Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Carbon pricing and household welfare: Evidence from Uganda Raavi Aggarwal,1,2 Sinem H. Ayhan,1 Michael Jakob1 and Jan Christoph Steckel1 Abstract Policymakers frequently voice concerns that carbon pricing could impair economic development in the short-run, especially in low-income countries such as Uganda. We estimate a consumer demand system for energy and food items to assess how households’ welfare, and demand for food and energy, can be expected to react to a carbon price of US$40/ton. The results show modest and overall progressive welfare effects of carbon pricing, in the range of 0.2 – 1.8%, across the population. We observe declines of 15 – 59% in the demand for electricity, kerosene and charcoal, with concomitant shifts within food consumption baskets, due to complementarities with cooking fuels and negative income effects. Heterogeneous demand responses across expenditure terciles reveal disparities in biomass and food consumption, as well as nutritional intake, due to carbon pricing. Around half of the Ugandan population experiences declines of up to 2.4% in food and nutrient consumption with disparate effects within income groups, revealing important “horizontal” equity considerations. Complementary social protection policies in conjunction with carbon pricing could potentially ease adverse effects on economic development in Uganda. Keywords: Consumer demand system, censored EASI, carbon pricing, Sub-Saharan Africa, household welfare, distribution JEL Codes: D12, Q41, Q56, R15 Declarations of interest: None Funding Source: German Federal Ministry of Education and Research (BMBF) (funding code 011A1807A, DECADE) 1 Mercator Research Institute on Global Commons and Climate Change, Torgauer Str. 19, 10829 Berlin, Germany. Corresponding Author. Email: [email protected]. Contact No.: +49 30 33 85 537 -217. Postal Address: MCC Berlin, Torgauer Str. 19, 10829 Berlin, Germany. 2 1 1. Introduction Carbon pricing (by means of a carbon tax or a cap-and-trade system) is an efficient instrument to reduce emissions (Somanathan et al. 2014) and avoid future lock-in into carbon-intensive energy systems (Mattauch et al. 2015). The High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices further recommends a global carbon price starting at US$40/t CO2 for efficient emissions reduction (World Bank 2017). While absolute emissions are arguably low, countries in Sub-Sahara Africa (SSA) carbonise rapidly, with 8 of 10 of the world’s fastest carbonising countries located in the region (Steckel et al. 2020). Some SSA countries including South Africa, Senegal and Côte d’Ivoire have already implemented or are currently considering carbon prices (World Bank 2021a). Uganda’s Intended Nationally Determined Contribution (INDC) to the 2015 Paris Agreement similarly aims to implement mitigation measures that could result in GHG emissions reduction of up to 22% by 2030 relative to the business-as-usual scenario (Government of Uganda 2015). It further emphasizes decarbonisation of the energy, infrastructure and transport sectors (UNFCCC 2016). Higher prices for fossil fuels resulting from a carbon price however impose greater costs on households, and in SSA, could lead to unintended welfare outcomes, such as promoting a shift toward traditional biomass like firewood (Jewell et al. 2018; Greve and Lay 2021). Biomass use could well be problematic for the climate, e.g. because of increased deforestation resulting from the unsustainable use of forests (Masera et al. 2015). Increasing use of biomass could also affect socio-economic development, such as health (through indoor air pollution) (Pratiti et al. 2020), food consumption (due to commodity price hikes) (Fuje 2019) and female labour force participation (due to time spent to gather firewood) (Köhlin et al. 2011). We investigate the potential impacts of a carbon price on household welfare in Uganda, examining the link between energy use and food consumption, and accounting for substitution within households’ consumption baskets. We first estimate price elasticities of demand for several food groups and energy sources, and then simulate the second-order welfare effects of a US$40/ton price on carbon emissions. Previous studies of energy demand in SSA find mixed patterns of substitution among fuels in response to fossil fuel price increases. Olabisi et al. (2019) estimate a censored quadratic almost ideal demand system (QUAIDS) for Tanzania, and find charcoal price increases to raise kerosene demand, with heterogeneous effects across rural and urban areas. On the contrary, fossil fuel price increases induce substitution toward traditional biomass in Senegal (Yaméogo 2 2015). Similar analyses for South Africa and Ethiopia highlight the role of energy access, availability of cook-stoves and connections to the electric grid, in determining energy demand (Okonkwo 2021; Alem and Demeke 2020; and Guta 2012). The distributional welfare impacts of carbon pricing in advanced countries are typically regressive (Sterner 2012). Cross – country analyses in low and middle-income countries (LMICs), however, suggest a high likelihood of progressive welfare outcomes, due to the relatively low energy expenditure shares of poorer households in LMICs (Ohlendorf et al. 2021; Dorband et al. 2019). Country-specific evidence for Asian and Latin American economies further confirms progressive distributional effects of energy taxes, but also reveals large indirect welfare consequences of food price increases (Renner et al. 2018; Bhuvandas and Gundimeda 2020; and Irfan et al. 2018). The Almost Ideal Demand (AID) System of Deaton and Muellbauer (1980), its quadratic version (Banks et al. 1997), and the more recently developed Exact Affine Stone Index (EASI) demand system (Lewbel and Pendakur 2009), have been extensively applied to models of food and energy demand in advanced countries (van der Ploeg et al., 2021, Eisner et al., 2021, Reaños and Wölfing, 2020, and Zhen et al. 2013). In low and middle-income countries, the QUAIDS demand system has been estimated for patterns of food consumption in Mexico, Uganda, Malawi and others (Attanasio et al. 2013; Attanasio et al. 2011; Boysen 2016, and Ecker and Qaim 2011). We extend the literature by implementing an approximately linear EASI model for Ugandan households, accounting for censored observations in reported commodity expenditures. We estimate a system of correlated Tobit equations, which model zero consumption of specific commodities, in a joint framework via the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM), taking into account cross-equation error correlations, and imposing parameter restrictions from consumer theory. We thus build on advancements made by Meyerhoeffer et al. (2005), Jakubson (1988) and Chamberlain (1980, 1984) in efficient estimation of censored models for a nonlinear equation system. Drawing on household-level expenditure data from the Uganda National Household Survey (UNHS), 2016-17, conducted by the Uganda Bureau of Statistics (UBOS), and commodity price data from the World Bank’s Living Standards Measurement Study (LSMS) for 2015-16, we estimate the uncompensated and compensated price elasticities of demand for 12 commodities. These include electricity, kerosene, traditional biomass (charcoal and firewood), 3 and several food groups. We then combine the estimated elasticities with product-level data on CO2 emissions from the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP 10), to examine the first- and second-order welfare impacts of a carbon pricing policy in Uganda. We investigate the consequent shifts in energy and food demand, in particular calorie and nutrient intake, across the income distribution. Lastly, we analyse potential increases in biomass consumption due to carbon pricing, and evaluate revenue redistribution schemes needed to mitigate trade-offs between climate policy and economic development. The results show clear patterns of substitution among fuels, with a 1% increase in electricity and kerosene prices raising firewood demand by 1% and charcoal demand by 0.5%, respectively. We find complementarities between food and energy items, with households raising their consumption of vegetables and meat in response to electricity price hikes, while reducing cereal consumption, synonymously with increases in biomass demand. A carbon price of US$40/t CO2 generates modest welfare losses in the range of 0.2 – 1.8% of expenditure. The consequent energy and food price increases lead to significant disparities in food, calorie and nutrient consumption across the population. Given the prevalence of cooking in household patterns of energy use, we identify cooking fuels as additional channels of policy impact. In conjunction with carbon pricing policies, social welfare programmes such as lump-sum transfers, could therefore create important pathways for long-term sustainable development in Uganda and the broader SSA region. This paper is structured as follows. Section 2 outlines the methodology, and section 3 discusses the data and presents descriptive statistics. Section 4 outlines the econometric methods and section 5 presents the results. Section 6 discusses the results and limitations, and section 7 concludes. 