* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Answers to ECMC02 First Test, October 15, 2004
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Answers to ECMC02 First Test, October 15, 2004 1. There are two distinct markets: United States and Brazil. In the United States, the demand curve can be turned around: P = 1000 - Q. Therefore, MR = 1000 – 2Q. Since MC = 100, we have 1000 – 2Q = 100 or Q = 450. Substituting into the demand curve, we find P = 1000 - 450 = $550. The correct answer is (S). 2. In Brazil, the demand curve is P = 1700 – 4Q. Therefore, MR = 1700 – 8Q. Since MC = 100, we have 1700 – 8Q = 100, or Q = 200. Substituting into the demand curve, we find P = 1700 – 800 = $900. The correct answer is (W). 3. If the diamond producer is unable to discriminate between markets, he must serve the entire market. We can find the joint market by summing across the quantity dimension. We have:(Q1 = 1000 - P1)+(Q2 = 425 – 0.25P2) = (Q = 1425 – 1.25P). This can be inverted to find P = 1140 - .8Q. Therefore marginal revenue in the joint market is MR = 1140 - 1.6Q. MC = 100, so profit maximization is at 1140 – 1.6Q = 100 or Q* = 650. Substituting into the joint demand function, we find P = 1140 – 0.8(650) = $620. Profit before markets are joined together – profit with price discrimination - is [(550 x 450) + (900 x 200)] – [10,000 + (100 x 650)] = $352,500. Profit after markets are joined together is [(620 x 650) – (10,000 + (100 x 650)] = $328,000. Profit falls by $24,500 if the diamond producer is unable to discriminate between markets. The correct answer is (M). 4. In the United States, consumer surplus under price discrimination is [(1000 – 550) x 450]/2 = $101,250. Without price discrimination, the price is $620. At this price, we can calculate using the United States demand curve that 380 units will be sold to United States consumers. The consumer surplus will therefore be [(1000 – 620) x 380]/2 = $72,200. The fall in consumer surplus is $29,050. The correct answer is (A). 5. In Brazil, consumer surplus under price discrimination is [(1700 – 900) x 200]/2 = $80,000. Without price discrimination, the price is $620, and the quantity sold is 270. The consumer surplus will, therefore, be [(1700 – 620) x 270]/2 = $145,800. The rise in consumer surplus by moving to the combined market is, therefore, $65,800. The correct answer is (T). 6. With no trade, domestic supply is P = .0025Q and demand is P = 60 - .005Q. The intersection of these functions gives equilibrium, where 60 - .005Q = .0025Q, or where Q* = 8000. By substituting into the demand curve, we find P = 60 .005(8000) = $20. The correct answer is (U). 7. If a perfectly elastic supply of running shoes is available at $5, we can find the amount traded where 60 -.005Q = 5 or where Q* = 11,000. The domestic supply at a price of $5 is given by 5 = .0025Q, or Qdom = 2,000. Imports are therefore 9,000. The correct answer is (W). 8. A tariff of 100% will drive the price from international sources up to $10. Before the tariff, the amount of imports was 9,000. After the tariff, the total amount traded is given by 60 - .005Q = 10 or Q* = 10,000. Domestic production after the tariff is at .0025Q = 10 or at Q = 4,000. Therefore, after the tariff the amount of imports is 10,000 – 4,000 = 6,000. The amount of imports fell by 3,000 because of the tariff. The correct answer is (Q). 9. Consumer surplus before the tariff was [(60 – 5) x 11000]/2 = $302,500. Consumer surplus after the tariff is [(60 – 10) x 10000]/2 = $250,000. The loss of consumer surplus is $52,500. The correct answer is (G). 10. The deadweight loss from the tariff is the sum of two triangles: [(4000 – 2000) x 5]/2 + [(11000 – 10000) x 5]/2 = 5000 + 2500 = $7500. The correct answer is (C). 11. Demand is P = 596 – 4Q, so MR = 596 – 8Q. MC = 20, so the profit maximizing output is found where 596 – 8Q = 20, or where Q* = 72. Substituting into the demand curve, we find that P = 596 – 4(72) = $308. This is the joint monopoly result in this market. The correct answer is (R). 12. With a Cournot duopoly, P = 596 – 4Q2 - 4Q1. For firm #1, MR = 596 – 4Q2 – 8Q1. Since MC = 20, we have 596 – 4Q2 – 8Q1 = 20 or 576 – 4Q2 = 8Q1. This gives us the reaction function of Firm #1, which is Q1 = 72 – .5Q2 . The reaction function of Firm #2 is similar: Q2 = 72 – .5Q1. Substituting, we find that these two reaction functions can be satisfied at only one point. Q1 = 72 – .5 (72 – .5Q1) or .75Q1 = 36. So Q1* = 48 and Q2* = 48. Total output in the industry is 96, so P = 596 – 4(96) = $212. The correct answer is (N). 