* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download çi̇n`de planli ekonomi̇den serbest pi̇yasa
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Transformation to a Socialist Market Economy in the Peoples’ Republic of China Seriye Sezen * Abstract: This article studies the transformation process of the Peoples’ Republic of China (PRC) from an economic regime based on “central planning” to the system called a “socialist market economy”. This process can be described as the gradual transformation of a country ruled by the Communist Party to market economy under state control. The study is carried out within the framework of economic reforms after the characteristics of the transformation and its constitutional fundamentals are given. In this context, the ownership regime, rural reform, administrative and fiscal decentralization, banking reform, state enterprise reform, modification to planning, privatization in public service and direct foreign investments are analyzed. The initial outcome attained from the study is that the transformation in the PRC should be interpreted as the response of the Communist Party of China to the dissolution of the socialist system in the Soviet Block and globalization as well as its endeavor to remain in power by maintaining its legitimacy. The second result is that this transformation is carried out via a manageable, exceptionally controlled, planned, gradual and pragmatic approach and that state is still the most powerful player of the economy despite liberalization policies. The third outcome of the study is that the said transformation involves the basic characteristics of the new public management approach. During the Cold War period, the factor that ensured the world’s security was the fear-driven balance between the US and the Soviet Union. It is probable that this balance, which deteriorated with the collapse of Soviet Union, will be struck between the US and the Peoples’ Republic of China this time on the basis of economic power. Key Words: The Peoples’ Republic of China, socialist market economy, economic reform, decentralization. The end of the 1980s witnessed the collapse of the socialist system in the Soviet Block as well as the rapid transformation of Soviet Block countries to liberal policies both in a politic and economic sense. The 1980s was also the period during which the Peoples’ Republic of China (PRC), another major socialist country, started to move towards a market economy. The distinctive feature of this * Associate Professor, Public Administration Institute for Turkey and the Middle East. [email protected] TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration, Volume 1 Issue 1 March 2007, p. 31-66. 32 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration movement in China is that China, as a socialist country, has realized a gradual transformation in its system without making any radical change to its political regime. This transformation has involved a very controlled and gradual transformation to the market economy under the leadership of the Chinese Communist Party. In order to reconcile a market economy, which is the economic system of the capitalist regime, and the socialist regime based upon the “unalterable” power of the Chinese Communist Party, the Chinese officials and academicians call this structure a “socialist market economy”. Today, the PRC is a country, which stands at the forefront and is discussed not only in relation to its population (1.3 billion) and total area (9.6 million sq km), but also with its rapid and stable economic growth, foreign capital inflow and cheap goods that command the world markets. The world is watching China’s development closely and at the same time with concern. While international economic organizations and foreign researches pay close attention to the rapid pace of change in China over the last three decades and the number of studies on different aspects of this transformation increases rapidly, the relative gap in our national academic literature is remarkable. Yet, the PRC is a very rich and interesting field for research predominantly for economists, lawyers, business administrators and public managers, as well as for researchers who study different disciplines of social sciences. This article attempts to elucidate the transformation from planned economy to socialist market economy in the Peoples’ Republic of China. However, this attempt does not cover all phases, main lines and results of the said transformation. Its aim is to give an overview and provide characteristics of the transformation and to analyze the main economic reforms and their methods. While the basic method of the study is literature analysis, the writer also makes use of the discussions she had during her visits to China in 1999, 2000 and 2006, two for study and one for academic purposes, as well as her observations. Characteristics of Transformation The Peoples’ Republic of China (PRC) is a multinational and unitary state, which has been governed by the Communist Party of China since 1949. These regions,1 where an intense population of ethnic communities lives and, which are accepted as the complementary components of the PRC, are autonomous. Hong Kong and Macao, 1 Xingyang, Inner Mongolia, Tibet, Guangxi Zhuang, Ningxia Hui autonomous regions. Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 33 both special administrative regions of China that reverted to the PRC’s rule in 1990s, are governed autonomously under the transfer of sovereignty agreements signed with the United Kingdom and Portugal. With more than 70 million members, the Chinese Communist Party, which was established in 1921, is the sole party in power. The 1982 Constitution defines the Peoples’ Republic of China as a socialist state under “the peoples’ democratic dictatorship” led by the working class and based on the alliance of workers and peasants. Today, the Constitution still preserves the principle of devotion to MarxismLeninism and Mao Tse-tung’s thought, except that Deng Xiaoping’s Theory, the pioneer of reforms, was appended to these principles of devotion in the1990s. The increasingly deepening reforms in PRC, which were initiated in 1978 and continued for almost 30 years, are not different from new liberal policies implemented in other developed and developing countries with respect to various aspects. These policies, which can be described as the transformation of functional, organizational and operational fundamentals of the state on the basis of privatization, localization and new public management, have become increasingly widespread in the 1990s and 2000s. Though the adopted policies are, in essence, in line with this transformation, the China experience has typical characteristics as to the process and functioning of reforms and the role of state in this process. These characteristics and the components of the reform process can be summarized as follows: 1. First of All Economic Reform: Unlike other socialist countries, transformation in the PRC embraces the liberalization in the economy, whereas it basically discards political liberalization. The necessity of implementing political reform voiced by the leaders of the Chinese Communist Party has never gone beyond words. The Communist Party has carried out the reform process in China, where the political regime is meticulously maintained. This has enabled the implementation of the reforms without being interrupted by political changes. Besides, the Chinese Communist Party’s (CPC) response to the economic development and globalization within the framework of neoliberal policies has secured the Party’s legitimacy, thus allowing it to remain in power. Therefore, the change, which China has undergone during almost the last 30 years and the country’s efforts to achieve economic development, should, at the same time, be considered endeavors to find ways of maintaining its power. The rapid pace of economic transformation and the abandonment of central planning in the early 1990s and the official announcement of the “socialist market economy” as the new economic policy of the country during 34 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration the period that followed the collapse of the socialist regime in the Soviet Union and Eastern Block countries should be evaluated within this context. During this process, the CCP has also undergone transformation to some extent, though it has maintained its power monopoly. The major shift is seen in the Party’s ideology. The Party has moved from dogmatic emphasis on the Maoist version of Marxism-Leninism to a pragmatic, market-oriented approach. Although the rhetoric of socialism has been retained (e.g., the recent emphasis on the "socialist market economy"), the staunch anti-market, anti-private initiative, anti-private gain focus has been removed (Montinola ao., 1995: 3). It is alleged that blurring the distinction between socialism and capitalism and giving the utmost priority to economic development, today the CCP is no more than ‘the Chinese Economic Development Party”, though it still carries on the utterance of socialism (Yabuki and Harner, 1999: 33).2 The CCP’s member profile has changed parallel to the shift in ideology. In the mid 50s, when farmers constituted 60% of party members, the values such as class struggle, public ownership, and equality were of great importance to get party membership. In the 1990s and the following years, during which the nature of the Party’s values have changed, the emphasis in admission to membership started to be placed on the economic development, rich people and confidence in market powers (Burns, 1999: 31). In line with this development, an increasing number of businessmen started to become the party member. While the proportion of the CCP members among businessmen was 13% in 1993, the said rate rose to nearly 20% in 2000 (Zheng, 2004: 74 quoted from Qiang, 2001: 26). Relations between the business world and the CCP are not one-sided. During the reform process, the party cadres and government officials were allowed and even encouraged to go into business. It is asserted that this development was the outcome of “allowing the capitalists to join the Party” rather than “allowing the party members to be capitalist” (Hui, 2005: 99). This attitude was aimed at breaking down likely resistance against radical economic reforms. For instance, in 1993 and 1995, the proportion of the Party cadres and government officials among those 2 According to some evaluations, CCP is a social democratic party. However, Hui (2005: 100), who emphasizes that social democratic parties rely on workers’ unions in developed countries and that primary objective of these parties is to develop parliamentary democracy, says that CCP neither attempts to establish parliamentary democracy, nor does it move wealth province forward. Hui also claims that the political structure is not shifting to democracy, but oligarchy. Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 35 who built up business is 36% and 24%, respectively. 3 This development provided an opportunity to the Party and government officials to exercise public powers for personal economic interests (Zheng, 2004: 70-71). In summary, during the reform process, while organic ties between state enterprises and the Party were broken, similar organic ties were established between the Party and the private sector. 2. Gradual approach rather than shock therapy approach: Another characteristic of the transformation in China is the progressive transformation to a market economy from a planned economy with a cautious approach. Concerns to preserve the national integrity and not to lead to social chaos played a significant role in the choice of this approach. In this context, the Chinese experience differs from the rapid transformation policy pursued both by Russia and Eastern Block countries. 