2. Methodology 2.1. Exact Affine Stone Index (EASI) demand system We estimate the approximate EASI implicit Marshallian demand system developed by Lewbel and Pendakur (2009), which is derived from consumer theory and expresses budget shares in linear forms. The EASI log of cost function 𝐶(. ) for the exact model for J goods, is expressed in terms of utility u, a J- vector of log prices p and a J- vector of errors 𝜀: 4 1 𝐶(𝑝, 𝑢, 𝜀) = 𝑢 + 𝑝′ (𝑏0 + 𝑏1 𝑢) + 𝑝′ 𝐴𝑝 + 𝑝′𝜀 2 (1) where A is a J×J matrix of parameters with elements [𝐴]𝑗𝑘 = 𝑎𝑗𝑘 , while 𝑏1 is a J- vector of coefficients. Applying Shephard’s Lemma to the cost function, we obtain Hicksian demands, and via duality, the vector of Marshallian budget shares in implicit form: 𝑤 = 𝑏0 + 𝑏1 𝑦 + 𝐴𝑝 + 𝜀 (2) where y is interpreted as a measure of implicit utility and the log of real household expenditure. Engel curves are modelled as approximately linear, while the 𝜀 terms are random utility parameters reflecting individual preference heterogeneity. Solving for y by equating the cost function 𝐶(𝑝, 𝑢, 𝜀) to the log of nominal household expenditure x and substituting for 𝑤 yields the following expression, with 𝑝′ 𝑤 equal to the log Stone price index (Stone 1954): 1 𝑦 = 𝑥 − 𝑝′ 𝑤 + 2 𝑝′𝐴𝑝 (3) This expression however relies on the matrix of estimable parameters A, and is endogenous due to its dependence on the budget shares 𝑤. We therefore estimate the approximate model (Lewbel and Pendakur 2009), with 𝑦̃ = 𝑥 − 𝑝′𝑤 ̅, and deflate nominal expenditure x by the Consumer Price Index, whose commodity weights are derived from national household expenditure surveys (UBOS 2018). The following parameter restrictions are imposed to satisfy consumer theory, in particular Walras’ law, homogeneity of the cost function of degree one in prices and symmetry of the Slutsky matrix: 1𝐽′ 𝑏0 = 1, 1𝐽′ 𝑏1 = 0, 1𝐽′ 𝐴 = 0, and 𝑎𝑗𝑘 = 𝑎𝑘𝑗 , ∀ 𝑗 ≠ 𝑘 (Lewbel and Pendakur 2009). However, as inequality constraints cannot be imposed, the model does not ensure negative semi-definiteness of the Slutsky matrix. The compensated price elasticity of the budget share for good j in response to an increase in the price of good k, is expressed as follows (Lewbel and Pendakur 2009): 𝑐 𝑒𝑤 = 𝑗 ,𝑝𝑘 𝑎𝑗𝑘 𝑤𝑗 (4) where 𝑤𝑗 is the observed budget share of good j. To obtain price elasticities of demand, we note that the cross-price budget share elasticities equal the corresponding price elasticities of demand. 5 The own-price elasticities are related to the budget share elasticities as follows:3 𝑐 𝑐 𝑒𝑗,𝑘 = 𝑒𝑤 −1 𝑗 ,𝑝𝑘 (5) 𝑐 where 𝑒𝑗,𝑘 is the compensated price elasticity of demand for good j with respect to the price of good k. The expenditure elasticities of demand are derived as follows: 𝑦̃ 𝑒𝑗,𝑦̃ = 𝑏1𝑗 𝑤 + 1 (6) 𝑗 We then derive the uncompensated (Marshallian) price elasticities of demand from the Slutsky equation in budget share form, as follows: 𝑢 𝑐 𝑒𝑗,𝑘 = 𝑒𝑗,𝑘 − 𝑒𝑗,𝑦̃ 𝑤𝑘 (7) 2.2. Welfare impacts The first-order (FO) welfare effect of a price change is the additional expenditure incurred by households for the original consumption bundle to be affordable. In budget share form, the FO effect is expressed as: 0 𝐹𝑂 = ∑𝐾 𝑗=1 𝑤𝑗 ∆𝑝𝑗 (8) 𝑝𝑗0 where 𝑤𝑗0 and 𝑝𝑗0 are the initial budget share and price for good j, respectively, with expenditures aggregated across the K goods that exhibit price increases. For goods unaffected by carbon pricing (in this study, charcoal and firewood), the welfare effect is zero. To account for household demand changes in response to relative price hikes and shifts within the consumption basket, we analyse the second-order (SO) welfare effects. Because SO calculations account for substitution effects, they are typically smaller than first-order calculations, which overestimate welfare losses. Banks et al. (1996) derive second order approximations to the welfare loss of an indirect tax on a single item in the consumption basket. Renner et al. (2018) extend this framework to multiple simultaneous price changes through a second-order Taylor series expansion of the expenditure function. We follow their approach to 3 This can be obtained by differentiating the budget shares 𝑤𝑖 = 𝑝 𝑖 𝑓𝑖 𝑥 , where 𝑓𝑖 is the quantity of good 𝑖 demanded, with respect to prices. These formulae hold for both uncompensated and compensated demand. The theory of duality shows that at consumers’ optimal bundles, Hicksian and Marshallian demands (and budget shares) are equal. 6 compute SO welfare effects, or the compensating variation, which measures the amount of compensation households require to achieve their initial utility levels at the new set of prices. As a proportion of household expenditure, the approximate second-order welfare effect is: 𝑆𝑂 ≈ ∑𝐽𝑖=1 𝑤𝑖 ∆𝑝𝑖 𝑝𝑖0 1 𝑐 + 2 ∑𝐽𝑖=1 ∑𝐽𝑗=1(𝑤𝑖 𝑒𝑖,𝑗 ∆𝑝𝑖 ∆𝑝𝑗 𝑝𝑖0 𝑝𝑗0 ) (9) The first term represents the first-order effect, while the second-term measures changes in consumption due to multiple price changes, captured by the compensated price elasticities of 𝑐 demand (𝑒𝑖,𝑗 ) and expenditure shares (𝑤𝑖 ). As the carbon pricing policy leaves the prices of biomass (charcoal and firewood) unaffected, any cross-price effects involving solid fuels will result in no additional welfare losses, despite non-zero demand changes. 2.3. Changes in final consumption 2.3.1. Commodity demand We compute the total change in quantity demanded for each item, in response to a carbon price, based on the estimated uncompensated price elasticities of demand. Consider a Marshallian demand function 𝑓𝑖 for commodity i, as a function of the J-vector of prices q,4 and total household expenditure x: 𝑓𝑖 = 𝑓𝑖 (𝑞1 , 𝑞2 , … 𝑞𝑖 , … , 𝑞𝐽 ; 𝑥) The proportionate change in quantity demanded is then approximately equal to:5 ∆𝑓𝑖 𝑓𝑖 ≈ ∑𝐽𝑗=1 𝑒𝑓𝑢𝑖 ,𝑞𝑗 ∆𝑞𝑗 𝑞𝑗 (10) 2.3.2. Food and nutrient consumption We additionally compute the change in total food consumption across the population. We first recalculate budget shares with respect to households’ total food expenditure, and use these modified budget shares as weights for the demand changes derived in equation (10) for the k 4 5 We distinguish prices q from the log of prices p, considered earlier. The derivation is presented in Appendix D. 7 food groups to compute the aggregate change in food consumption. Hence, the proportionate change in total food demand due to carbon pricing is: ∆𝐹 𝐹 = ∑𝑘𝑖=1 ∆𝑓𝑖 𝑓𝑖 𝑤𝑓𝑖 (11) where 𝑤𝑓𝑖 is the modified expenditure share for food group i, for a total of k food groups. Despite lack of data on quantities, budget shares can be used to analyse shifts in the composition of food consumption, while holding total expenditure constant.6 Lastly, we calculate the percentage change in consumption of calories, protein and micronutrients due to carbon pricing. Following Ecker and Qaim (2011), we analyse changes in five key micronutrients: Iron, Vitamin C, Riboflavin, Folate and Vitamin B12. Using a food composition table for Uganda from HarvestPlus,7 we first individually calculate the average level of nutrients, 𝑛𝑖 for calories (kcal), protein (grams) and micronutrients (grams) in each food category i per kilogram, using food item-specific consumption shares as weights for the ∆𝑁 broad food category. We then obtain the percentage change in total nutrient intake, ( 𝑁 ) due to the carbon price, as follows: ∆𝑁 𝑁 = ∑𝑘 𝑖=1 𝑛𝑖 𝑤𝑓 ∆𝑓𝑖 𝑖 𝑓𝑖 ∑𝑘 𝑖=1 𝑛𝑖 𝑤𝑓 (12) 𝑖 3. Data and Descriptive Statistics 3.1. Expenditure and price data Household expenditure data are drawn from the Uganda National Household Survey (UNHS), conducted by the Uganda Bureau of Statistics (UBOS), for the latest year available, 2016-17. The UNHS is nationally representative, with a sample size of 15,912 households for an estimated population of 38 million (UBOS 2018). The survey comprises detailed consumption modules on expenditures incurred for food items and energy sources, with respective weekly and monthly recall periods. Following Deaton and Zaidi (2002), we scale expenditures to annual levels. For each item, we aggregate the expenditures incurred on market purchases and the expenditure values of goods produced at home, collected from villages/forests or items 6 We further simulate national price increases for each commodity, so that prices do not exhibit differential increases across regions, due to carbon pricing. 