say that the international comparison of social expenditure data is not a settled matter and that, in general, it requires a serious interpretative effort. What we can safely say is that countries at the same level of development have social security systems of similar dimensions if all the functions they perform are jointly considered. 8 This potential convergence in terms of dimensions should not obscure the existence of important institutional differences. The UK is the only country with a consolidated funded portion and with an important role attributed to occupational pension schemes. In Continental Europe the public component is absolutely dominant and although, for instance, our TFR is dimensionally not so far from the UK personal pension benefits, it cannot be completely assimilated to them. If one believes that the way the social security system is structured is crucial to determine both its micro impact (because it can affect the incentives to save, to work, to invest in human capital or to insure, just to take some examples) and its macro effects (because it influences total savings, growth, risk sharing, income distribution or poverty, again just to mention a few), the result according to which countries at similar level of development spend similar shares of their GDP for social security is relevant to evaluate the Italian anomaly, but it leaves the harder issue of the appropriate model to manage income for retirement open. We go back to these issues in the conclusions. 4. The future prospects of the Italian pension system We here tackle the second main issue of our work, namely we discuss the prospects of the Italian pension system. The main question we address refers to the sustainability of our system in the long run. We focus on two interpretation of sustainability: on the one hand, we look at the amount of resources absorbed by the pension system; on the other, we focus on the adequacy of pension transfers at an individual level. To measure the former we present the macroeconomic projections on public pension expenditure (which includes means-tested benefits but excludes the TFR) over GDP formulated by the Italian RGS using its forecasting model; to capture the latter we calculate the replacement rate, that is the ratio of the first pension to the last income, for different types of workers and under different assumptions on their career. The main assumptions on which the RGS forecasts are based are summarised in Table 9 and 10. We here briefly comment on some of them. The assumption on the rate of growth of GDP is very conservative and, as we know, very crucial for the results on the dynamics of pension expenditure over GDP, especially when pensions are only indexed to prices. The participation rate is at the moment very low in Italy, if we believe official statistics, when compared with other European countries. According to the main variant of the demographic projections by ISTAT, the fertility rate increases from 1,23 to 1,45 in 9 2020 and then it remains stable. Population ageing shows up in an increase in the share of old age people of about 10% in the first half of the simulation horizon. Starting from a level of 14% in 1999, public pension expenditure over GDP is expected to rise until 2031 when it will reach its maximum value of 15,9% and then to fall sharply and to reach 13,3% of GDP at the end of the forecasting period in 2050 (See Figure 3). The ratio of average pension to labour productivity is responsible for the rise in pension expenditure during the first five years of the forecasting horizon, while the ratio of pensions to employment is the main responsible for the increase in the next ten years. The slowdown in pension expenditure in the central years of the forecasting period comes from the decline in the ratio of the average pension to average productivity caused by the gradual introduction of the NDC system. According to the RGS projections, this effect is so large that it basically offsets the rise in the ratio of pensions over employment caused by the demographic changes. In the last years of the simulation horizon, both ratios tend to decline, causing the decrease in pension expenditure over GDP. We now turn to discuss the issue of individual adequacy of retirement income. This is certainly not an absolute but a relative concept whose discussion requires a preliminary definition of the role of pensions. According to Diamond (1998), "a pension should guarantee a target income for participants during retirement. The target is generally expressed as a replacement rate that gives the ratio of real benefits to real earnings towards the end of a worker's career" . According to others (see the many works by Feldstein for instance), a pension is equivalent to mandatory savings which transfer individual resources between the working and the retirement period of an agent's life and which are remunerated at the (risky) financial market rate of return. Depending on where one stands between these two different interpretation of the role of pensions, the assessment of pension's adequacy changes. The latter is also affected by the presence of public and private components in the pension system and by