3. Direction of Reform; rural-to-urban: The first intervention points of reforms were rural areas. This choice aimed to preserve political stability and national integrity and not to cause social chaos. The other reasons for this preference were the significance of the rural population and rural economy specific to the country and the strategic approach by which the transformation would be initiated from the weakest link of the planned economy. In other words, rather than “biting the hardest bone”, which was under the strict control of the planned economy, the weakest, therefore easily intervenable part of the system was targeted (Zhaomu, 2000: 451). In the second stage, reforms were shifted to urban from rural by the method of “surrounding cities from country” (Zhaomu, 2000: 446). The progress of the reform in urban areas was, again, two-staged. Giving priority to the coastal cities located in the east of the country, these cities were transformed into almost a development base via the established special economic zones. 4. Pragmatism: In a socialist regime, how can the Chinese experience, which has built the market economy by means of this regime, be put on a theoretical basis?4 Some of the Chinese academicians and researchers, who attempt to bring a theoretical explanation to the socialist market economy regard the “socialist market economy” itself as a theory and accept Deng Xiaoping - the pioneer of the reforms - as the creator of this theory. The concept on which the theory is based is 3 4 These rates rise to 40 % and 50 % at province or city level. See. (Hui, 2005: 99). According to Amin (2005: 129), a fundamental criterion that distinguishes market socialism from pure capitalism is the ongoing public ownership in major sectors. Social re-distribution implementations for the elimination of inequalities that accompany the emergence of the market can be listed among the differences. 36 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration pragmatism. According to Deng Xiaping, “it does not matter what color the cat is, so long as it catches the mouse” (Wong, 2003: 127); “the cat, which catches the mouse is a good cat and the method that boosts production is a good method” (Yabuki and Harner, 1999: 28). According to Deng, who considers the reforms implemented “to emancipate the mind and seek truth from facts”, socialism can, at the same time, improve the market economy, since the basic differences between socialism and capitalism are not “plan” or “market”. While capitalism has its own planning, a planned economy is not equal to socialism. Likewise, a market economy is not identical with capitalism. Both plan and market are economic measures and factors. Socialism has the power and ability to adopt and improve market economy (Shaopeng, 2000: 4). Accordingly, as mentioned before, Deng Xiaoping’s theory was put into the constitution, as the thought the country is loyal to. 5. Administrative reform based on economic reforms: Economic reforms were followed by administrative reforms in 1980s and public personnel reform in 1990s and 2000s within the framework of administrative reform, central government institutions, and chiefly the institutions responsible for economic management were restructured and the number of these institutions was reduced via mergers or abolitions. Public personnel reform, the Law on Civil Servants, which was initiated in the 1990s and whose last step was put into force in 2006, was seeking a new personnel system required by economic and administrative reforms need as well as new human force model. While the economic model was transformed from a central and rigid planned economy into the market economy, a public personnel regime, which is based on the former economic model, will be rendered consistent with the new economic model. 6. Membership to financial institutions of the capitalist system: The Peoples’ Republic of China has been a member of United Nations since 1971 and is one of five permanent members of the Security Council with veto power. Immediately after adopting the “open door” policy at the end of the 1970s, the PRC re-became a member of World Bank, of which it had been one of the founding members. It also became a member of International Monetary Fund (IMF) in 1980 and started to get financial and technical assistance from both institutions. Besides the project investment and technical assistance, the World Bank, which started its activities in the PRC in 1982, played an important role in the establishment of reform policies via researches and counseling (World Bank, 2004: 55). In 1981, China Investment Bank was founded for the audit of payment of project funds extended Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 37 by the World Bank (Zheng, 2004: 121). Between 1981 and 2002, the Bank gave a total of US$ 36 billion loans to China in order to support more than 240 projects (World Bank, 2004: 113). PRC is the biggest borrowing country from the World Bank. China is also the second biggest borrower from International Development Association, part of the World Bank group. Nevertheless, loans extended by World Bank constitute only a small portion of China’s resource inflow (in the early 1990s, 0.6 % of GDP at the most) (World Bank, 2004: 31). It should be underlined that China’s relations with both World Bank and IMF are quite different from the relations of the said institutions with Turkey. The World Bank itself stresses that its relations with China are not founded on the basis of conditions, but mutual “respect” and “equality” (World Bank, 2004: 50). Unlike other developing countries, China’s relations with IMF give a similar portrait (Kornberg and Faust, 2005: 228). Following nearly 15 years of negotiations, PRC has become a full member of the World Trade Organization (WTO) in 2001. After rejecting the membership proposal in 1971, China sought to activate its full membership in the 1980s and got the observer status in the WTO 5 in 1982 (Kornberg and Faust, 2005: 234). Membership of the WTO is a significant step towards integrating into to the capitalist system. The reason is that the PRC has made a commitment to cut the tariffs imposed on agricultural and industrial products, to enhance the transparency in trade and investment regimes, to implement a countrywide common trade policy, to open services sectors to competition in addition to eliminating subsidies, to ease restrictions applicable to foreign investors and to remove them in the course of time. At the same time, this membership has allowed the government to overcome internal obstacles to further deepening of liberal reforms (Adhikari and Yang, 2002). 7. Openness to knowledge and learning and benefiting from experiences: Another characteristic of the reform process is the keen in- terest showed in the experiences of other countries, particularly of developing countries, and drawing lessons from these experiences. In this context, the emphasis given to China’s role as “knowledge bank” by the World Bank is very sensible (World Bank, 2004: 49). With the adoption of the open door policy, besides bilateral and multilateral relations at national level, the PRC attaches special importance to establishing relations with other countries via public institutions and learning the experiences of them. Openness to learning other coun5 It was then called General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade. 38 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration tries’ experiences does not connote one-to-one conveyance of these experiences. Economic, social, geographical and cultural conditions are taken into consideration and the policies under consideration are implemented by adapting them to their own conditions.6 Constitutional Fundamentals of Transformation It is possible to monitor the stages of transformation from planned economy to a socialist market economy in China via constitutional amendments. Almost all articles of the 1954 Constitution were amended by the 1982 Constitution, which was drawn up in order to meet new political and economic requirements and 32 new articles were added (Zheng, 2004: 80). To date, the 1982 Constitution has been amended four times in 1988, 1993, 1999 and 2004. 7 The most frequently amended article is Article 11 that governs state-economy relations. The said article was amended in every constitutional change. Determining power of constitutional changes, which reflect the projections of economic transformation, is the Chinese Communist Party. National Peoples’ Congress, the legislative body, has effected the constitutional changes in accordance with the decisions made at the Party Congress. For instance, at the 13 th Party Congress held in 1987, the need for supporting the development of the private sector to the complement to public sector growth was accepted and it took place in the 1988 constitutional change. At the 14th Party Congress held in 1992, the socialist market economy was accepted and this concept was introduced to the Constitution in the 1993 amendments. In the 15th Party Congress in 1997, private enterprises were officially 6 7 For example, the Chinese Ministry of Personnel (CMP) interruptedly maintains its mutual relations with many countries, including Turkey, and even with various institutions of these countries (in Turkey, the cooperation with CMP was first established by TODAİE in the early 1990s. Today, besides TODAİE, CMP is also in cooperation with The State Personnel Department). While the CMP conveys its system to the delegations that come from these countries every year, the delegations sent by the CMP have the opportunity of getting information about the personnel regimes of the countries they have visited. The keen interest of the members of the Chinese delegations in the system of each country they have been visiting is remarkable. Taking the costs of these mutual visits into account, the financial resource used for such visits are impressive. Moreover, during the preparation process of Civil Servants Law, which took four years and, was put into effect in 2006, the personnel laws of a numerous countries, including Turkey’s Civil Servants Law No.657, was analyzed and the CMP officials are informed of the draft on new personnel law in Turkey. The source for full text of the Constitution and the 1988, 1993 and 1999 amendments: Constitution of the People’s Republic of China, Fourth Edition, Foreign Languages Press, Beijing 1999; the source for the 2004 amendments: www.npc.gov.cn/zgrdw/english/constitution/constToDetail.jsp? id=2004 Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 39 legitimized as a significant element of the socialist market economy and this was reflected in the constitution by he amendments of 1999 (Wong, 2003: 129). Major constitutional changes, which are significant with respect to the economic regulations, can be summarized as follows: The 1988 Amendments: Article 11 of the1982 Constitution defined the individual economy of urban and rural working people operated within the limits prescribed by law, as the complement to the socialist public economy and governed that the state would protect the lawful rights and interests of the individual economy. Moreover, the article stipulated that the state would guide, help and supervise the individual economy by exercising administrative control. In the 1988 amendments, a new paragraph was introduced to Article 11, which read that the state would permit the private sector of the economy to exist and develop within the limits prescribed by law. The amendment to the Article also defined the private sector of the economy a complement to the socialist public economy. The state would protect the lawful rights and interests of the private sector of the economy, and would exercise guidance, supervision and control over the private sector of the economy The second amendment to the 1988 Constitution was related to land utilization. The Constitution governed that land in the cities was owned by the state, while land in the rural and suburban areas was owned by collectives except for those portions that belonged to the state. The Constitution also stipulated that no organization or individual might appropriate, buy, sell or lease land, or unlawfully transfer land in other ways. The 1988 amendment allowed the transfer of the right to use land. The 1993 Amendments: With the annexes made to the preamble of the Constitution, it was emphasized that state was in the first stage of socialism and that the people of China would continue to be loyal to the peoples’ democratic dictatorship and socialist path. It was also underlined that the people of China would carry on supporting the reforms and openness to the outside world. The highlights of the amendments of 1993 were the introduction of the term “socialist market economy” to the Constitution and the constitutional announcement of transformation from a planned economy to a socialist market economy. In line with this preference, the provisions related to the role and binding nature of plans in the economy were repealed and the regulatory and supervisory role of the state was brought into the foreground. 