7 The Food Composition Table for Uganda from HarvestPlus is available here. 8 received in-kind. Accounting for missing data on commodity expenditures, we obtain a sample of 15,682 observations. Individual food items are categorised into commodity groups based on likely complementarities between items, in order to satisfy the assumption of multi-stage budgeting and weak separability between the demand for food and fuel, from the demand for other nondurable and durable items. We model demand for 12 consumption groups including 4 energy sources – electricity, kerosene, charcoal and firewood, and 8 food categories – cereals; fruits; vegetables; meat & fish; milk & eggs; cheese, oils & fats; alcohol & tobacco, and other food & drink. The demand system excludes other non-durable and durable goods due to lack of commoditylevel price data. We further exclude transport due to inadequate expenditure and price data.8 However, the non-durable items considered account for 65 per cent of households’ mean total spending. To curtail the effects of outliers, we omit observations whose budget shares for individual items exceed the corresponding 99th percentile values, and budget shares that are censored at 1. We further trim the top and bottom 1% of observations of the real expenditure distribution, resulting in a final sample of 13,582 households, which covers 85% of the Ugandan population. Data on commodity prices are drawn from two sources. First, energy prices for kerosene, biomass and food items are obtained from the Uganda National Panel Survey, conducted by the World Bank’s Living Standards Measurement Study (LSMS), for the closest year available, 2015-16.9 We take simple averages of item-specific market prices reported by households and construct average annual prices for each of the 12 categories of the demand system, at the district – rural/urban level, to capture spatial heterogeneity, and mitigate seasonal influences in biomass availability. This level of spatial aggregation controls for potential endogeneity of prices due to household production, and mitigates concerns of quality differentiation in unit prices (Capéau and Dercon 2006). For districts with missing price data in the UNPS, we impute the corresponding national, annual average price for each commodity. We then inflate all 8 Only 7% of sample households report spending on motor fuels. We find insufficient commodity price data in the Uganda National Household Survey and thus rely on the UNPS for prices. 9 9 commodity prices to 2016-17 levels using the Consumer Price Index for Uganda, to match the household expenditure data.10 Second, we obtain national electricity tariffs for Uganda from the Electricity Regulatory Authority (ERA).11 These are available at a quarterly frequency, with the pricing structure involving a two-block tariff, around a threshold consumption level of 15 kWh units per month. Data on electricity consumption from the UNPS for 2015-16 suggest that around 90% of households with positive reported expenditures for electricity consume more than 15 units per month. Therefore, we apply only the higher marginal tariff as a uniform price for electricity for all households. 3.2. CO2 Emissions Data To analyse the distributional welfare impacts of a national carbon price, we combine the household-level expenditure survey with the Global Trade Analysis Project (GTAP 10) database for 2014, which provides carbon dioxide emissions levels for 65 sectors, based on an environmentally-extended multiregional input-output table (Aguiar et al. 2019). Since the GTAP database excludes emissions from biomass, there are no resulting price changes for charcoal or firewood (Dorband et al. 2019). Based on the conversion table provided for Uganda, the 140 consumption items from the UNHS are mapped to 16 corresponding sectors in GTAP 10 (documented in Appendix Table A7). The CO2 intensity for a specific item can either be attributed to direct emissions due to energy consumption (e.g. electricity and kerosene), or indirect emissions due to food consumption (Renner 2018). We compute the weighted carbon intensities for the 12 categories of the demand system based on the mean consumption shares of individual items within each category, in the UNHS. This yields a household-level dataset with expenditures and budget shares for various commodity groups, and corresponding weighted carbon intensities for each category. We deflate expenditures and prices to 2014 values using the consumer price index and subsequently calculate price changes for all commodities due to the carbon price. 10 11 Additional details of the commodity price data are provided in Appendix A. The Schedules of End-User Tariffs are available here. 10 3.3. Descriptive Statistics Summary statistics for expenditure shares, annual household expenditure on food and energy, and prices used in estimation of the EASI demand system are presented in Table 1. The mean budget shares (Column 1) suggest that households’ consumption baskets for food and fuel are largely composed of vegetable consumption, followed by cereals, meat & fish, and other foods, while energy comprises less than 5% of expenditure. For the sub-sample of electricity users (Column 3), the average budget share is 7.3%, compared to mean budget shares of 0.6% for kerosene, 2.3% for charcoal and 3.3% for firewood, for the respective users. A substantial proportion of households further report zero expenditures for various items. For instance, only around 27% of households report positive expenditures on electricity (Column 4), with 73% of the sample reporting zero spending on electricity, which is largely due to lack of widespread access to the electric grid (IEA et al. 2020).12 Table 1. Expenditure shares for the full sample (% of expenditure on food & fuel) Item Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other Food & Drink Annual Expenditure on Food & Energy (UgX) N (1) (2) Mean (%) Std. Dev. 1.95 0.19 0.62 1.98 17.7 2.96 42.51 10.86 2.74 2.09 2.98 13.41 4.516 0.335 1.236 2.393 14.708 4.589 21.974 11.227 4.551 2.09 6.067 20.7 3,338,494 2,012,756 13,582 13,582 (3) Mean if exp. > 0 (%) 7.32 0.57 2.29 3.30 20.46 6.11 44.56 15.96 6.70 2.92 8.89 13.46 (4) Percent with positive exp. 26.65 33.43 27.28 59.86 86.51 48.48 95.38 68.05 40.95 71.69 33.48 99.65 - 13,582 Note: The sample sizes for items with positive reported expenditures in Column 3 are distinct for each item and hence not reported. 12 The reporting of zero expenditures partly reflects lack of access to modern energy sources, but also differential fuel and food consumption patterns across the population. Additionally, the 7-day recall period used in the survey may lead to exclusion of certain food groups not consumed in the week preceding the survey (Ecker and Qaim 2011). 11 Households’ budget shares for different energy items by expenditure quintile are displayed in Figure 1.13 Patterns of energy use show a gradual decline in the share of biomass from 3.4% to 2%, and that of kerosene use from 0.3% to 0.08%, across expenditure quintiles. The share of electricity in households’ energy mix however rises sharply from 0.3% to 4.8%, along the expenditure distribution. While the Engel curves are nonlinear for several items (Appendix Figure A1), the EASI model specification we employ is parsimonious and linearly approximates Engel curves for model tractability, and is a limitation of the analysis. Figure 1. Energy expenditure shares by expenditure quintile Note: The X-axis represents expenditure quintiles. Biomass comprises charcoal and firewood. Summary measures for commodity prices are presented in Table 2. We observe significant price variation for most items, in particular kerosene, charcoal, meat & fish and cheese, oils & fats, which ensures reliable econometric identification. The mean expenditure shares and standard deviations for all items by expenditure tercile – rural/urban groups, are presented in Appendix Table A1. 