13. In the Stackelberg equilibrium, the first firm incorporates the reactions of the second firm into its profit-maximizing decision and firm #2’s output is no longer a constant from Firm #1’s point of view. P = 596 – 4(72 – .5Q1) - 4Q1, which can be simplified to P = 308 - 2Q1 . Therefore, MR1 = 308 - 4Q1 = 20 or Q1* = 72. From Firm #2’s reaction function, we can calculate that Q2* = 36. Therefore, total output in the Stackelberg industry is 108 and P = 596 – 4(108) = $164. The correct answer is (J). 14. In a perfectly competitive equilibrium (or quasi-competitive equilibrium), P = $20 and Q = 144. Compared to this, a Stackelberg equilibrium has a consumer surplus loss of (164 – 20) x (144 – 108)/2 = $2592. Since there is no producer surplus, this is the total efficiency loss (deadweight loss) from Stackelberg. Comparing the Cournot equilibrium to the perfectly competitive equilibrium, we find a loss of consumer surplus of (212 – 20) x (144 – 96)/2 = $4608. Again, there is no producer surplus, so this is the total efficiency loss. The Cournot equilibrium has a larger deadweight loss by $2016, so the correct answer is $2016. The correct answer is (W). 15. We know that MR = P(1 + 1/ED), where elasticity of demand is measured as a negative number. Also the profit-maximizing monopolist will have MR = MC. In this case, we know that 48 = (P x 12) – (3 x 12), so P = $7. So, we have 3 = 7(1 + 1/ED) or (1 + 1/ED) = 3/7 or 1/ED = 3/7 – 7/7 = -4/7. We can calculate that ED = -7/4 = -1.75. The correct answer is (R). Short Answer Questions 16. We cannot reproduce the diagram here, but note that the MC function before the tax is MC = 3Q. The tax increases the marginal costs of production, so the new MC + T = 50 + 3Q. The new P* = $90 and the new Q* = 10. (a) The original equilibrium price was P = $80; the new equilibrium price is $90. Therefore the buyers’ share of the $50 tax is $10. Therefore, the sellers’ share must be $40. (b) The competitive (or quasi-competitive) result is where P = MC or where 100 – Q = 3Q. The competitive equilibrium is therefore at Q = 25 and P = $75. Compare the original monopoly solution to this to find the DWL from monopoly = [(80 – 60) x 5]/2 = $50. (c) Calculate the deadweight loss from the after-tax equilibrium compared to the competitive equilibrium. DWL with tax = [(90 – 30) x 15]/2 = $450. Since the DWL from monopoly was $50, it is clear that the additional DWL from the tax = 450 – 50 = $400. 17. (a) Draw the diagram and show the efficiency loss as a triangle. Charging a minimum price of $8.00 reduces the quantity demanded to 2000 bushels of wheat. The triangle should shade the area between 2000 and 6000 bushels, with the demand curve forming the upper boundary and the supply curve the lower boundary. The efficiency loss = [(8 – 2) x (6000 – 2000)]/2 = $12,000. The amount of consumer surplus before this minimum-price policy was implemented = [(10 – 4) x 6000]/2 = $18,000. After the policy, the amount of consumer surplus = [(10 – 8) x 2000]/2 = $2,000. The loss of consumer surplus due to the policy is therefore $16,000. (b) Now the Canadian government purchases sufficient wheat to bring the price up to $8.00 per bushel. In other words, the new demand curve must intersect the existing supply curve at $8.00 per bushel. The equation of the supply curve is P = 1 + .0005Q, so this occurs at Q = 14,000. In other words, the government has to buy 14,000 – 2,000 = 12,000 bushels of wheat. The cost of this wheat at a price of $8 is $96,000. However, producers gain additional producers’ surplus, over and above the amount transferred from consumers. The additional producers’ surplus = [(8 – 4) x (14,000 – 2,000)]/2 = $24,000. The net efficiency loss is therefore $96,000 - $24,000 = $72,000. Consumers’ surplus before the policy was [(10 – 4) x 6000]/2 = $18,000. After the policy, it is [(10 – 8) x 2000]/2 = $2,000. Therefore, the loss of consumers’ surplus is $16,000. 