40 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration Article 15 of the Constitution, which governed that “The state practices planned economy on the basis of socialist public ownership. Disturbance of socioeconomic order or disruption of the state economic plan by an organization or individual is prohibited", was amended to "The state practices socialist market economy. The state shall enhance economic legislation and improve macro-control of the economy. The state shall, in accordance with the law, prohibit disturbance of the socioeconomic order by any organization or individual.” Articles 16 and 17 that govern the administrative principles of state and collective enterprises were amended and the binding emphasis on the unified leadership by the state and full fulfillment of state plans during the decision-making process was repealed. The 1999 Amendments: In 1999, the regulations in Article 11 relating to the individual economic enterprises and the private sector economy were amended and a new concept “non-public economy” was introduced to the Constitution. Non-public economy, which comprises individual and private sectors prescribed by law, is major component of the state’s socialist market economy. The presentation of the private sector, which was described as a complement to the socialist market economy, as major complement of the socialist market economy, is of great importance. The 2004 Amendments: In 2004, with the amendment to Article 11, the encouragement and support of the non-public sector was defined as a state task. Moreover, it was specified that the lawful property of Chinese people was inviolable. Nevertheless, the state may, in the public interest and in accordance with law, expropriate or requisition private property for its use and shall make compensation for the private property expropriated or requisitioned (Article 13). Besides, the state is entrusted with establishing a social security system consistent with economic development level (Article 14). Major Steps Towards Transformation In the core of the transformation process in the PRC lays the change in the social production system. In this context, it will be helpful to put emphasis on state and local enterprises - the fundamental economic units of a socialist regime - and land ownership regime, which is the economic factor of rural production. Before discussing the reforms affected in this field, it will be useful to mention the ownership structure of land and economic units. Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 41 Land and enterprises are divided into two groups with respect to ownership state-owned and collectively owned. State ownership denotes that the property is owned by all Chinese citizens. In collectively owned property, the owner of the property is a small community with specific limits, which is accepted as collective. In practice, the citizens, whether as a whole or as small collectives, did not have three rights (sale, management and earning residual income) arising from ownership. De facto owners of land and enterprises at local level were local governments.8 However, the administrative units, the owner of property, did not have all the rights on the said property. For example, local administrations could not sell the property in their possession. They had merely limited rights related to the management of the property. Central planning dictated the limits of these rights. Furthermore, the residual income yielded (profit) belonged not to the property owner, but the central management. Neither the production team, nor the producer/farmer had the right to detain the management or residual income. Similarly, local governments lacked the right to keep revenues generated within their locality and the right to decide how this revenue would be used. Provincial and county governments, like state-owned factories, submitted their profits upward and received a budget allocation from the upper levels to cover set operating expenses. (Oi, 1999a: 19). Rural Reform: In China, where nearly 800-900 million of the population lives in rural places, countryside assume great importance with respect to both their population and production unit. As mentioned before, economic reforms had been initiated in rural areas in the early 1970s. In this context, the most radical transformation has been made in rural production form. The system established in the 1950s, by which land was owned by the collectives, was revoked in the 1980s. It was replaced by the “household production responsibility system” that was based on a profit-making production by the families by which they sold the remaining products after deducting the state’s share. However, the said transformation in rural production was not a consequence of the central government’s efforts. This system9, “Down to the level of county, governments had under their jurisdiction (and therefore ‘owned’) both state and collective enterprises. Below the county, communes and brigades had collectively owned enterprises within their respective jurisdictions. Production teams, subordinate to brigades, were the legal owners of the agricultural land and the harvest produced on thet land, as well as of any team-level enterprises.” (Oi, 1999a: 18-19). 9 Eighteen farmers from poor Xiaogang village of Anhui Province decided to share the land among each other, which they collectively cultivated. They would sell or exchange the excess products they had produced after paying the grain tax to the prov8 42 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration which was, at the beginning, conducted on the basis of a secret agreement made by a group of farmers, became widespread and was overlooked at first by the local administration and then the central government. Though the central government tried to restrict this system to poor regions, it was obliged to legalize it in 1981 upon its actual widespreadness (Lin, 1994: 41-42). The system was based on the leasing of land from collectives by families (OECD, 2005: 2). Still being a collective property, land is divided into parcels and then it is allocated to villagers for cultivation on long-term contracts (usually 30 years). Producers sell a portion of their products to the state institutions at a low price. They sell the remaining products to the market at a higher price. At the beginning, this system generated a rapid growth in agricultural productivity and rural income, leading to a quick increase in county and village enterprises (Wong, 2003: 127). [Though villagers can cultivate or rent these lands against a specific fee payable to the village administration payment. But, they cannot provide collateral for credit or to sell the lands] (OECD, 2005: 3; The Economist, 25-31 March 2006: 3; Oi, 1999: 56). Nevertheless, the rapid rate of increase could not be maintained in the following period. Another development in the reform process concerning the rural labor force is the exemption of population movement from state control. Under the hukou system in China, persons who wished to migrate to another place of residence had to receive permission from state officials. And this permission was not granted easily in order to prevent population mobility from rural to urban, mainly to big cities. This application was gradually loosened in the1980s and was entirely annulled in the 1990s (Rong, 2003: 239; Oi, 1999: 58). Administrative and Financial Decentralization: One of the characteristics of the process of transformation from planned economy to socialist market economy in PRC is the “decentralization”. In fact, today China is accepted as one of the most decentralized countries in the world (The Economist, 25-31 March 2006: 8). In PRC, local governments10 should not only be considered administrative units, but ince. So, they made a secret agreement among each other in December 1978. This system increased the production in a short time. Due to the fact that household responsibility system has not initiated by the government, but the villagers in an unofficial manner, it is widely accepted that the start of market economy in PRC was given by farmers (Fishman, 2005: 47-48). Today, the contract signed by the farmers with their fingerprints - taking the risk of jail, even death sentence – is on display in the Museum of Chinese Revolution Museum in Beijing. See. (Wu, 2005: 110-111). 10 Local governments are the units that constitute the administrative levels of PRC. Provinces, autonomous regions and the municipalities, which are under the cen- Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 43 also economic units. Today, the share of local government expenditures in total government expenditures is 70 %, while local government revenues constitute almost half of government revenues (Caufield, 2006: 257, quoted from China Statistical Yearbook, 2003). These local administrations are accountable for “industrialization of rural areas and their accord to national market” (Caulfield, 2006: 257). One of the basic functions of local governments is to run local state enterprises. While only large-scale state enterprises are managed by central government, small and medium scale enterprises, which comprise the majority of enterprises11, is administered by local governments. Considering the fact that in 1993, the numerical, employment and industrial production shares of small and medium scale enterprises among nearly 300.000 state enterprises were 95 %, 57 % and %43 (Cao et.al., 1999: 109), respectively, the role of local governments both in the national economy and the reform process can be better comprehended. In fact, the PRC is not unfamiliar to the decentralization process. The difference of the post-1980 decentralization from the previous ones is the presence of financial incentives and its enhanced powers on its own economic activities. Besides current decentralization, which is based on the confidence in market mechanism, allows openness to international markets (Montinola et.al., 1995: 10). Local enterprises constitute the spirit of the decentralization movement in the economic reform process. In this context, the basic policy in implementation is to improve local economy and to leave the initiative to find out the related techniques and methods to local governments. In the 1980s, the priority was given to the administrative decentralization and enterprises were empowered with respect to the production, pricing, organization and employment. Moreover, in order to ensure the operation of enterprises in compliance with the market conditions and to enhance their administrative effectiveness, performance evaluation system was put into effect. In 1990s, the ownership structure of enterprises were started to change (Caulfield, 2006: 260, 262). By Corporate Law, which was enacted in 1993, individuals were allowed to own limited liability corporations (OECD, 2005a: 2). In the early 1990s, the privatization process of state started. During privatization, methods such as the direct sale of enterprises to domestic or foreign investors/companies, or transforming some tralgovernmnet, take place at the first step of this level. These are divided into subadministrative units among each other. 