Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
HOW DO SHOCKS AND FRICTIONS WITHIN FINANCIAL MARKETS AFFECT THE REAL ECONOMY? Stephen Millard (Bank of England, Durham University Business School and Centre for Macroeconomics) Alexandra Varadi (Bank of England) Eran Yashiv (Tel Aviv University, CfM, and CEPR) 17 March, 2017 Roadmap • Introduction and motivation • Relevant literature • Model • Effects of shocks • Effects of frictions • Conclusions and next steps What is our research question? • How do financial and real frictions affect the transmission of shocks (including financial) onto the real economy • Three key question we want to consider: • How do financial frictions and frictions in the real economy, such as labour market frictions, interact in the presence of shocks? • What does this mean for the transmission of monetary and macroprudential policies? • What does this mean for the transmission of problems in the financial sector into the wider macroeconomy? Where do we fit in the literature? DSGE models with financial frictions • Gertler and Kiyotaki (2015) • Bernanke, Gertler and Gilchrist (1999) DSGE models with labour/investment frictions • Yashiv (2015) DSGE models with housing • Iacoviello (2015) We incorporate all these frictions into one model to move away from studying them in isolation Our Model • Two types of households – patient and impatient – who get utility out of consumption, housing and leisure. Impatient households borrow subject to a collateral constraint (mortgage borrowing). • We think of the loan-to-value ratio in this constraint as a potential policy tool and examine the effects of a temporary shock to this. • Firms subject to costs of adjusting prices, hiring costs and investment adjustment costs. Have to borrow to finance investment and hiring costs. • Banks lend to firms and households and are subject to Gertler-Kiyotaki frictions. Our model: Patient Households • Mass of 1-s patient housheholds • ‘Patience’ implies low discount rate • These households save via bank deposits • Get utility out of consumption and housing • Disutility from members of the household working • Nj is the proportion of household j in employment • Total employment of patient households equals NP Our Model : Patient Households • Maximize: 1 E0 1 ln c j ,t cH ,t 1 jA j ,t ln H j ,t N j ,t 1 t 0 t P • Subject to: D j ,t Qt H j ,t Rt 1 D j ,t 1 Qt H j ,t 1 Wt N j ,t j ,t Pt c j ,t T j ,t N j ,t 1 N N j ,t 1 h j ,t Our model: Impatient Households • Mass of s impatient housheholds • ‘Impatience’ implies high discount rate • These households borrow via mortgages • Get utility out of consumption and housing • Disutility from members of the household working • Nj is the proportion of household j in employment • Total employment of impatient households equals NI Our Model : Impatient Households • Maximize: E0 1 ln c j ,t cH ,t 1 jA j ,t ln H j ,t N j ,t 1 t 0 t I • Subject to: Qt H j ,t L j ,t Qt H j ,t 1 RL ,t 1 L j ,t 1 Wt h j ,t Pt c j ,t T j ,t L j ,t ltvt Qt H j ,t N j ,t 1 N N j ,t 1 h j ,t Our model: Firms • Monopolistically competitive • Owned by the patient households • Maximise present discounted utility value of dividends • Face costs of adjusting investment and hiring costs • Have to borrow from banks to finance hiring costs • Also have to borrow from banks to finance investment • Face quadratic costs of adjusting prices • Wages are set so that all the surplus of job matches goes to firms • Households will be indifferent between supplying an extra worker and not supplying an extra worker Our Model : Firms • Maximize: h P Pt 1 h l ,t l ,t 1 P y P I W N L R L t l ,t t l ,t l ,t L ,t 1 l ,t 1 l ,t l ,t 2 N 2 Pl ,t 1 t 1 Pt c P ,t c P ,t 1 l ,t 2 Pt yl ,t Pl ,t 1 y A k N z ,t l ,t 1 l ,t • Subject to: l ,t I l ,t kl ,t 1 k kl ,t 1 I l ,t 1 S I l ,t 1 h hl ,t Ll ,t Pt I l ,t Pt yt 2 N l ,t N l ,t 1 N N l ,t 1 hl ,t 2 yt 2 P y t t Our Model : Firms • First-order conditions: • New Keynesian Phillips curve 1 rmct t P Et t 1 ln rmc • Value of installed capital QK ,t rmct 1 yt 1 1 Et 1 t 1 1 k QK ,t 1 Rt kt • Investment demand ˆ Rˆ Rˆ Q 1 L ,t t P Iˆt Iˆt 1 Et Iˆt 1 k ,t 1 P 1 P k 1 P Our model: Firms • Definition of real marginal cost wt N t h RL ,t ht ht 1 rmct 1 yt 1 Rt N t N t RL ,t 1 ht 1 yt 1 N t 1 N h Et 1 t 1 Rt 1 Rt 1 N t 1 yt N t 1 • This is the usual expression for real marginal cost plus an additional term reflecting the cost of hiring additional workers and this term depends on the spread • This is the key link between financial frictions and the real economy and inflation Our model: Banks • Banks are funded through capital (retained earnings) and • • • • deposits Bank assets are loans to impatient households (mortgages) and firms Banks are owned by the patient households Each period banks either continue to accumulate net worth (probability z) or ‘die’ and distribute their accumulated net worth to patient households as dividends (probability 1-z) The 1-z ‘dead’ banks are replaced by 1-z new banks with initial net worth Pn, provided lump sum by the patient households Our model: Banks • For a surviving bank, net worth evolves according to: n j ,t n j ,t 1 RL ,t 1 1L j ,t 1 Rt 1 1D j ,t 1 y ,t n j ,t 1 • Where y is a shock to bank profits (and, by implication, net worth) • Net worth will equal assets less liabilities (deposits) n j ,t L j ,t D j ,t • So, aggregate net worth in the banking sector evolves according to: nt z RL ,t 1 Lt 1 Rt 1 Dt 1 y ,t nt 1 1 z Ptn Our model: Banks • Bankers have the opportunity to ‘run away’ overnight with • • • • • a proportion, q, of the bank’s assets. To stop them doing so, it must be more profitable for them to keep the bank open as an ongoing business than to run away with