13 12 Table 2. Summary statistics for item-specific prices Item (Unit) Electricity (kWh) Kerosene (L) Charcoal (Kg) Firewood (Bundle) Cereals (Kg) Fruits (Kg) Vegetables (Kg) Meat & Fish (Kg) Milk & Eggs (Kg) Cheese, Oils & Fats (Kg) Alcohol & Tobacco (L) Other Food & Drink (Kg/L) Mean 657.77 2700.67 466.54 77.24 1865.68 955.52 1292.93 5921.61 1163.79 2151.41 2886.99 1590.09 Std. Dev. 33.63 374.66 211.10 21.83 396.93 341.74 415.96 1436.84 320.83 1171.74 653.74 235.21 Min. 623.60 105.68 147.95 35.23 528.40 42.27 211.36 422.72 369.88 132.10 158.52 1044.12 Max. 696.90 4227.19 5529.34 399.23 3593.11 4720.36 2792.96 13209.96 2656.08 13611.54 5748.21 3579.90 Note: Prices are in Ugandan shillings (UgX) per unit. Litre is abbreviated as ‘L’. 4. Econometric Methods We estimate the EASI model as a system of 12 correlated Tobit equations efficiently via the Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) (Hansen 1982; Wooldridge, 2010). A significant proportion of households in the sample report zero consumption expenditure for individual items, such as electricity, due to factors related to energy access, cost of electricity grid connections and availability of cook-stoves. This motivates the use of a corner solution response model. The latent budget share equation, based on Eqn. (2), for good j and household i is: 𝑤𝑖𝑗∗ = 𝑏0𝑗 + 𝑏1𝑗 𝑦̃𝑖 + ∑𝐽𝑘=1 𝑎𝑗𝑘 𝑝𝑘𝑑 + 𝜀̃𝑖𝑗 (13) where 𝜀̃𝑖𝑗 ~𝑁(0, 𝜎𝜀2 ), with the corresponding Tobit Type I model: 𝑤𝑖𝑗 = max(0, 𝑤𝑖𝑗∗ ) where 𝑤𝑖𝑗 is the observed budget share, 𝑦̃𝑖 is the log of real expenditure (nominal expenditure x, deflated by the Consumer Price Index), 𝑝𝑘𝑑 are log prices for commodity k and district d, and 𝜀̃𝑖𝑗 is a normally distributed error term. In compact form, let 𝑤 denote the vector of observed budget shares (𝑤𝑖𝑗 ), X the vector of covariates (𝑦̃, 𝑝𝑘𝑑 ), 𝛽 the vector of coefficients (𝑏0𝑗 , 𝑏1𝑗 , 𝑎𝑗𝑘 ), and let 𝑋𝛽 be the expected value of the latent budget share. 13 Assuming weak exogeneity between the covariates and the error terms, i.e. 𝐸(𝜀̃𝑖𝑗 |𝑋𝑖 ) = 0, we apply the pooled Tobit estimator, which maximizes the partial likelihood for each equation. Given potential correlation between error terms across equations, we estimate the equation system efficiently via GMM, using all covariates as instruments. As each of the covariates is plausibly exogenous, the number of instruments equals the number of regressors, and the model is exactly identified. We define each moment condition as follows: 𝐸[𝑔(𝑤, 𝑋, 𝛽)] = 𝐸[𝑤𝑖𝑗 − 𝐸(𝑤𝑖𝑗 |𝑋)] = 0 The expected value of the observed budget share given covariates X is obtained from the Tobit model as: 𝑋𝛽 𝑋𝛽 𝜀 𝜀 𝐸(𝑤𝑖𝑗 |𝑋) = Ф ( 𝜎 ) 𝑋𝛽 + 𝜎𝜀 𝜑( 𝜎 ) where Ф(. ) is the standard normal cumulative distribution function and 𝜑(. ) is the corresponding probability density function (Wooldridge 2010, pp. 672). Identification of the coefficient vector 𝛽 thus requires a preliminary estimator for 𝜎𝜀 . We estimate each commodity equation distinctly using pooled Tobit and obtain an estimator 𝜎̂𝜀 . From the Law of Large Numbers, the Continuous Mapping Theorem and the Slutsky Theorem, 𝜎̂𝜀 consistently (albeit not efficiently) estimates 𝜎𝜀 . We then implement two-step GMM, taking advantage of cross-equation correlations in the error terms, and impose cross-equation parameter restrictions from consumer theory, to obtain a consistent and efficient estimator for the coefficient vector 𝛽, to solve the minimization problem: min𝑏∈Θ 𝑔̅ (𝑤, 𝑋, 𝑏)′ 𝑊𝑔̅ (𝑤, 𝑋, 𝑏) where 𝑔̅ are the sample analogues of the population moment conditions and 𝑊 is the weight matrix. 5. Results This section presents the estimated elasticities, the welfare impacts of carbon pricing and demand shifts in households’ consumption baskets due to energy and food price increases. We assess all effects for a counterfactual carbon price of US$40/t CO2. This price is the lower 14 bound of the range recommended by the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices to meet the temperature targets of the 2015 UNFCCC Paris Agreement (World Bank 2017). 5.1. Price elasticities of demand The compensated and uncompensated price elasticities of demand for the full sample are presented in Tables 3 and 4, respectively, while Table 5 displays compensated elasticities for energy items for the rural – urban sub-samples. Each cell (row i, column j) represents the percentage change in demand for good i due to a 1% increase in the price of good j. The EASI model coefficients, with z-statistics and standard errors are presented in Appendix Table A2.14 Additional robustness checks for the demand system using an instrumental variable approach for commodity prices, and an alternative pooled cross-sectional dataset from the Uganda National Panel Survey (2009-2020), are presented in Appendix Tables A8 and A9. 5.1.1. Energy items The results show negative own-price compensated elasticities of demand for all items across the sample, with several items like electricity, kerosene and charcoal, being highly price elastic in both rural and urban areas. A 1% increase in the price of charcoal lowers its demand by 3.3% for the average household, and by a considerable 9.6% among rural households. Similarly, a 1% increase in the price of electricity lowers its demand by 12% and 3% in rural and urban areas, respectively, with all effects statistically significant at the 99% confidence level. The uncompensated own-price elasticities of demand (Table 4) are negative for all items and smaller in absolute value than the corresponding compensated elasticities for most items, except for inferior goods (for e.g. kerosene and firewood15). The cross-price elasticities of demand reveal important substitution effects between energy sources. A 1% increase in electricity prices raises kerosene demand by 3.5% in urban areas, while it remains unaffected in rural areas. Similarly, higher electricity prices raise firewood 14 Expenditure elasticities of demand are presented in Table A3, while the full matrices of compensated price elasticities for rural and urban areas are presented in Appendix Tables A4 and A5. Elasticities for the full sample and the rural/urban sub-samples are estimated through nonlinear combinations of the sample-specific estimated regression coefficients, using the ‘nlcom’ command in statistical software Stata. 15 The estimated elasticities may not accurately reflect substitution behavior for firewood due to potentially imprecise measurements of collections from forests and wood-fuel received in-kind. 15 demand across rural and urban regions. On the other hand, firewood is complementary to kerosene use, particularly in rural areas, with the former primarily used for cooking, and the latter for lighting. Charcoal is however substitutable for kerosene, with a 1% increase in kerosene prices raising charcoal demand by 0.14% on average and by 0.1% in urban areas. Charcoal and firewood are net substitutes, with percent increases in charcoal prices increasing firewood demand by 0.1 – 0.5%, across regions. Uncompensated elasticities largely mirror the observed patterns of substitution among fuels. The results broadly corroborate the energy ladder hypothesis, wherein households sequentially “step down the ladder” from modern energy sources such as electricity and kerosene, to traditional biomass in the event of fuel price increases. 