the different views on their respective roles. Given these general premises, let us focus on the replacement rate that the reformed Italian system is likely to guarantee. As the amount of the pension depends on the age of retirement, on the length of the contributory period, on the average rate of growth of GDP at which individual contributions are capitalised, on the rate of increase of the individual wage and, finally, on being an employee or a self-employed, we focus on some individual profiles which can illustrate the implicit guarantees of the Italian reformed pension system. As Table 11 shows, an employee who retires at 62 after 40 years of work receives 10 a pension whose amount depends on the relationship between the individual wage growth rate and the rate of return on contributions: namely, the replacement rate is 73% of the last wage if the individual wage growth rate is the same as the rate of return on contributions (and both are set at 1,5%) and 55% of the last wage if the individual wage growth rate is higher (3% versus 1,5%). As Table 12 shows, for a self-employed, the replacement rate decreases from 44% to 33% under the same assumptions as above: the lower level of replacement rates comes from the lower level of contribution rates (20% against 33%). We now try to translate the replacement rates in pension income in absolute terms in order to understand the value of the promises our society is making to future retirees. We consider three different profiles, two for employed and one for a self-employed individual. The rate of return on contributions is set to 1,5% while the individual wage growth rate is respectively 1,5% and 3% for the employees and 3% for the self-employed. If the initial gross wage is 800 Euro (this is more or less the starting wage for people with average qualification), the final gross wages after 40 years of work are 1451 and 2609 Euro and the first gross pensions they will receive are respectively 1029, 1445 and 870 Euro. (See Table 13) Any evaluation of adequacy is, as we have already mentioned, necessarily subjective. We can however add that the above replacement rates from the public pillar should be integrated via the development of a second funded pillar based on the contributions currently financing the TFR, if the last policy efforts in this direction are successful. This integration should be particularly relevant for people in the higher wage groups. As a reference, we present in Table 14 the current Italian, German and British replacement rates for an average worker. 5. Conclusions Our analysis highlights that the anomaly in the Italian pension system is not large in quantitative terms if one consider the total transfers to old-age people in the different countries here examined. The focus on pensions which characterises the Italian social security system represents however a peculiar structural feature. This feature is associated with a relatively limited size of the overall social protection system for reasons that should be carefully analysed. The last reforms seem successful in controlling the evolution of pension expenditure in the long run, even in the presence of strong population ageing. The determination of pension benefits on the basis of contributions, the abandonment of wage indexation and 11 the introduction of an endogenous adjustment parameter to reflect demographic changes are the main responsible for the achievement of pension cost control. The lower bound of the flexible retirement age appears to be low and might not deliver a significant increase in the average retirement age with respect to the current one, if the adjustment in the amount of annuity is not perceived as too penalising: an increase in the minimum retirement age seems conceivable in the presence of improvements in life expectancy. Our analysis also points out that the reduction in pension expenditure is associated with a significant reduction in replacement rates, especially for workers with dynamic careers. The development of a second pillar should guarantee higher protection to this group. The presence of a very large public component in the pension system is a common feature of Italy and of other Continental European countries. The UK system is different from ours for the importance of occupational pensions and of the private funded component. However, the fact that the occupational pensions currently paid are of the defined benefit type reduces the differences in terms of protection that the two systems guarantee to current retirees. Nonetheless, the increase in defined contribution plans for current workers signals a switch in terms of risk-sharing between future retirees and pension funds: in the future the differences could become more relevant. Another feature which is common to Continental European social protection systems is that a relatively high level of pension is guaranteed to the whole population. On the contrary, in the UK a profitable access to occupational and personal pensions which integrate the low level (for Continental European standards) of the basic state pension is somehow limited to medium and high income groups with an almost uninterrupted working career. Defined benefit