11 Telecommunication, railway transportation, airlines, banks and, enterprises that render services in the fields such as oil and petrochemicals. (Cao et.al., 1999: 109). 44 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration enterprises into limited companies, or the sale of majority shares to the employees, were used (Cao et.al., 1999: 110). Decentralization was not limited to state enterprises. Local governments were authorized extensively for the management of special economic zones, withdrawal of foreign capital and price liberalization. For instance, among total foreign investments, the ratio of those under the provincial administration, which was 35 % in 1985, rose to 68 % in 1992 (Montinola ao., 1995: 11). Pre-Reform Financial System: Another field, which was subject to centralization, was financial administration and it was loosely related to the privatization of local enterprises. In fact, pre-reform financial system was not based on a strict centralization. It was decentralized to a certain extent. Though the financial power was exercised by the central government, financial liabilities and resources were distributed among local governments. The system was called “unified leadership, level-by-level management”. The concept of unified leadership denoted that expenditure budgets of provinces were drawn up by the central governments, while the provincial governments were granted little autonomy with regard to this issue. “Level-by-level management meant that the profits of enterprises run by central ministries went to the central government, and the profits of locally run enterprises went to local governments.” Local governments, whose revenues were realized above their expenses, transferred surplus revenues to the central government. Otherwise, they got assistance from the central government (Shirk, 1993: 155).12 One of the primary functions of local governments in the Mao period, during which a tax organization did not exist at the national level, was to collect tax on behalf of the central government. The entire sum of revenues was accrued in the name of the central government (Caulfield, 2006: 260). Financial Decentralization: During the reform process, the first step towards financial decentralization was made in the 1980s and the old system called “eating from large saucepan” was reformed into the new system called “eating in separate kitchens”. In the 1980s, the central government started to distribute financial revenues among the administrations. Under this system, the central government shared total revenues with the provinces in accordance with an agreement made beforehand. Similar contracts were signed between Shirk (1993: 155) says that since central government-affiliated enterprises predominate in heavy industry, where profit ratio was low, and local government enterprises outweigh in light industry that has a high profit ratio, most provinces sent surplus revenues to the central government. 12 Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 45 provinces and substate units (Zheng, 2004: 153). These contracts demonstrated the amount of profits from taxes collected in that region to be sent to the higher unit and the amount, which would be retained by the sub-administrative unit that had generated the revenues. The said system, by which the terms and conditions of contract were set on the basis of bargain between the province officials and the Ministry of Finance, were applied in a flexible manner on different terms and conditions for different regions. 13 The system, which was applied until 1994, increased the fiscal power and resources of provinces as well as the autonomy of provinces on their budgets since the central government would not impose any financial targets any more. However, at the same time, provinces would liable for their own budgets from now on due to the fact that the central government would no longer send assistance to them (Shirk, 1993: 166). With the tax reform enforced in 1994, a clear distinction was made between national and local taxes. National and local tax offices were founded and value added tax (VAT) came into effect (Cao et.al., 1999: 116). Moreover, in order to simplify the system, the number of taxes was reduced to 18 from 32 (Caulfield, 2006: 261). The central government was basically accountable for national defense, foreign relations and the expenditures relating to the management of central government institutions, while local governments were liable for the expenditures of their institutions as well as the economic and social development expenditures in their region. Taxes were divided into three groups: central government taxes, local government taxes and taxes shared between the central and local governments .14 Central The system involved five different categories. For instance, in Guandong and Fujian provinces, where the central government increased its efforts towards foreign investments, almost entire income resources were retained by provinces. Municipalities of Beijing, Tianjin and Shanghai, which took lion’s share, were subject to more restricted application. Every year, they would give a certain percentage of their total revenues to the central government and these ratios were reviewed on annual basis. Meanwhile, the “sharing of certain revenues” system was implemented for 16 provinces. The “sharing of certain revenues” system applicable to autonomous regions, which used to get assistance from the central government in order to close their chronic deficits, put into practice along with subsidy, which was fixed for five years to be increased by 10 percent every year (Shirk, 1993: 167-168). 14 Among central government taxes are customs taxes, consumption tax, income taxes of central government-affiliated enterprises, operation tax, profits paid by central government enterprises, province maintenance tax, profits paid by various banks and insurance companies and vehicle purchase tax. A portion of tax revenues of local government consists of profits transferred from local enterprises, land utilization tax, housing ownership tax, farm land occupation tax, duty tax, agriculture tax, land ap13 46 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration government taxes were those necessary for to protect national interests, while the taxes shared was directly related to the economic development. Nevertheless, the central government transferred a portion of tax revenues to local governments as to the amount of VAT and consumption tax at local level. As regards the organization of tax management, taxes shared with the central government were collected by national tax offices and local taxes by, local tax offices (http: //www.mof.gov.cn). In addition to these regulations, with the Budget Law, which was enacted in 1995, strict measures were introduced to prevent both the central government and local governments producing deficit. Among these measures were: the prohibition of the central government from withdrawing excess money from the Central Bank and the coverage of its deficit from current account, the stipulation of drawing up balanced budget by local governments at every level and the enforcement of strict rules for bond issue in order to restrict the local government borrowing from the financial market (Cao et.al., 1999: 117). Another restriction imposed on local governments was related to bank loans. Local governments were influential in allocation and repayment of loans via the Central Bank and specialized banks. 15 The reason was that local bank branches were under the supervision of both the Central Bank and local government (Montinola et.al, 1995: 15). After 1994, binary supervision of the local branches of the Central Bank was abolished and their power to allocate loan allocation was annulled (Cao et.al., 1999: 117 quoted from Xie, 1996). In summary, considering simultaneously the regulations enacted in financial and banking sectors, the decentralization in China can be regarded as bringing of new public management approach to life with its major elements, because local governments are being excluded from the “safeguard” of the central government to a great extent and they are expected to achieve local development and to solve their own problems. While the system operated in favor of regions having the capacity of attracting investments, some of the local governments in poor regions came to the point where they could not pay the salaries of their employees. Financial problems compelled local govern- preciation tax. The most important tax item, which is shared between the central government and local administrations, is VAT, 75 % of which is transferred to the central government (http: //www.mof.gov.cn). 15 Before 1994, 70 % of credits extended to state banks by the Central Bank were provided by local branches of the Bank (Cao ao. 1999: 117). Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 47 ments to privatize local enterprises,16 to employ private sector more and more in rendering public services and to transfer local land to investors at very low cost and to sell it to real estate agents. Comprehensive decentralization in the PRC is called “ de facto federalism” (Orban et.al., 2003: 237 quoted from Zheng, 2000: 217), or “Chinese style federalism” due to the fact that it somewhat establishes a foundation for market-preserving federalism (Montinola et.al., 1995; Cao et.al., 1999). According to this opinion, “market-preserving federalism” necessitates the following conditions as regards the distribution of power and responsibility among different administration levels: - There is a hierarchy among the governments each of which the scope of authority has been circumscribed. Each government is autonomous within its scope of authority. - Sub-national governments are authorized on their local economies at the first degree. - National government is entitled to exercise control over common market at nationwide and to ensure the mobility of goods and factors across sub-government jurisdictions. - Revenue sharing among administrations is limited and borrowing by administrations is constrained so that all administrations face hard budget constraints. - The distribution of power and responsibility was institutionalized in order to prevent any kind of change as a result of pressures from national government or sub-national governments (Montionola et.al., 1995: 5).17 Citing localization, fiscal decentralization and tight budgetary restrictions as examples, writers assert that though partially, the stateTherefore, it is pointed out that the privatization experience of the PRC and the experiences of Eastern European countries and former Soviet Union s (?) display differences as regards the factors that haves led to privatization. This opinion asserts that while province enterprises in the PRC were compelled towards privatization, the privatization in Eastern Europe and former Soviet Union was used for aggravating budgetary restrictions on enterprises (Cao et.al., 1999: 106). 17 The economic outcomes of market preserving federalism are as follows: It led to competition among administrations. The production factors of competition such as labor and capital were expanded, leading the administrations to set up an appealing environment to attract production factors. Local governments directed to a rational fiscal management due to tight budgetary restrictions. A political ground was established for markets because of absence of political interventions that deteriorated the operation of market due to the deactivation of central government (Montionola et.al., 1995: 8). 