16 Table 3. Compensated price elasticities of demand (Full sample) Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other Food & Drink E K C Fw Ce Fr V Me Mi Ch Al O -5.205*** (0.351) 0.112 (0.235) -1.740*** (0.236) 0.941*** (0.114) -0.084*** (0.020) 0.202*** (0.058) 0.070*** (0.008) 0.414*** (0.044) 0.098 (0.092) 0.011 (0.023) -1.596*** (0.125) 0.144*** (0.035) -0.039*** (0.013) 0.003** (0.001) 0.008** (0.004) 0.000 (0.000) 0.006*** (0.002) -0.006 (0.006) -0.556*** (0.076) 0.470*** (0.114) -3.275*** (0.203) 0.099*** (0.027) -0.017*** (0.005) 0.113*** (0.017) 0.043*** (0.002) -0.008 (0.007) 0.17*** (0.028) 0.954*** (0.115) -0.400*** (0.135) 0.315*** (0.085) -1.325*** (0.066) -0.041*** (0.006) -0.046** (0.018) -0.009*** (0.002) -0.008 (0.007) -0.186*** (0.029) -0.759*** (0.184) 0.243** (0.111) -0.472*** (0.140) -0.371*** (0.057) -1.456*** (0.033) 0.311*** (0.073) 0.162*** (0.010) 0.083*** (0.031) 0.054 (0.082) 0.307*** (0.088) 0.120** (0.059) 0.537*** (0.079) -0.069** (0.027) 0.052*** (0.012) -1.821*** (0.048) -0.034*** (0.004) 0.058*** (0.013) 0.224*** (0.048) 1.534*** (0.164) -0.065 (0.089) 2.944*** (0.138) -0.191*** (0.052) 0.388*** (0.025) -0.493*** (0.06) -1.181*** (0.014) -0.366*** (0.030) 0.448*** (0.075) 2.302*** (0.246) 0.318*** (0.108) -0.135 (0.127) -0.042 (0.040) 0.051*** (0.019) 0.213*** (0.048) -0.094*** (0.008) -1.19*** (0.029) 0.385*** (0.072) 0.138 (0.129) -0.091 (0.093) 0.746*** (0.122) -0.258*** (0.041) 0.008 (0.013) 0.208*** (0.044) 0.029*** (0.005) 0.097*** (0.018) -2.767*** (0.099) 0.334*** (0.056) -0.206*** (0.045) 0.265*** (0.053) 0.087*** (0.021) -0.074*** (0.005) 0.060*** (0.016) -0.009*** (0.002) -0.030*** (0.006) 0.108*** (0.025) 0.400** (0.166) 0.916*** (0.084) 1.047*** (0.103) -0.068 (0.119) -0.223*** (0.017) 0.082 (0.058) 0.002 (0.007) 0.075*** (0.022) -0.006 (0.065) -0.459 (0.354) -0.819*** (0.187) -1.377*** (0.232) 0.234 (0.234) 0.393*** (0.029) 0.162 (0.107) 0.021* (0.012) -0.131*** (0.045) 0.478*** (0.130) 0.312*** (0.052) -0.019*** (0.004) 0.079*** (0.016) 0.082*** (0.019) -0.627*** (0.044) 0.086*** (0.022) -0.186*** (0.035) -0.156*** (0.031) 0.142*** (0.032) -1.17*** (0.016) 0.179*** (0.032) 0.278*** (0.065) 0.262** (0.109) 0.059*** (0.005) 0.220*** (0.022) -0.045 (0.079) -1.325*** (0.101) 0.082 (0.057) 0.026 (0.094) 0.274*** (0.080) -0.005 (0.060) 0.126*** (0.022) -2.392*** (0.094) 1.720*** (0.162) -0.067 (0.051) -0.012*** (0.003) -0.064*** (0.011) 0.035 (0.034) 0.518*** (0.039) 0.036 (0.024) 0.068* (0.037) -0.106*** (0.036) 0.098*** (0.027) 0.043*** (0.010) 0.382*** (0.036) -1.930*** (0.104) Note: The items are: Electricity (E), Kerosene (K), Charcoal (C), Firewood (Fw), Cereals (Ce), Fruits (Fr), Vegetables (V), Meat & Fish (Me), Milk & Eggs (Mi), Cheese, Oils & Fats (Ch), Alcohol & Tobacco (Al) and Other food and drink (O). Robust standard errors in parentheses. N = 13,582. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. 17 Table 4. Uncompensated price elasticities of demand (Full sample) Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats E -5.501*** (0.347) 0.364 (0.234) -1.744*** (0.235) 1.101*** (0.114) -0.092*** (0.020) 0.073 (0.058) 0.078*** (0.008) 0.263*** (0.044) -0.096 (0.092) K -0.018 (0.023) -1.572*** (0.125) 0.144*** (0.035) -0.023* (0.013) 0.002 (0.001) -0.005 (0.004) 0.000 (0.000) -0.009*** (0.002) -0.025*** (0.007) C -0.651*** (0.075) 0.551*** (0.115) -3.276*** (0.202) 0.151*** (0.027) -0.019*** (0.005) 0.072*** (0.017) 0.046*** (0.002) -0.056*** (0.007) 0.108*** (0.028) Fw 0.654*** (0.117) -0.144 (0.136) 0.311*** (0.086) -1.163*** (0.067) -0.050*** (0.007) -0.177*** (0.019) -0.001 (0.003) -0.160*** (0.008) -0.382*** (0.031) Ce -3.443*** (0.236) 2.533*** (0.144) -0.509*** (0.164) 1.078*** (0.072) -1.535*** (0.041) -0.862*** (0.095) 0.232*** (0.017) -1.285*** (0.044) -1.706*** (0.109) Fr -0.143 (0.092) 0.503*** (0.061) 0.531*** (0.082) 0.174*** (0.028) 0.039*** (0.013) -2.018*** (0.049) -0.023*** (0.005) -0.171*** (0.014) -0.070 (0.050) V -4.911*** (0.372) 5.433*** (0.233) 2.856*** (0.260) 3.289*** (0.123) 0.198*** (0.067) -3.310*** (0.165) -1.013*** (0.037) -3.651*** (0.084) -3.776*** (0.187) Me 0.655** (0.269) 1.723*** (0.124) -0.158 (0.142) 0.847*** (0.049) 0.002 (0.025) -0.507*** (0.063) -0.051*** (0.011) -2.029*** (0.036) -0.695*** (0.084) Mi -0.278** (0.130) 0.264*** (0.094) 0.740*** (0.123) -0.033 (0.041) -0.004 (0.013) 0.026 (0.045) 0.040*** (0.005) -0.115*** (0.019) -3.040*** (0.099) Ch 0.017 (0.058) 0.064 (0.046) 0.261*** (0.054) 0.258*** (0.021) -0.083*** (0.006) -0.078*** (0.018) -0.001 (0.002) -0.192*** (0.007) -0.100*** (0.026) Al -0.051 (0.171) 1.301*** (0.088) 1.041*** (0.105) 0.176 (0.120) -0.236*** (0.018) -0.115* (0.059) 0.014* (0.007) -0.155*** (0.023) -0.302*** (0.067) O -2.492*** (0.376) 0.916*** (0.196) -1.404*** (0.242) 1.332*** (0.235) 0.332*** (0.034) -0.727*** (0.116) 0.074*** (0.015) -1.168*** (0.051) -0.855*** (0.140) 0.317*** (0.052) -0.018*** (0.004) 0.081*** (0.016) 0.087*** (0.020) -0.582*** (0.055) 0.093*** (0.023) -0.079 (0.089) -0.128*** (0.038) 0.149*** (0.033) -1.165*** (0.017) 0.187*** (0.033) 0.312*** (0.069) Alcohol & 0.183* 0.051*** 0.194*** -0.126 -2.048*** -0.039 -1.711*** -0.170* -0.118* 0.040 -2.513*** 1.172*** Tobacco (0.108) (0.005) (0.022) (0.080) (0.140) (0.059) (0.257) (0.101) (0.061) (0.025) (0.097) (0.174) Other Food & -0.002 -0.005** -0.043*** 0.100*** 1.108*** 0.135*** 1.484*** 0.256*** 0.189*** 0.113*** 0.481*** -1.483*** Drink (0.052) (0.003) (0.011) (0.035) (0.062) (0.025) (0.122) (0.048) (0.027) (0.012) (0.037) (0.106) Note: The items are: Electricity (E), Kerosene (K), Charcoal (C), Firewood (Fw), Cereals (Ce), Fruits (Fr), Vegetables (V), Meat & Fish (Me), Milk & Eggs (Mi), Cheese, Oils & Fats (Ch), Alcohol & Tobacco (Al) and Other food and drink (O). Robust standard errors in parentheses. N = 13,582. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. 18 Table 5. Compensated price elasticities of demand for energy sources (Rural vs. Urban) Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Panel A: Rural Electricity Kerosene Charcoal -11.845*** -0.057 -0.041 (1.027) (0.054) (0.163) -0.287 -1.834*** 0.296 (0.274) (0.183) (0.196) -0.164 0.233 -9.645*** (0.653) (0.155) (0.66) 0.612*** -0.036*** 0.108*** (0.126) (0.012) (0.026) Firewood 1.391*** (0.286) -0.413*** (0.141) 0.982*** (0.237) -1.466*** (0.057) Panel B: Urban Electricity Kerosene -3.108*** 0.133*** (0.319) (0.029) 3.54*** -2.037*** (0.763) (0.264) -0.065 0.089*** (0.191) (0.034) -0.0300 2.422*** (0.435) (0.062) Firewood 0.614*** (0.11) -0.203 (0.42) 0.324*** (0.071) -0.986*** (0.319) N = 9,185 Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Charcoal -0.023 (0.069) 0.852*** (0.324) -1.400*** (0.094) 0.462*** (0.101) N = 4,397 Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. 5.1.2. Food items Energy price hikes have implications for food demand due to complementary patterns of cooking fuel use, and budgetary reallocations within consumption baskets. Electricity price increases simultaneously raise the demand for firewood and for most food groups including vegetables, meat & fish, and fruits, while reducing cereal and charcoal consumption. On the other hand, increases in kerosene prices raise the demand for charcoal, cereals, meat and fish, while reducing the demand for firewood, cheese, oils & fats, and other food & drink. Given the symmetry of substitution effects, food price increases similarly have consequences for biomass demand and create additional shifts in food baskets. Higher vegetable prices simultaneously raise the demand for cereals and charcoal. The increase in vegetable and meat consumption due to higher electricity prices is complementary to firewood use, owing to interdependencies between cooking fuels and the relatively longer cooking times of these items (Treiber et al. 2015). Kerosene price increases, 19 however, modestly raise the demand for cereals and meat & fish, revealing smaller compensating effects for households’ food consumption relative to electricity price increases. These substitution patterns suggest trade-offs between food security and clean fuel use, as fossil fuel price increases could affect household nutrition. 5.2. Welfare effects of carbon pricing The percent price increases in energy and food items resulting from a carbon price of US$40/t CO2 are presented in Table 6. Kerosene and electricity exhibit the largest price hikes (16.4% and 10.2%, respectively),16 while prices for food items rise by less than 1%. Table 6. Price and demand changes due to carbon pricing (US$40/tCO2) Category Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other food & drink Price Increase (%) 10.2 16.4 0 0 0.25 0.17 0.19 0.39 0.22 0.2 0.4 0.25 Demand Change (%) -58.9 -18.8 -14.7 12.6 -1.3 -1.0 0.7 0.3 -3.9 2.7 1.0 0.5 Note: Demand changes (%) are based on the uncompensated price elasticities of demand estimated for the full sample (Table 4). The first- and second-order welfare effects of a carbon price of US$40/t CO2 are highlighted in Figure 2. The average first-order welfare loss is estimated at 0.46% of households’ total expenditure on food and fuel, with progressive distributional effects in the range of 0.17% to 3.5%. Despite the large price increases for electricity and kerosene, their relatively low budget shares generate overall modest welfare effects.17 The average second-order welfare loss is estimated at 0.35% of households’ expenditure on food and fuel, rising steadily from 0.17% to 16 The 10% price increase for electricity is comparable to tariff changes of approximately 8% implemented by the Electricity Regulatory Authority, Uganda between 2017 and 2020. 