the assets. This implies the incentive constraint: Vt qLt This leads to a spread between lending and deposit rates, which is increasing in leverage and this friction, q. We implement regulatory policy as affecting q . We also implement a shock to bank equity prices, V, which will directly affect the spread. Our model: Banks • Dividends will be given by DivB ,t 1 z RL ,t 1 Lt 1 Rt 1 Dt 1 t nt 1 • So, banks will solve the following profit maximisation problem: • Maximise Vt Pt Et j 1 • Subject to j P z j 1 1 z 1 R L ,t j 1 Lt j 1 Rt j 1 Dt j 1 t j nt j 1 Pt j cP ,t j cP ,t j 1 Vt qLt Our model: Banks • The Bellman equation for this problem implies: y ,t 1 1 q 1 Et Rt 1 z zqj t 1 jt Rt jt RL ,t • That is, the spread is increasing in leverage j, the (expected value of) the shock, y, and the friction, q Our model: Public sector and market clearing • The government is assumed to run a balanced budget: Pt Gt Tt • The Central Bank operates a Taylor rule: 1 ln Rt 1 R ln H y R ln Rt 1 1 R n t n y ln t y • Finally, market clearing implies: yt ct I t Gt 2 h ht 1 t 2 2 Nt 2 R,t Effects of frictions We compare results from four models: 1. Model with no other friction than sticky prices • Firms are 100% equity financed and face no investment or hiring adjustment costs • No role for banks, one representative household 2. Model with hiring and investment frictions • Same as Model 1, but firms face costs of hiring and adjusting investment 3. Model with financial frictions • Firms have to borrow to finance investment • Impatient households borrow for housing purchases 4. Model with all the frictions • Financial frictions : LTV ratios, leverage constraint, firms have to borrow to finance investment, costs of adjusting investment, and hiring costs , and impatient households borrow for housing purchases • Hiring and investment frictions Effects of a monetary policy shock Model 1: Only price frictions Per cent 5 Model 2: Just price, hiring and investment frictions Per cent 0.05 Consumption Consumption 0.00 0 House prices GDP GDP -5 -0.05 Investment -0.10 -10 Employment -0.15 Employment -15 -0.20 -20 -0.25 House prices Investment -25 -0.30 -30 -0.35 -35 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 -0.40 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Quarters after shock Model 3: Just price and financial frictions 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock Per cent 1 Model 4: All frictions Per cent 0.05 Consumption Consumption 0.00 0 House prices GDP GDP -1 -0.05 Investment -0.10 -2 -0.15 Employment Employment -3 -0.20 -4 House prices Investment -5 -0.30 -6 -0.35 -7 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock -0.25 -0.40 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock Effects of shocks Look at shocks to: • Bank equity prices, y • Mortgage loan-to-value ratio, ltv • Banking regulation (proxied by q) Effects of a bank equity price shock Effect of a bank equity price shock Per cent 0.05 Effect of a bank equity price shock on interest rates and inflation Basis points 700 600 Consumption 0.00 500 Spread GDP -0.05 400 -0.10 Investment Employment Loan rate 300 -0.15 200 -0.20 100 Inflation -0.25 0 Deposit rate -100 -0.30 0 1 2 3 4 5 0 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock Effect of a bank equity price shock on bank lending and net worth Per cent 20.0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock Effect of a bank equity price shock on the housing market Per cent 4 Housing stock held by patient households 15.0 6 2 Net worth 0 10.0 House prices -2 -4 5.0 -6 Housing stock held by impatient households Lending to firms -8 0.0 -10 Deposits Mortgage lending 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 -5.0 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock -12 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock Effects of a mortgage loan-to-value shock Effect of a rise in LTV ratios Per cent Effect of a rise in LTV ratios on interest rates and inflation 0.06 Basis points 40 Lending rate 20 0.04 Inflation 0.02 Consumption 0 Deposit rate -20 0.00 GDP -40 Spread -0.02 Employment Investment -0.04 -60 -0.06 -80 -100 -0.08 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock Effect of a rise in LTV ratios on bank lending and net worth Per cent 2.0 Mortgage lending 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock Effect of a rise in LTV ratios on the housing market Per cent 2.0 1.5 1.5 1.0 Deposits Housing stock held by impatient households 0.5 1.0 0.0 0.5 Lending to firms House prices -0.5 0.0 -1.0 Net worth -2.0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock -0.5 Housing stock held by patient households -1.5 0 1 2 3 4 -1.0 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock Effects of a loosening in regulation (q) Effect of a loosening in regulation Per cent Effect of a loosening in regulation on bank lending and net worth 0.18 Per cent 4 Deposits 0.16 Mortgage lending 0.14 Investment 2 0 Lending to firms 0.12 -2 0.10 Employment 0.08 -4 0.06 -6 0.04 GDP Consumption Net worth -8 0.02 -10 0.00 -12 -0.02 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Quarters after shock Conclusions • According to our model, a loosening of bank regulation leads banks to lend more while allowing their net worth (capital) to fall • A shock to bank equity valuations leads to a marked rise in the spread but a relatively small fall in output • Raising the LTV ratio on mortgage lending leads to a rise in mortgage lending but only a small rise in house prices • But we are still not happy with the quantitative implications of the model: in particular, for the spread • Need for a more careful calibration of the model • In future work we hope to estimate the model!