16 48 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration ments relating to the existence of market-preserving federalism in the PRC were proved. In the meantime, Cao et.al. maintains that the Chinese style federalism establishes an economic and political basis for, again, a Chinese style privatization. Competitive pressures from the private sector, accompanied by tight budgetary restrictions, imposed strong financial pressures lots of local administrations to solve the problems of state enterprises, thus pushing them towards privatization (1999: 123). In my opinion, bearing in mind the unitary structure of the Peoples of Republic of China and centralized political authority, defining the decentralization in China as “federalism” is a quite “free” evaluation, which is open to debate. Furthermore, taking into account the country’s political regime and the Chinese Communist Party’s political sovereignty, evaluating local government elements separately, despite all powers delegated to them, and the central government stands out as a different problem. The reason is that the delegation of power from central government to local governments does not change the origin of power. Those who exercise these powers at local level are, again, leading party officials.18 In the meantime, I had mentioned before that reforms aimed at legitimizing the CCP power and preventing the demand for political change. As a matter of fact, according to Shirk, who calls this process as the “playing with provinces’ strategy of the Party, the central officials of the Party retain all official power. Yet, they delegate some of these powers to subadministrations in order to enhance the consistency of incentives with each other, to avoid being the sole accountable body and to gain political support. The writer also stresses that fiscal decentralization offered the central politicians the opportunity for gaining the gratitude and political support of province officials (1993: 150). Banking Reform: Prior to the reforms, “China’s banking system was characterized by its singularity and administrative features” Nevertheless, it is clear that the qualification “federalism” was accepted among academicians. For instance, a study, in which the Chinese decentralization is qualified as “fluid federalism”, compares the PRC, the USA and Federal Germany with respect to the management of productive enterprises, regulation of the economy, trade and commerce, financial relations, monetary policy and labor mobility. The study concludes that the decentralization in China is more advanced compared to two federal states. It is provinced in the study, which is based on the question “Are there lessons derivable from the Chinese experience for all levels of managers in Federal Germany, the USA and other countries?” that in the USA, federal government is mostly regarded as the body, which is primarily accountable for national economy, whereas in China, people generally believe that not central government, but local governments are primarily responsible for the economic dynamism of their region (Orban et.al., 2003). 18 Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 49 (Shanguan, 1998: 324). The People’s Bank of China (PBC) was the sole authority to perform all banking activities. The PBC, which was founded in 1948, had not only assumed the role of central bank as a national state bank, but also carried out other banking activities (savings account, non-agriculture loans, etc.). The Bank, which was organized in the county parallel to the state’s administrative division, had branches and representative offices in factories and mines and savings units in all kinds of enterprises and public organizations (Whitaker and Shinn, 1972: 564-566). There were two other banks called the Bank of China and Joint State-Private Bank affiliated to the Bank, which was under direct control of central government. These two banks were assigned with special transactions. While the Bank of China conducted foreign exchange and foreign trade transactions, Joint State-Private Bank, which was founded in 1952 in Shanghai following the merger of private banks, accepted savings deposits exclusively. Being under the supervision of the State Council, the activities of the Agricultural Bank of China, which was established in 1963, were related to the agriculture sector. The bank was assigned with making payments in certain fields such as banking, agriculture, forestry, and irrigation in compliance with the plans, budget and policies on behalf of state (Whitaker and Shinn, 1972: 566-567). In 1983, the central banking system was established and the PBC was restricted with the role of the central bank. The bank would no longer assume the functions of specialized and commercial banks. Starting from the end of the 1970s, specialized banks of the state were restructured and transformed into commercial banks. Banks were granted administrative autonomy, rendering them accountable for their profits and losses. It was aimed to increase the profits of banks, except the Agricultural Bank of China, via reducing their expenses (Lixin, 2000: 421-422). In 1979, Long-Term Credit Bank of Japan opened a branch in Beijing as the first financial institution in China (Lixin, 2000: 425). In the 1980s, a few foreign financial institutions were allowed to open branches only in private economic fields, while Shanghai became the first coastal city to open to foreign banks in 1990. As of 1999, both transactional and geographical restrictions on foreign banks were significantly loosened (Zheng, 2004: 123). Today, there are three types of public bank. The first one is the Peoples’ Bank of China, which act as a central bank. The second one is a non-profit development bank, which are trusted with implementing special fiscal policies. For example, State Development Banks provide loans to basic industries such as steel and oil and developing indus- 50 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration tries such as automotive or computer. The third one is commercial banks19 (Orban et.al., 2003: 247-248). In the PRC, both foreign and domestic private capital enters into the banking sector through various ways. For example in 2005, the shares of foreigners and private capital in 11 national joint stock commercial banks were 14.33 % and 12.07, respectively. While the share of state in these banks decreased in the 2002-2005 period, the shares of domestic and foreign capital expanded (http: //www.cbrc.gov.cn). The PRC has assured the World Trade Organization that it would eliminate the restrictions on the entry and operation of foreign banks in the country. Besides, as a result of membership to the WTO, the banking regulation and supervision duties of Peoples’ Bank of China were delegated to a regulatory institution, which was established to fulfill these duties (Hou and Jianying, 2006: 1-2). The Chinese Banking Regulatory Commission, which was established by the Chinese Banking and Supervision Law enforced in 2004, exercises all powers relating to make regulations, permissions, supervision and sanctions in the banking sector.20 Although there is not a clear regulation stipulating the autonomy of the Commission, which operates under the State Council, it is governed by the banking law that while fulfilling their supervisory duties, the Commission and the supervisory officials shall be protected by Law and that the Commission shall not be intervened by local governments, government institutions at various levels, public organizations and individuals.21 State Enterprises Reform: State enterprises take place in the center of economic reforms. Prior to the reform, it was the Planning Committee that decided the type and amount of products to be produced by enterprises. Enterprises did not have a voice in pre- and post-production stages. These were determined by plans. The determining factor in the appointment of the managers of enterprises was the relations with the Communist Party. Industry and Trade Bank, Agriculture Bank, the Bank of China, which conducts foreign exchange and foreign trade transcactions and Reconstruction Bank that renders services to big enterprises are among these banks (Orban et.al., 2003: 248). 20 The Commission is composed of eight members, a chairman, four vice-chairman, two assistants to the chairman and a commisioner of discipline investigation. The Commission has a large county organization consisting of 16 service buildings as well as 30 bureaus in administrative units such as provinces, municipalities and perefectures (http: //www.cbrc.gov.cn/mod_en01). 21 For Banking Regulation and Supervision Law, see. (http://www.cbrc.gov. cn/mod_en00). 19 Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 51 The primary objective of the state enterprises reform was to break the ties between the government and the enterprise, granting more autonomy to the enterprises in their production and management, and consequently, to ensure the establishment of a system, which would operate consistent with the market economy in a competitive manner. The policies formulated towards this objective can be summarized as granting autonomy to the enterprises, reducing their number, decomposing the management and ownership structures, empowering the managers, shifting production areas from light industry to heavy industry, pursuing a selective supporting policy, moving to mixed ownership and weakening the social facilities significantly. However, these policies were implemented progressively in compliance with the general principle of the reform. For this purpose, at first, the reform was effected in the limited number of enterprises of a pilot region and then was spread out according to the results. For example, industrial reform was first tested in six enterprises opted in Sichuan Province with the aim of ensuring self-management and expanding the enterprise. A further 100 enterprises participated in the implementation following the results obtained from the former one. Similar implementations were simultaneously carried out in other provinces and were progressively widespreaded countrywide. This implementation is defined by Deng Xiaoping as “wading the river by touching cobbles” (Shaopeng, 2000: 10). In the beginning, the number of products, which were subject to plans with respect to both production and prices, were gradually reduced and at last, the type, amount and marketing of products were started to determine by market conditions. 22 Efforts were initiated towards breaking organic ties between the government and enterprises. Enterprises would be administered by professional managers provided that public ownership is preserved and the harmonization of marketing and operation systems with the market economy would be ensured. In the 1980s, the autonomy of the enterprises were enhanced and they were empowered with the management of products, production sale, pricing, staff employment, personnel system, fees and bonus distribution and the settlement of inter-organizational structure. However, according to Amin (2005: 135), cutting off resources transFor instance, the number of agricultural product subject to planning declined from 25 to 9 between 1979-1993, while the number of industrial products was reduced from 120 to 36 between the 1980-1993 period (Lixin, 2000: 396-397). 