17 A scatterplot correlating item-wise expenditure shares and percent increases in prices (Appendix Figure A2) reflects this insight. 20 1.8% across the expenditure distribution. The second-order effects are smaller than the firstorder effects at each percentile of the distribution, and drop sharply at the upper tails, reflecting larger substitution possibilities in households’ consumption baskets.18 Figure 2. First- and second-order welfare effects of a US$40/ton carbon price Note: The Y-axis represents the percent change in households’ expenditure on food and fuel. 18 This is due to the combined effect of larger budget shares for fossil fuel-based energy sources among richer households and sizeable compensated price elasticities of demand. 21 Figure 3. Welfare effects of carbon pricing for energy & select food items by expenditure quintile Note: We calculate the average welfare effect for each item, at each percentile, and plot the variation in average effects within expenditure quintiles. Expenditure percentiles are calculated based on households’ total real expenditure. The boxes represent the interquartile range (25th percentile to 75th percentile) and the horizontal line in each box represents the median value. The upper and lower whiskers capture the upper (lower) adjacent values, which are the largest (smallest) observations equal to the value at the third (first) quartile plus (minus) 1.5 times the interquartile range, while all remaining observations, i.e. those above (below) the upper (lower) adjacent values, are excluded from the plot. Decomposing the welfare effects by consumption categories, Figure 3 highlights significant heterogeneity across and within expenditure quintiles for energy and select food items. We find welfare losses along the vertical (i.e. across-quintile) and horizontal (i.e. within-quintile) equity dimensions, with the largest impact for electricity among households in the top quintile, despite overall progressive effects. The indirect welfare loss due to electricity consumption ranges from 0 – 1.6% over the sample, while kerosene consumption generates regressive, albeit modest welfare effects, which is analogous to the decline in budget shares for kerosene across expenditure quintiles (Figure 1). While the welfare loss due to consumption of meat & fish is progressive, the effect for vegetable consumption is largely regressive, as households in the top quintile exhibit proportionately smaller welfare losses. 22 5.3. Shifts in the consumption basket Carbon pricing further creates shifts in the consumption basket, with a staggering reduction in electricity consumption by up to 60%, and declines in kerosene and charcoal demand by 19% and 15%, respectively (Table 6). This is due to the highly price elastic nature of electricity demand (with an own-price uncompensated elasticity of -5.5) and important cross-price effects due to multiple, simultaneous commodity price hikes. However, firewood demand exhibits a 13% increase as a result of a US$40/ton price on carbon emissions, and suggests substitutability between readily available, low-grade biomass, and fossil-based energy sources. The demand for several food items including vegetables, meat & fish, and cheese, oils & fats, similarly increases, by 0.3 – 2.7% for the average household, while consumption of cereals, fruits and milk & eggs declines by 1 – 4% on average. We find disparities in food consumption and nutritional intake due to carbon pricing across expenditure tercile – rural/urban groups, resulting from differences in the composition of households’ food consumption (Figure 4, panels A and B).19 On average, food consumption rises by 0.1%, but ranges from declines of up to 2.3%, to increases of up to 1.7%. Patterns for nutrient intake mirror those for food consumption, with a rise in calorie and micronutrient consumption of 0.15% and 0.23% respectively, for the average household. On the contrary, protein intake declines by 0.1% for the mean household, with impacts ranging from -2.4 to 2.14% across the sample. Impacts vary substantially within expenditure terciles, reflecting the importance of horizontal equity effects. Increases in food consumption and nutrient intake among urban households occur largely due to increased demand for meat & fish and vegetables, concomitantly with greater firewood use. Households in the bottom third of the distribution exhibit large variations in impacts on food security and nutrition. The majority of households in the top tercile in urban areas experience declines in food and protein intake, thus highlighting the role of other demographic and socio-economic characteristics in determining heterogeneous impacts of carbon pricing. Demand changes by expenditure tercile – rural/urban groups are computed from group-specific elasticities, which are derived from the estimated regression coefficients (for the full sample) and the group-specific budget shares and real expenditure for all items. These are presented in Appendix Tables A6.1 – A6.3. 19 23 Figure 4. Percent changes in A) Food and Calorie consumption and B) Protein and Micronutrient intake, due to carbon pricing (US$40/t CO2) Panel A Panel B Note: T1, T2, and T3 refer to the first, second, and third expenditure terciles, respectively, while R and U represent respective rural and urban areas. The boxes represent the interquartile range (25th percentile to 75th percentile), with the horizontal line measuring the median value. The upper and lower whiskers capture the upper (lower) adjacent values, which are the largest (smallest) observations equal to the value at the third (first) quartile plus (minus) 1.5 times the interquartile range, while all remaining observations, i.e. those above (below) the upper (lower) adjacent values, are excluded from the plot. The Y-axis measures the percentage change in household demand due to carbon pricing, relative to baseline demand observed in the survey. 24 6. Discussion Carbon pricing is considered an effective instrument for climate change mitigation and longterm sustainable development. In the SSA context, it could stimulate investments in renewable energy and reduce dependence on carbon-intensive energy infrastructure in the long run. In Uganda alone, a carbon price of US$40/t CO2 could provide revenues to cover one-fifth of the financing requirement for the SDG 2030 Agenda (Franks et al. 2018). However, when designing carbon pricing schemes, potential trade-offs with economic development objectives particularly in low-income countries, need to be taken into account. 6.1. Welfare impacts Previous studies analysing the first-order welfare effects of a carbon price find progressive distributional outcomes for low- and middle-income countries (Dorband et al. 2019; Ohlendorf et al. 2021). Using first- and second-order welfare measures, our results similarly show modest and progressive welfare outcomes across the Ugandan distribution, broadly reinforcing the conclusions of the literature. The paper additionally underscores the impacts of carbon pricing on multidimensional measures of household welfare including energy demand, biomass consumption, and consequences for food and nutrient intake, revealing important interactions between climate policies and economic development. These dimensions have hitherto been neglected in the literature, but are important considerations in the design of socially just and efficient sustainable development policies in the SSA region. Average welfare impacts across the distribution mask substantial heterogeneity of effects within income groups. The recent literature distinguishes between the horizontal (within income) and vertical (across income) equity effects of carbon taxes/cap-and-trade systems, and finds substantial welfare losses and greater variation of impacts within consumption deciles relative to across deciles, albeit with a focus on the United States (Cronin et al. 2019; Fischer and Pizer 2019). In Uganda, accounting for the direct and indirect effects of carbon pricing points to welfare losses along both equity dimensions. Given the prevalence of these hardship cases in all expenditure quintiles, further research is necessary to investigate the factors that determine specific patterns of energy use, consumption expenditures and demand shifts along the distribution. While differential elasticities across expenditure terciles allow for differing demand responses, further disaggregation in estimating price elasticities of demand is important to understand substitution behaviour across households within specified income groups. 