18. (a) The demand curve for Type A consumers is P = 20 –10Q. The demand curve for Type B consumers is P = 40 - 5Q. The maximum amount that Type A consumers will consume is 2 units; for Type B consumers, this maximum is 8 units. To encourage Type A consumers to just be willing to consume 2 units, the monopolist can charge them their maximum willingness-to-pay which is the entire area under the demand curve (20 x 2)/2 = $20. However, Type B consumers could decide to consume this “Type A” package once it is offered on the market. If they did they would gain consumer surplus of [40 x 8]/2 – (30 x 6)/2 - 20 = $50. Because of this, any other package offered to Type B consumers has to offer them at least this same amount of consumer surplus, or else they will not select it. Therefore, if the monopolist wishes to get Type B consumers to purchase 8 units of output, the maximum it can charge is (40 x 8)/2 – 50 = $110 (i.e., the total willingness to pay under the Type B demand curve, minus the consumer surplus they need to be given). The two packages are, therefore, 2 units at $20 and 8 units at $110. Type B consumers will get $50 of consumer surplus. (b) If Q = 1 for Type A consumers, the maximum that can be charged is the area under this demand curve out to Q =1, which is [(20 – 10) x 1]/2 + (10 x 1) = $15. At Q = 1, the marginal valuation along the demand curve is $35. The consumer surplus given to Type B consumers by purchasing the Type A package would be (40 x 8)/2 – (35 x 7)/2 – 15 = $22.50. Therefore, the Type B package can be priced so as to give Type B consumers this same amount of consumer surplus. In other words, the price can be (40 x 8)/2 – 22.50 = $137.50. The old arrangement gave the monopolist profit of 20 + 110 = $130. Under the new arrangement, the profit is 15 + 137.50 = $152.50. The increase in profits is $22.50. 19. In the long run, the amount of producer surplus is determined by the demand for the good (along with the upward slope of the supply curve which reflects the scarcity (or differential productivity) of some input to production). Higher demand, all else equal, will increase producer surplus; lower demand will lower it. The poem presents two alternative ways of looking at high prices. First, the conventional wisdom suggests that pigs cost more because their inputs have risen in price (corn and land are higher priced). In the second half of the poem, the conventional wisdom is turned on its head. If you would like to know why the price of farmland is high, you are asked to consider that the price of farmland is high because suppliers of pigs are willing to pay high prices for farmland because the price of pigs is high enough to justify it. In other words, the high demand for pigs creates a high demand for farmland and so the price of these inputs rises. It is the rising price of inputs that makes up long run producer surplus. 20. There are 5 identical firms so 5q = Q or q = .2Q. The industry supply curve is, therefore, P = .05 x .2Q = .01Q. Demand is P = 60 - .005Q. The intersection will come where .01Q = 60 - .005Q or where Q = 4,000 and P = 40. We need to find the demand curve faced by the dominant firm (which nets out the supply provided by the competitive fringe of firms). At a price of $40, we have just calculated that the supply by the competitive fringe and the market demand will intersect, so at this point there will be zero quantity demanded from the dominant firm (price leader). On the other hand, from the supply curve/function of the competitive fringe, we can see that at a price of $0 or below, there will be zero quantity supplied by the competitive fringe, so the entire demand will be left to the dominant firm. At P = $0, market demand is 0 = 60 - .005Q or Q = 12,000. Therefore the slope of the dominant firm’s demand function is (40 – 0)/12,000 = .003333 and the equation of this demand function is P = 40 - .003333Q. The marginal revenue of the dominant firm is given by 40 - .006666Q and the marginal cost is constant at $20. Therefore 40 - .006666Q = 20 or Q = 3,000. This is the profit-maximizing output of the dominant firm. The price charged can be found by substituting this quantity into the dominant firm’s demand function or P = 40 - .003333(3,000) = $30. At this price, the competitive fringe of firms will want to supply 30 = .01Q = 3,000 units of output. The dominant firm sells 3,000 units at a price of $30 and has average costs of $20 per unit. Profit = (30 x 3000) – (20 x 3000) = $30,000. The dominant firm in this problem has a cost advantage over other firms, perhaps because of technological superiority or control of a scarce productive input. The long run profit advantage of the dominant firm can be viewed as a return to this scarce input or technology and therefore as an economic rent.