22 52 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration ferred to enterprises from the central government, while increasing the administrative autonomy has compelled these enterprises to resolve their financial problems by borrowing from the market. While the production areas of state enterprises were shifted from food and light industry to heavy industry, the support policy was changed as well. Instead of supporting all enterprises, large-scale enterprises having the competitive power, which could adapt to the market economy, were started to support. In 1997, in compliance with the strategy of “protecting the big and giving way to the small”, big enterprises were incorporated, while small enterprises were liquidated through bankruptcy, merging them with large enterprises, the transfer of their ownership or management to private sector. By the end of 2000, 635.000 small enterprises were privatized. According to the results of first national economic census, in 2001-2005, the number of state enterprises fell to 192.000 by a 48% decline, while the number of collective joint ownership decreased by 46% to reduce to 456 thousand. Meanwhile, the number of private enterprises reached 1.98 million by a 49 % increase (http: //english.gov.cn) In line with the decline in number, the share of state enterprises in the industrial production decreased gradually. The ratio of state enterprises in gross industrial production, which was 70% in the end1970s, became merely 24% in 2000, during which public enterprise was basically limited with big strategic industry (Wong, 2003: 129). The number of individuals employed by enterprises was reduced by 30 million between 1998 and 2002 (World Bank, 2004: 14). During the planned economy period, state enterprises were not only economic institutions, but they also functioned as social institutions - a “mini social state”. Social assistance provided by the state to the state employees via enterprises ranged from cheap housing or free health services, to retirement pension or transportation and allocations. While enterprises transferred all their profits to the state, all expenditures were met by the state (Gu, 2001: 130-133). Another aim and outcome of state enterprises reform was to cease the operation of enterprises as a “mini social state”. Enterprises, whose powers end responsibilities relating to financial resources and human force were enhanced, were compelled to meet their social expenditures from their own resources. The number of employees of enterprises was also reduced. Thus, they were prevented from being institutions that absorbed human force. For example, in 1998, the number of individuals employed by enterprises was reduced by about 25 million compared to 1995 during which the number of enterprises was 291.000 (Shulian, 2000: 113-114). Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 53 Change in Planning: The PRC, which had moved to central planning in the 1950s, put its first five-year plan into effect in 1953. State Planning Commission (SPC), which was established in 1952 with the transformation to central planning, turned out to be the most powerful economic bureaucracy, the approval authority for almost all big projects and investments (Yabuki and Harner, 1999: 224). During the reform process, the content and the binding nature of plans were progressively weakened. After the initiation of liberalization, the number of products within the scope of plan was gradually reduced and with the transformation from centrally planned economy to the market economy by constitutional change in 1993, determining and binding nature of plans in economic and social life was officially terminated. In spite of the fact that five-year plans are still drawn up,23 Wong (2003: 130) says that these plans merely function as some sort of perspective plan or a rough indicator of government policies. Even though it is beyond dispute that intervention areas of plans are quite restricted compared to the past, this fact should not be perceived as the complete distraction of China from its planning tradition and practice. When the targets of plans are analyzed, it is seen that the policies of “progressive” reform process are based on a plan that these policies guide the process at macro level. The weakening of central planning also resulted in the loss of power and the importance of the State Planning Commission (SPC), the planning organization. The SPC, which was restructured under the name of the State Development and Planning Commission in 1998, was entrusted with the tasks of regulating management functions merely at macro level, long-term development planning and maintaining general economic balance (Worthley and Tsao, 1999: 573). With the loss of ground in central planning during the process of transformation to the market economy, the SPC also lost its power and authority and State Economic Commission (SEC), which was established in 1956, became the leading commission of the new economic order and most powers of the SPC were transferred to SEC, which was named the State Economic and Trade Commission SETC). In this period, the SETC acted as basic bureaucratic tool of the government in effecting economic reforms (Yabuki and Harner, 1999: 226). Privatization in Public Services: As in most countries, privatization practices in the PRC were not limited to state enterprises. Before all else, services fields such as health and education were opened to the 23 Today, eleven plans that cover the 2006-2010 period are in practice. 54 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration market and private hospitals and private education institutions have started to provide services.24 Since the PRC was founded, services such as water, electricity, gas and heating, postal services, communication, collective transportation, drainage, sewerage, garbage annihilation, road and bridge construction were under the monopoly of the state. Under this system, which state acted as policy-maker, implementer and supervisor, services were carried out on basis of low price and high subsidies. Starting from the 1990s, the said traditional method was abandoned and a new system, which was based on the reduction or removal of subsidies and cost-oriented pricing, was introduced (China Ministry of Personnel, 2005: 6). As of the second half of the 1990s, the services were progressively and widespreadly contracted to domestic and foreign corporations via methods such as the build-operate-transfer model (BOT) or the transfer of right to operate.25 For the first time, in 1994, a private company undertook the project of building a bridge in Quanzhou city of Fujian province via BOT method (He, 2005: 7). Major methods of rendering basic public services via the private sector are as follows (China Ministry of Personnel, 2005: 10-12): Build-Operate-Transfer (BOT): It is a form of project financing, wherein a private entity receives a franchise from the public sector to finance, design, construct, and operate a facility for a specified period, usually for 25-40 years, after which ownership is transferred back to the public sector. This model is widely used especially in carrying out public infrastructure projects (construction of urban water supply, public transportation and road construction). For example, a 90 milToday, the number of private higher education institutions, which were founded in the 1980s, reached 1300. 25 of these institutions are in the status of university ( China Daily Special Supplement, 9 June 2006: 11). 25 In the early 2005, a document titled “Remarks on the Encouragement, Support and Guidance to Individual, Private and Other Non-Public Economies”, which was published by State Council, is the most comprehensive, systematic and lucid political document relating to the development of private sector since the beginning of openness to abroad. The goal of the said document, which is believed to aim at fulfilling the WTO stipulations, is to further remove the impediments to private sector development, to establish equality among market players and to ensure fair competition. The document clearly emphasizes the necessity of applying the principle of equal access to the market and equal treatment in the market to the private market economy and allowing private sector enter the sectors not prohibited by laws. It is also stated in the document that the entry of private sector into the electricity, telecommunication, railways, civil aviation and oil sectors, services sectors such as gas and heating, collective transportation, sewage and garbage annihilation, infrastructure services sector, social sectors such as education, health, scientific researches and defense industry and technology should especially be allowed (China Ministry of Personnel, 2005: 5). 24 Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 55 lion Yuan worth of garbage power plant will be constructed by a private enterprise in Wenzhou province. After being operated for 25 years, it will be transferred back to the public sector. Transfer-Operate-Transfer: In this model, the private enterprise, which purchases the operation right of a constructed facility of state, operates it for a specified period on a contractual basis. At the end of the said period, the facility is transferred back to the public sector. This model is widely used too. Sale of Public Shares: In this method, which involves the sale of publicly owned enterprises' shares to the private or foreign investment institutions, the percentage of shares sold ranges between 25% and 70%. For example, in 2002, the shares of five public companies (energy, water, gas, public transportation and food companies) ranging between 25% and 60% were sold by international tender in Shenzhen state. Contract/Tender Model: This system, which is based on the assignment of a public service to a private enterprise or enterprises against a specified fee, is the most widely used method. Garbage collection, street cleaning, public buildings cleaning, municipal facility maintenance and repairs, parks management and performance evaluation are among the services, for which the contractual model is most widely used. The privatization of both public services and enterprises has brought along certain problems such as damage to public interest, corruption, and private monopolies. Especially some local province, which try to overcome financial difficulties by this way and to achieve regional political success, fail to display necessary meticulousness in selecting projects, supervising investments and establishing standards for services (China Ministry of Personnel, 2005: 13-14). Foreign Direct Investments: Legal arrangement that allows the inflow of foreign direct investments (FDI) went into effect in 1979 (Dullien, 2005: 127). In the following years, the PRC took a number of measures in order to increase FDI.26 Special economic zones and industrial parks, where environmental arrangement and infrastructure are better than other regions of the country, were established for foreign investors. In these regions, tax exceptions and different policies 26Joerg Wuttke, the vice-governor of European Trade Chamber in the PRC, who has been doing business there for 16 years, asserts that the process of establishing business in the PRC is shorter compared to the other countries. He says that while the said process takes 41 days in the PRC, this period of time is 152 days in Brazil, 89 days in India and in his own country Germany 45 days (www.oecdobserver.org). 56 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration such as relatively liberal foreign trade regime were applied in order to attract foreign capital (Taube and Öğütçü, 2002: 22). One of the methods used by the PRC in attracting especially foreign capital and foreign technology during the reform process was “special economic zones” (SEZs), “economic development zones” (EDZs), “open coastal cities” and “free harbor” implementations. With these implementations, an exceptional tax system was applied to the enterprises in the zones declared as SEZs and EDZs with the aim of attracting foreign investments. Moreover, local administrators were granted large autonomy with respect to economic regulations and more flexible export and import policies were implemented (Zhaoumu, 2000: 447). The said zones became a kind of laboratory for the implementation of reforms and acted as a bridge between national and international markets.27 Besides, the domestic labor force gained the experience of the new economic system and its operation in these zones, which were utilized to attract foreign capital, technology and human force with the aim of developing an economy consistent with exports. The experience acquired by the domestic labor force was used as a reference in the restructuring of national economy (Fulin, 2000: 335). Special economic zones were first established in four places in 1979 by the decision of the CCP Central Committee and the State Council.28 In 1984, 14 coastal cities29 and Hainan Island were declared as open coastal cities (Yabuki, 1995: 245). SEZs, EDZs, open coastal cities and free harbor practices were progressively expanded in the 1980s and 1990s, thus major cities were opened to foreign investments. Today, these zones compete with each other to attract investments. 