25 6.2. Revenue recycling Potential adverse welfare effects can typically be ameliorated through compensation payments and revenue recycling schemes (Douenne 2020). The existing literature finds that the implementation of cash transfer programmes in combination with carbon pricing enhances the progressivity of welfare outcomes in middle-income countries like Mexico and Ecuador (Renner et al. 2018; Schaffitzel et al. 2020). Similar evidence on the direct and indirect welfare impacts of energy subsidy reforms in Latin America and the Caribbean suggests that negative welfare outcomes for the bottom 40 per cent of the population can be alleviated through government transfers utilising only 19 per cent of the collected tax revenue (Feng et al. 2018). For the Ugandan case, we investigate a basic revenue recycling model with the total generated revenue redistributed equally on a per-capita basis to all households via lump sum transfers. Taking into account the short-run demand changes due to energy and food price hikes, the total revenue generated from a US$40/t CO2 price amounts to UgX 90 billion (US$35 million). For 8.5 million Ugandan households, the lump sum transfer is approximately UgX 10,575 (US$3) per household. We find this rebate compensates close to three-quarters of the population for welfare losses accruing due to carbon pricing, yielding net welfare gains of up to 1.6% for these households. On average, households in the bottom expenditure quintile observe the largest net welfare gains of 0.6% of expenditure on average, while households in the top quintile experience welfare losses of 0.25% of expenditure on average. 26 Figure 5. Mean welfare effects of carbon pricing with lump-sum transfers by expenditure quintile Note: The graph depicts average welfare effects for households by expenditure quintile, measured as the percent change in expenditure on food and fuel, due to carbon pricing. In the second scenario, revenues from carbon pricing are redistributed to households via lump-sum transfers, and the scheme generates net average welfare gains for the bottom 60% of the distribution. In addition to alleviating negative welfare effects, cash transfer programmes in SSA countries can further have positive impacts such as stimulating agricultural households to undertake productive activities, fostering arrangements for sharing of food and production inputs within communities, and especially in reducing market failures typically faced by low-income households in SSA (Daidone et al. 2019). In the context of LMICs, providing subsidies for cleaner cooking fuels, such as LPG (Irfan et al. 2018), may prove beneficial in promoting a clean energy transition and reducing indoor air pollution, while ameliorating potential adverse effects on food consumption. Evidence from Indonesia finds that LPG subsidies along with quantity restrictions on kerosene consumption within districts can effectively stimulate largescale fuel transitions. The LPG program lowered the demand for kerosene by 80% over the 2007-2012 period and created positive spillovers on maternal and child health (Imelda 2020). Although LPG use is less prominent in Uganda, expansions in access to fuel efficient cookstoves, for instance via the World Bank-led clean cooking supply chain expansion project, 27 could alleviate pressures on deforestation (World Bank 2021b). The use of charcoal briquettes for fuel, processed from agricultural residue, can similarly reduce the overall demand for charcoal and promote efficient energy use (Kwesiga 2019). 6.3. Substitution and complementary effects in energy use Carbon pricing generates significant shifts in the composition of energy demand in Uganda, with households substituting solid fuels like firewood for electricity. Based on the final changes in demand due to carbon pricing for the average household (Table 6), we compute the potential change in short-run aggregate demand for biomass in Uganda, using household survey weights. Relative to annual production levels (WAVES 2019), we find an aggregate decline in charcoal demand by 2.8% and a 1.6% increase in total firewood consumption.20 These are interpretable as lower bound estimates, given a potentially large unmeasured increase in home produced firewood. Fossil fuel subsidy removal and introduction of a carbon price could thus have implications for the environment through increased fuelwood demand, and potentially aggravate the public health burden due to resulting increases in indoor air pollution (IAP) from biomass burning.21 6.4. Heterogeneous effects on food consumption Energy demand is closely linked to food consumption and dietary composition through the complementary use of cooking fuels. Items with long cooking times such as vegetables and meat & fish are typically cooked with firewood or charcoal, while those with shorter cooking times like milk and tea/coffee could be complementary to kerosene use (Treiber et al. 2015). These complementarities differ by income groups due to differential prices and the availability of fuels in rural vs. urban regions. The relatively higher incomes of urban households enable a large increase in firewood use and increased consumption of nutrient-rich foods like vegetables. In rural areas, the availability of lower grade biomass and consumption of possibly cheaper varieties of meat and fish, ameliorates the negative effects of carbon pricing on food consumption for some households. Nevertheless, around half of the population experiences adverse effects on dietary composition and nutritional intake. This is due to multiple factors including low budget shares for protein- and nutrient-rich food groups, and negative income effects of food and energy price increases. 20 Bundles of firewood recorded in the data are converted to kilograms based on the average weight of a firewood bundle, which is approximately 30 kgs (Albers 2016). 21 In 2017, 400,000 deaths were recorded due to IAP across SSA (Roth et al. 2018). 28 The results are viewed against a background of a large prevalence of nutritional deficiencies among over a quarter of the Ugandan population, despite a marked drop in poverty levels over the 1993-2013 period (Boysen 2016). Carbon pricing without revenue recycling therefore creates welfare losses and could lead to a compounding of pre-existing challenges of food insufficiency and undernutrition, particularly for households around the threshold of poverty. In order to prevent adverse impacts of increased biomass use and stimulate a transition towards cleaner cooking fuels, targeted food security programmes and cash transfers would be required in conjunction with emission pricing policies in Uganda. 6.5. Limitations Our analysis is limited in a number of ways. First, the demand system is parsimonious and does not account for household demographics and other socio-economic characteristics, which would better reflect preference heterogeneity at the individual level. A more granular analysis of household demand responses is also needed to understand shifts in demand patterns and identify households most affected by environmental policies in Uganda. Second, the analysis relies on price data from the year preceding the household expenditure survey, which could be subject to differential time trends across Ugandan sub-regions. While we inflate energy and food prices by the consumer price index, we do not control for regionspecific time trends, for the purpose of model tractability, which qualifies the analysis. Third, while we assume weak separability between broad commodity groups, this may be violated due to complementarities between cooking fuels and certain food items. For example, higher kerosene prices may impact the demand for certain cereals or vegetables differently than others, due to taste preferences, cultural reasons or longer cooking times of specific items. Further, while we assume multi-stage budgeting between consumables (food and energy), durables and other non-durables, we do not compute shifts in the expenditures allocated to food and energy, due to carbon pricing. Hence, for simplicity, we do not simulate carbon