systems financed on a pay-as-you-go basis were, and probably still are, the dominant model to manage income for retirement. Although in the 1990s both OECD and middle income countries have changed in some important respects their mandatory public pension systems, the reform process is not over yet, nor is the debate on the appropriate model to manage income for retirement and on the aims public pension systems should pursue. In our opinion, the choice between alternative models should stem from the role attributed to the pension system in a specific society and it should take into account the risks different systems are subject to. Pay-as-you go systems are often associated with political, demographic and occupational risk, while funded systems seem to be characterised by investment and inflation risk (also the demographic risk can be 12 relevant for them if the pension system has to provide a target income). The superiority of a funded privatised system to a traditional public pay-as-you-go one is not uncontroversial, nor is the superiority of mixed systems, which have become rather popular as of late. Although there is no wide consensus on the ideal system to manage income for retirement, the individual opinions are very clear-cut. We believe that some further progress is necessary in theoretical models (Casarico [2000] discusses these issues in some detail) and in the availability and comparability of data in order to improve the framework of analysis and to have adequate tools to contrast different systems. This seems particularly urgent in view of the increasing degree of globalisation and, focusing on Europe, of the realisation of the EMU. References Adema W. (1996). Net Public Social Expenditure, Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional Paper n.19, OECD. Adema W. (1999). Net Social Expenditure, Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional Paper n.39, OECD. Agulnik P. (2000). Maintaning Incomes after Work: Do Compulsory Earnings-Related Pensions Make Sense, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, vol.16, n°1. Blake D. (2000). The United Kingdom: Examining the Switch from Low Public Pensions to High-Cost Private Pensions, Paper presented at the NBER – Kiel Institute Conference on “Coping with the pension Crisis – Where does Europe stand?” Boldrin M. et al. (1999). The Future of Pension Systems in Europe, Economic Policy –A European Forum, 29, October. Burtless G. (1999). Social Security Privatization and Financial Market Risk: Lessons from U.S. Financial History, Paper presented at the World Bank Conference ''New Ideas About Old Age Security'', September 14-15, Washington D.C. Casarico A. (2000). An Economic Analysis of Pension Systems and Reforms, D.Phil thesis, Nuffield College, Oxford. Department of Social Security (1999). Social Security Statistics 1999, London, Government Statistical Office. Department of Social Security (2000). Retirement Pension. Summary Statistics. Diamond P. (1998). The Economics of Social Security Reform, NBER working paper 6719, September. Diamond P. (ed.). (1999). Issues in Privatizing Social Security, MIT Press. Econpubblica (2000). Un’analisi comparata dei sistemi pensionistici europei: Italia, Francia, Germania e Regno Unito, mimeo. 13 EUROSTAT (2000a). European social statistics. Social protection 1980-1997. EUROSTAT (2000b). European social statistics. Social protection 1980-1998. Feldstein M. (1996). The Missing Piece in Policy Analysis: Social Security Reform, American Economic Review, 86, 1-14, May. Feldstein M. and Samwick A. (1998). The Transition Path in Privatizing Social Security, in Feldstein M. (ed.) (1999). Privatizing Social Security, University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Franco D. (2000). Italy: a never-ending pension reform, paper presented at NBER – Kiel Institute Conference on “Coping with the pension Crisis – Where does Europe stand?” Geanakoplos J., Mitchell O. and Zeldes S. (1998a). Would a Privatised Social Security System Really Pay a Higher Rate of Return?, Pension Research Council WP 98-6. ISTAT (1998). Il sistema pensionistico italiano: beneficiari e prestazioni, Anno 1997. ISTAT (1999). I Trattamenti Pensionistici, Anno 1998. Kalish D.W. and T. Aman (1998). Retirement Income Systems: The Reform Process across OECD Countries, Social Policy Division, OECD working paper. Ministère de l’Emploi et de la Solidaritè, Les comptes de la protection sociale 1990-1997, Paris, La documentation Francaise, 1997. Ministero del Tesoro (2000). Relazione Generale sulla Situazione Economica del Paese 1999 Ministero del Tesoro, Ragioneria Generale dello Stato, Ispettorato generale per la spesa sociale. (2000). Le tendenze di medio-lungo periodo del sistema pensionistico italiano, Temi di finanza pubblica e protezione sociale, Quaderno n°2. Office for National Statistics (2000). United Kingdom National Accounts (the Blue Book) 1999. Orszag P. and Stiglitz J. (1999). Rethinking Pension Reform: Ten Myths About Social Security Systems, Paper presented at the Conference on ''New Ideas About Old Age Security'', The World Bank, Washington D.C., September 14-15. Statistiches Jahrbuch fur die Bundesrepublik Deutschland (2000).