30 Similar to the other implementations, a progressive approach was applied in this practice in conformity with the general tendency of reform.31 Deng Xiaoping defines special economic zones as the windows of technology, management, capital and the PRC’s foreign policies (Yabuki, 1995: 245). 28 Shenzhen, Zhuhai and Shantou in the Guangdong province and Xiamen in Fujian province are the first special economic zones. 29 Among these coastal cities are Tianjin, Shanghai, Guangzhou, Zhanjiang and Beihai. 30 For instance, Tianjin, Shanghai, Xian and Zhuhai cities competed for the investment of the Airbus firm, which would make its first outside-Europe investment in the PRC. In the end, the firm decided to make its investment in Tianjin as it had the most suitable conditions. The said facilities, which will contribute to the know-how of the national aviation industry, will manufacture four jet aircrafts until 2011 (China Daily, 9 June 2006: 1). 31 For example, economic development zone in Bohai region of Tianjin municipality, which is one of 14 EDZs, has been established on a of 33 km2 area. It has been decided that the said area, where there are 4.000 foreign capital-enterprises, 100, of which are internationl companies such as Toyota, Motorola, 280.000 are employer 27 Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 57 Various Results of Transformation In the early-1980s, the PRC mapped out a three-stage, long-term development strategy: resolving hunger and clothing problems, diminishing poverty, to increase gross national product and income per capita four folds at the end of the 20th century and to join the group of medium developed countries in the mid-21st century. Today, the PRC has attained the first two targets. With the same growth rate, the PRC is expected to reach the level of medium-upper income developing countries defined by World Bank until 2020 (Bi, 2005: 109-110). Economic Growth: The most concrete and discussed item among the Chinese economic reforms is related to economic growth. 32 In 1979-2000, annual real economic growth rate was 9.6%. The economy grew by 8% in 2000, 7.3% in 2001 and 7.5% in 2002. The said rate growth is predicted to continue. Such a growth represents the most permanent and rapid economic transformation of world economy in the last 50 years (OECD, 2005a: 2). The Chinese economy has been affected less by global economic contractions thanks to its large volume and population. Though 80% of growth stemmed from domestic demand, this fact does not point to the insignifance of foreign demands. In fact, the Chinese economy has become more reliable on exports growth. In the last two decades, the rate of increase in exports is 15%. The reason is that the volume of Chinese exports ranked sixth in the world in 2002 (Wong, 2003: 111-113) and third in 2007. The foreign exchange reserve, which was US$ 818,9 billion in 2005 (National Bureau of Statistics of China, 2006), reached US$ 1 trillion at the end of 2006. Today, the PRC is the world's largest foreign currency depositor (www.chinatoday.com).33 The Change in the Economic Components: While the share of industrial and services sector expanded, both economic and demographic share of the agriculture sector receded. During the 19702000 period, the share of the agriculture sector in the economy declined from 40% to 16%, while the proportion of those who earn their living from agriculture fell from 81% to 50%. In the meantime, the proportion of rural citizens decreased from 83% to 64%. Nevertheless, the rural economy employs 475 million people (World Bank, and 70.000 mobile phones were manufactured merely in 2005, will to expand to 2270 km2 during the ‘11th five-year plan’ period. 32 The growth rate in the period prior to reform (the 1952-1978 period) was also high. The rate of growth in this period is around 6.2% according to Amin (2005: 131) and 5.7% according to Wong (2003: 132). 33 Foreign exchange reserve of the PRC corresponds to six-fold of its short-term debts and more than 1/5 of global reserve (The Economist, 28 October 2006: 91). 58 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration 2004: 59). In 2003, the share of agriculture in the GDP was 14.6%, while the shares of the industrial sector and the agricultural sector were 52.3% and 33.1%, respectively (OECD, 2004: 6). Inflow of Foreign Investments: Today, the PRC attracts most foreign capital. During the 1998-2001 periods, the annual rate of increase in foreign direct investments is averagely 30%. The PRC attracts most foreign direct investments (FDI) among developing countries. In world ranking, the PRC comes second after the USA. Foreign investments that flowed into the country between 1979-1990 correspond to 10% of world’s total FDI and 39% of total FDI that flow in developing countries (OECD, 2000: 4). At the end of 2002, total FDI in the PRC reached US$ 446 billion (Wong, 2003: 113). Today, 80% of the world’s largest 500 companies have investments in the PRC (Wong, 2003: 113 quoted from The Standart (Hong Kong)). Nevertheless, the high rate of foreign investment should not be perceived as easy flow of foreign capital in the country. Foreign capital policy pursued in the PRC is based on the principle of mutual interest and bargain made for this purpose. That is to say, the purpose is to ensure the benefiting of the country from the inflow of foreign country, as much as the foreign capital itself (technology transfer, know-how, cloning, spare parts imports, local suppliers, etc).34 Although the volume of foreign investments is large, the number of origin countries is limited. While 50% of investments come from chiefly from Hong Kong as well as Taiwan, Singapore and Malaysia, the share of each of the developed economies such as European Union, the USA and Japan is less than 10% (Taube and Öğütçü, 2002: 22). Deepening of Development Gap Among Regions and Rural-Urban: Transformation from planned economy to market economy has gradually turned the PRC into a country of conflicts and inequalities. In the PRC, rich coastal cities and poor inner provinces, rich enterprisers and unemployed masses coexist (Pye, 1999: 15). Economic reforms have deepened the development gap between coastal regions located in the east of the country and inner regions (See. Table 1). For example, while the income per capita in urban areas was 1.85 times that in rural areas in the mid-1980s, it was 3.2 times in 2004 (OECD, 2005: 4). While income per capita in the coastal provinces For example, main parts and the assembly of more than 3.000 aircrafts of Boeing firm all over the world, which has % 65 share in the PRC, were provided by the Chinese firms. Boeing is predicted to buy aircraft parts worth of US$ 1.3 billion from China until 2010 (Fishman, 2005: 227). 34 Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 59 and cities exceeds the national average as they develop and open abroad, income per capita in inner and western regions remains below the national average (Wong, 2003: 117). Inequality is not specific to regions. The rural-urban gap is also wide in income distribution. At the end of 2005, while net annual income per household was US$ 407 in rural areas, it was US$ 1311 in urban regions. Moreover, 23.65 million rural people live in poverty (annual income below US$ 85), while the number of low-income people in rural regions is 40.67 million (annual income US$ 86-118) (National Bureau of Statistics of China, 2006). Table 1. GNP Per Person by Provinces (2005) GNP (US$) Provinces and Municipalities >4000 Beijing, Shanghai, Tianjin, 3000-4000 Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Guangdong 2000-2999 Liaoning, Shandong, Fujian 1500-1999 Xingyang, Inner Mongolia, Heilongjiang, Jilin, Hebei, Shanxi 1000-1499 1000< Tibet, Qinghai, Ningxia, Shaanxi, Henan, Anhui, Jiangxi, Hunan, Guangxi, Hubei, Chongoing, Sichuan, Hainan Gansu, Yunnan, Guizhou Source: The Economist, 25- 31 March 2006: 4 Foreign investments in the country deepen the inter-regional inequality as well. While inner and western regions do not attract foreign investments, a large portion of current foreign direct investments were made in rich coastal regions. Until 2000, while 86% of FDIs was made in coastal regions, the rate of FDIs made in the central region and western region were merely 9% and 5%, respectively (Kreutzberger, 2002: 85). 50% of foreign investments that were made in coastal regions flew to three provinces (Guangdong, Jiangsu, Fujian) (Hugonnier, 2002: 115). Poverty and Corruption: Today, the PRC moves from being a society based on ideology, equality and values to a society, which is based on individual gain and interest. Liberal policies have created a new class in the country and changed consumption patterns to a great extent. The said class, whose income level and luxurious consumption expenditures is high and which has adopted a western style of living, is in minority. In the cities surrounded by skyscrapers, bicycles, the 60 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration symbol of the country, are increasingly being replaced by luxury cars. On the other hand, some people live in poverty or at the minimum living standard income level. Though the proportion of ruralpopulation having a daily income under 1 US dollar declined from 31.3% in 1990-2000 to 11.5%, today 30 million people live in poverty in rural regions, while 20 million people live at the minimum living standard income level in the cities (Bi, 2005: 105-106). The new social structure based on individual gain and interest has substantially boosted corruption as well. It is notable that among those involved in corruption are some top-level officials of the Communist Party and public bureaucracy. Internal Immigration: Reforms led to a rapid rural-urban immigration. Due to the removal of impediments to population movement and poverty in rural areas, individuals move to the provinces where there is more job opportunities compared to rural areas. Today, the number of rural origin labor force that work in provinces is 120 million. The said number is predicted to reach 300 million in 2020 (China Daily, 12 June 2006: 2). Conclusion The PRC’s economic success is neither as simple as which can be explained merely by the superiority of huge and cheap labor force, nor is a miracle. Undoubtedly, a large labor force army, which does not have the power to bargain and accordingly, low cost are the significant superiority of the PRC. However, transforming this potential into superiority and sustaining the said superiority depend on good manageability. The characteristics of the Chinese reforms are that they are manageable, sustainable and are based on long-term strategies and plans. The authoritarian and permanent nature of the PRC’s political regime is a significant factor in maintaining the reforms. Progressive implementation of reforms taking into account the conditions specific to the country is another remarkable characteristic. The results of rapid transformation in the Soviet Bloc have become influential both in the acceleration of transformations by the Communist Party and the adoption of reforms by the Chinese people because of the fear of experiencing similar chaos. The Chinese Communist Party sought to keep up its monopoly power by preserving its legitimacy. For this purpose, the Party led the transformation in both on its own initiative and in the light of facts and could be able to transform its policies within the framework of these developments. The Party was able to maintain its sovereignty as long as it could display flexibility. It has Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 61 also evolved during this process and changed its ideology and member structure. Giving up development based on central planning and public ownership, it adopted a controlled market economy where public ownership still preserved its leading role. The Party eliminated likely inner resistance in the very beginning and prevented any movements towards new political power by ensuring the party members would take efficient roles in the new economic system. Reform was not initiated concurrently with all its dimensions at national level. Besides, pressures for change did not come from central government but local administrations. Different attempts were initiated simultaneously in different local administrations. Implementations were expanded in compliance with the results of these attempts and in the last stage they were converted into national policies. Each local government, special economic zone and development zone functioned as laboratories for these implementations. Instead of suppressing them, the Communist Party and central government transformed these into national policy. Thus it preserved its legitimacy and made use of these methods. All elements stipulated by the new public management understanding, such as decentralization, decentralized budget, delegation, employment in compliance with market conditions, appear to have been put into practice. Yet, the state ruled by the Communist Party has been managing the process as the most powerful actor. This fact is a significant characteristic that distinguishes the Chinese experience from the liberalization process experienced in many countries in the last 30 years. Though door to “confidence in the market” is gradually being opened partly, this confidence is not still at the level that ensures opening the door wide. Nevertheless, it is clear that the obligations brought by the membership of the WTO will further force the door open and the state’s power in the economy will gradually weaken. Development gaps between regions, unfair income distribution and elimination of corruption and poverty are the country’s priorities and grave problems. The success to be achieved in settling these issues will determine the future of both the Chinese Communist Party and the Peoples’ of Republic of China. If it is admitted that we live in a globalization era, the most important product of globalization must be the Peoples’ Republic of China. While the USA, the sovereign power of globalization, is the largest borrower of world, foreign exchange reserves of the PRC amounts to US$ 1 trillion, which is more than the USA debts. The economic and political advance development to be achieved by the PRC not only closely concerns the economies of all countries, but also in- 62 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration ternational balances. As it is known, during the Cold War, world security was depended on the fear-oriented balance between the USA and the Soviet Union. It is highly probable that the said balance, which has changed with the collapse of Soviet Union, will be established between the USA and the PRC, this time on the basis of economic power. References Adhikari, Ramesh and Yang, Yongzheng (2002), “What will WTO Membership Mean for China and its Trading Partner?”, Finance and Development, Vol. 39, No: 3, September, www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2002/09/adhikari.htm, (07.09.2006). Amin, Samir (2005), “Theory and Practice of the Chines ‘Market Socialism’ Project: Is ‘Market Socialism’ an Alternative to Liberal Globalization?”, in: The Chinese Model of Modern Development, (Ed. Tian Yu Cao), Routledge, Oxon, p. 128-148. Bi, Jiyao (2005), “China’s New Concept for Development”, in: China in Globalizing World, United Nations, Geneva, p. 105-123. Burns, John P. (1999), “The People’s Republic of China at 50: National Political Reform”, in: The People’s Republic of China after 50 Years, (Ed. Richard Louis Edmonds), Oxford University Press, New York, p. 18-32. Cao, Yuanzheng Yingyi Qian and Barry R. Weingast (1999), “From Federalism, Chinese Style to Privatization, Chinese Style”, Economics of Transformation, Volume 7/1, p. 103-131. Caulfield, Janice L. (2006), “Local administration in China: A Rational Actor Perspective”, International Review of Administrative Sciencies, 72/2, June, p. 253-267. China Daily, 12 June 2006. China Daily Special Supplement, 9 June 2006. China Ministry of Personnel (2005), “China’s Private Sector and its Development in the Sector of Public Utilities”, paper presented at the Annual Conference of the International Institute of Administrative Sciences, held in Berlin, on 20-23 September 2005. Constitution of the People’s Republic of China, Fourth Edition, Foreing Languages Press, Beijing 1999. Dullien, Sebastian (2005), “FDI in China: Trends and Macroeconomic Challenges”, in: China in a Globalizing World, United Nations, Geneva, p.125153. Fishman, Ted C. (2005), China Inc., Simon and Schuster UK Ltd., Great Britain. Fulin, Chi (2000), “China’s Opening Policy Towards outside World”, in: China’s Economic Transformation Over 20 Years, (Chief Ed. Wang Mengkui), Foreign Languages Press, Beijing, p. 320-368. Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 63 Gu, Edward X. (2001), “Beyond the Property Rights Approach: Welfare Policy and the Reform of State-Owned Enterprises in China”, Development and Change, Vol. 32, No: 1, January, p. 129-150. He, Hai-Bing (2005), “The Marketization of Public Service in Mainland China”, paper presented at the Annual Conference of the International Institute of Administrative Sciences, held in Berlin, on 20-23 September 2005. Hou John ve Jianying, Huang (2006), “Globalization of Banking Industry and Development of China’s Banking Regulatory Framework”, www.kingandwood.com/Bulletin/Bulletin%20PDF/en_2006-05-Chinajohnhou.pdf (03.08.2006). Hugonnier, Bernard (2002), “Foreign Direct Investment and Regional Development: Experience of OECD Regions and Prospects for China”, in: OECD, Foreign Direct Investment in China, Paris, p. 111-118. Hui, Qin (2005), “China’s Economic Transformation, Social Justice and Democratization at the Turn of the Century”, in: The Chines Model of Modern Development, (Ed. Tian Yu Cao), Routledge, Oxon, p. 88- 127. Kornberg, Judith F. ve Faust, John R. (2005), China in World Politics: Policies, Process, Prospects, 2nd ed., Lynne Rienner Publisher, Canada. Kreutzberger, Peter (2002), “What Type of FDI for the Chinese Hinterland?”, in: OECD, Foreign Direct Investment in China, Paris, p. 85-87. Lin, Justin Yifu (1994), “Chinese Agriculture: Institutional Changes and Performance”, in: Agriculture and Trade in China and India, (Ed. T: N. Srinivasan), ICS Press, California, p. 23-72. Lixin, Zheng (2000), “The Reform of China’s Macroeconomic Administrative System”, in: China’s Economic Transformation Over 20 Years, (Chief Ed. Wang Mengkui), Foreign Languages Press, Beijing, p. 369-429. Montinola, Gabriella, Qian, Yingyi ve Weingast, Barry R. (1995), “Federalism, Chinese Style: The Political Basis for Economic Success in China”, World Politics, 48/1, October, p. 50-81. National Bureau of Statistics of China (2006), Statistical Communiqué of The People's Republic of China on the 2005 National Economic and Social Development, http: //www.stats.gov.cn/english/newsandcomingevents/t20060302_402308 116.htm (1.7.2006). OECD (2000), Main Determinants and Impacts of Foreign Direct Investment on China’s Economy, www.oecd.org/dataoecd/57/23/1992648.pdf (30.09.2006). OECD (2004), Income Disparities in China, Paris. OECD (2005), “Agricultural Policy Reform in China”, in: China and the OECD, Policy Brief (Forum 2006, 22-23 Mayıs 2006, Paris), Special Edition, s. 17, www.oecd.org/dataoecd/16/3/36174313.pdf. (13.07.2006). 64 TODAİE’s Review of Public Administration OECD (2005a), “Economic Survey of China, 2005”, in: China and the OECD, Policy Brief (Forum 2006, 22-23 Mayıs 2006, Paris), Special Edition, s. 17, www.oecd.org/dataoecd/16/3/36174313.pdf. (13.07.2006). Oi, Jean C. (1999), “Two Decades of Rural Reform in China: An Overview and Assessment”, in: The People’s Republic of China After 50 Years, (Ed. Richard Lous Edmonds), Oxford University Pres, New York, p. 54-66. Oi, Jean C. (1999a), Rural China Takes Off: Institutional Foundations of Economic Reform, University of California Pres, California. Orban, Edmond, Xiaoyuan, Chen, Koehn, Peter H. (2003), “Great-power Decentralization and the Management of Global/Local Economic Policy and Relation: Lessons in Fludity from the People’s Republic of China”, International Review of Administrative Sciences, Vol. 69, No: 2, June, p. 235-238. Pye, Lucian W. (1999), “An Overview of 50 Years of the People’s Republic of China: Some Progress, but Big Problems Remain”, in: The People’s Republic of China after 50 Years, (Ed. Richard Louis Edmonds), Oxford University Press, New York, p. 7-17. Qiang, Li (2001), “Guanyu siyingjingji de ruogan zilio” (Some Data on the Private Economy), Zhenli de zhuiqui (The Seeking of Truth), No: 5. Rong, Ma (2003), “Population Growth and Urbanization”, in: Understanding Contemporary China, (Ed. Robert E. Gamer), 2nd ed., Lynne Reinner Publisher, Boulder-London, p. 227-254. Shangquan, Gao (1998), The Second Revolution Historic Changes in China’s Economic System, Joint Publishing (HK) Co., Ltd., Hong Kong. Shaopeng, Zhou (2000), “Progress and Experiences on China’s Economic Reform”, paper presented at the Annual Conference of the International Assocation of Schools and Institutes of Administration, held in Beijing, on 10-13 July 2000.. Shirk, Susan L. (1993), The Political Logic of Economic Reform in China, University of California Press, California. Shulian, Zhou (2000), “Reform of Ownership System and State-Owned Enterprises in China”, in: China’s Economic Transformation Over 20 Years, (Chief Ed. Wang Mengkui), Foreign Languages Press, Beijing, p. 65-145. Taube, Markus ve Öğütçü, Mehmet (2002), “Main Issues on Foreign Invsetment in China’s Regional Development: Prospects and Policy Challenges”, in: OECD, Foreign Direct Investment in China, Paris, p. 17-52 The Economist, 25- 31 March 2006 (A Survey of China). The Economist, 28 October 2006. The Standart (Hong Kong), July 12, 2002. Whitaker, Donald P ve Shinn, Rinn-Sup (1972), Area Handbook for the People’s Republic of China, US Government Printing Office, Washington DC. Transformation to the Socialist Market Economy 65 Wong, John (2003), “China’s Economy”, in: Understanding Contemporary China, (Ed. Robert E. Gamer), 2nd ed., Lynne Reinner Publisher, BoulderLondon, p. 111-153. World Bank (2004), “China: An Evaluation of World Bank Assistance”, Advance Copy, Washington DC, www.wordlbank.org.cn/English/Content/china_cae.pdf (21.06.2006). Worthley, John Abbott and Tsao, King K. (1999), “Reinventing Government in China A Comparative Anlysis”, Administration&Society, Vol. 31, Number 5, (November), p. 571-587. Xie, P. (1996), The Choice of China’s Financial System, Far East Publishing House, Shanghai. Wu, Jinglian (2005), Chinese Economic Reform, Thomson South-Western, Singapore. Yabuki, Susumi (1995), China’s New Political Economy: The Giant Awakes, (Japonca’dan çev. Stephen M. Harner), Westview Press, Colorado. Yabuki, Susumi and Harner, Stephan M. (1999), China’s New Political Economy, Revised Edition, Westview Press, Colorado. Zhaomu, Lin (2000), “The Relations Among Reform Development and Stability in China”, in: China’s Economic Transformation Over 20 Years, (Chief Ed. Wang Mengkui), Foreign Languages Press, Beijing, p. 430-481. Zheng, Yongnian (2004), Globalization and State Transformation in China, Cambridge University Press, China. Zheng, Yongnian (2000), “Institutionalizing de facto Federalism in Post-Deng China”, in: China Under Jiang Zemin, (Eds. Hung-mao Tien and Yun-han Chu), Lynne Reinner, Boulder, CO, p. 215-231. Elektronik ortam kaynakçası www.npc.gov.cn/zgrdw/english/constitution/constToDetail.jsp?id=2004, (01.07.2006). http: //www.cbrc.gov.cn/mod_en00/jsp/en004002.jsp?infoID=2596&type=1, (03.08.2006). www.oecdobserver.org/news/printpage.phd/aid/1909/Business_China.html (30.09.2006). http: //www.mof.gov.cn/english/english.htm#, (04.07.2006). http: //www.cbrc.gov.cn/mod_en01/htm/en010000.htm (03.08.2006). http: //www.cbrc.gov.cn/mod_en00/jsp/en004002.jsp?infoID=554&type=1 (05.07.2006). http: //english.gov.cn/2005-12/08/content_121412.htm (01.07.2006). www.chinatoday.com (25.01.2006)