prices for durable goods. Fourth, the demand system does not account for households’ access to (and expenditure on) electricity sourced directly from local hydropower or solar power facilities, such as mini-grids or off-grid power, due to lack of survey data on expenditures and related investment costs. If the use of solar/hydropower were modelled in the demand system, we could expect transitions toward their use in the context of carbon pricing, although predictions regarding substitutions between solar power and food consumption cannot be made ex ante. 29 Lastly, the paper does not delve into the multidimensional welfare impacts of carbon pricing, albeit these are important questions for future research. Specifically, future work could analyse firewood collections from forests vis-à-vis market purchases and the complementarities between cooking fuels and food consumption. In a related manner, the time use and market labour supply of women (Imelda 2020; Köhlin et al. 2011), are important policy questions to understand the multifaceted implications of mitigation policies on economic development in SSA. 7. Conclusion This paper investigates the welfare effect on Ugandan households imposed by a carbon price of US$40/t CO2. We estimate a consumer demand system to account for substitution effects between traditional biomass and modern energy, and the effects of energy price changes on food consumption. We identify trade-offs between climate change mitigation and economic development. Our results show substantial reductions in the demand for charcoal, kerosene and electricity by 15% – 59%, and an increase in firewood consumption by 13% on average, in response to carbon pricing. Welfare effects are progressive and reach a maximum of 1.8% of household expenditures on food and fuel, with heterogeneous impacts within and across expenditure quintiles for individual items. The demand system reveals dependencies between food consumption and energy price changes due to the complementary use of cooking fuels. Increases in fossil fuel prices create large shifts in food consumption baskets, with substitution toward vegetables, meat & fish and other food groups, alongside an increase in firewood use. Commodity price increases negatively impact the dietary composition and nutritional intake of around half of the Ugandan population, with disparate effects within expenditure tercile groups. Energy price hikes resulting from a carbon price reveal important trade-offs between access to cleaner fuels and food security, and could have consequences for forest degradation. Climate policies could potentially exacerbate undernutrition for a majority of households, particularly those at the brink of poverty. Combinations of energy and development policies are therefore required to ameliorate these adverse effects and could result in multiple co-benefits for households. Carbon pricing with revenue redistribution could help achieve the twin objectives of long-term sustainable and inclusive economic development in Uganda and the broader SubSaharan African region. 30 Author Contributions (see here) Raavi Aggarwal: Methodology, Software, Formal Analysis, Writing – Original Draft; Sinem Ayhan - ; Michael Jakob - ; Jan Steckel - . References Aguiar, A., Chepeliev, M., Corong, E. L., McDougall, R. and van der Mensbrugghe, D. 2019. The GTAP Data Base: Version 10. Journal of Global Economic Analysis 4 (1): 1-27. Albers, P. 2016. Sustainability: availability, distribution and consumption of firewood near Kidepo Valley national park. Household surveys and forest inventory. Bachelor’s Thesis. Unpublished. Alem, Y. and Demeke, E. 2020. The persistence of energy poverty: A dynamic probit analysis. Energy Economics 90: 104789. Angrist, J. D. and Pischke, J-S. 2008. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist's Companion. Princeton University Press. Attanasio, O., Di Maro, V., Lechene, V. and Phillips, D. 2013. Welfare consequences of food prices increases: Evidence from rural Mexico. Journal of Development Economics 104: 136151. Attanasio, O., Battistin, E. and Mesnard, A. 2011. Food and Cash Transfers: Evidence from Colombia. The Economic Journal 122 (March): 92-124. Banks, J., Blundell, R. and Lewbel, A. 1997. Quadratic Engel Curves and Consumer Demand. The Review of Economics and Statistics 79 (4): 527-539. Banks, J., Blundell, R. and Lewbel, A. 1996. Tax reform and welfare measurement: Do we need demand system estimation? The Economic Journal 106 (438): 1227-1241. Bhuvandas, D. and Gundimeda, H. 2020. Welfare impacts of transport fuel price changes on Indian households: An application of LA-AIDS model. Energy Policy 144: 111583. Boysen, O. 2016. Food Demand Characteristics in Uganda: Estimation and Policy Relevance. South African Journal of Economics 84(2): 260-293. 31 Capéau, B. and Dercon, S. 2006. Prices, Unit Values and Local Measurement Units in Rural Surveys: an Econometric Approach with an Application to Poverty Measurement in Ethiopia. Journal of African Economies 15(2): 181-211. Chamberlain, G. 1984. "Panel data," Handbook of Econometrics, in: Z. Griliches & M. D. Intriligator (ed.), Handbook of Econometrics, edition 1, volume 2, chapter 22, pages 1247-1318 Elsevier. Chamberlain, G. 1980. Analysis of Covariance with Qualitative Data, The Review of Economic Studies, Volume 47, Issue 1, 1980, Pages 225–238. Cronin, J.A., Fullerton, D. and Sexton, S. 2019. Vertical and Horizontal Redistributions from a Carbon Tax and Rebate. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 6(S1): S169 - S208. Daidone, S., Davis, B., Handa, S. and Winters, P. 2019. The household and individual-level productive impacts of cash transfer programs in Sub-Saharan Africa. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 101(5): 1401-1431. Deaton, A. and Muellbauer, J. 1980. An Almost Ideal Demand System. The American Economic Review 70 (3): 312-326. Deaton, A. and Zaidi, S. 2002. Guidelines for Constructing Consumption Aggregates for Welfare Analysis. World Bank LSMS Working Paper No. 135. Dorband, I., Jakob, M., Kalkuhl, M. and Steckel, J. C. 2019. Poverty and distributional effects of carbon pricing in low- and middle-income countries – A global comparative analysis. World Development 115: 246-257. Douenne, T. 2020. The Vertical and Horizontal Distributive Effects of Energy Taxes: A Case Study of a French Policy. The Energy Journal 41(3). Ecker, O. and Qaim, M. 2011. Analyzing Nutritional Impacts of Policies: An Empirical Study for Malawi. World Development 39(3). Eisner, A., Kulmer, V. and Kortschak, D. 2021. Distributional effects of carbon pricing when considering household heterogeneity: An EASI application for Austria. Energy Policy Volume 156, September 2021, 112478. 32 Feng, K., Hubacek, K., Liu, Y., Marchán, E. and Vogt-Schilb, A. 2018. Managing the distributional effects of energy taxes and subsidy removal in Latin America and the Caribbean. Applied Energy 225: 424-436. Fischer, C. and Pizer, W. 2019. Horizontal Equity Effects in Energy Regulation. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 6(S1): S209 - S237. Franks, M., Lessmann, K., Jakob, M., Steckel, J. C. and Edenhofer, O. 2018. Mobilizing domestic resources for the Agenda 2030 via carbon pricing. Nature Sustainability 1(7): 350357. Fuje, H. 2019. Fossil fuel subsidy reforms, spatial market integration, and welfare: Evidence from a natural experiment in Ethiopia. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 101(1): 270-290. Government of Uganda. 2015. Uganda’s Intended Nationally Determined Contribution (INDC). Ministry of Water and Environment. Accessible at < https://www4.unfccc.int/sites/ndcstaging/PublishedDocuments/Uganda%20First/INDC%20U ganda%20final%20%2014%20October%20%202015.pdf> Greve, H. and Lay, J. 2020. Stepping down the ladder: The unintended impacts of fossil fuel subsidy removal in a developing country. European Association of Environmental and Resource Economists (EAERE) Conference Paper 2020. Guta, D. 2012. Application of an almost ideal demand system (AIDS) to Ethiopian rural residential energy use: panel data evidence. Energy Policy 50: 528-539. Hansen, L. P. 1982. Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimators. Econometrica Vol. 50, No. 4, pp. 1029-1054. IEA, IRENA, UNSD, World Bank, and WHO. 2020. Tracking SDG 7: The Energy Progress Report. World Bank, Washington DC. Imelda. 2020. Cooking that kills: Cleaner energy access, indoor air pollution, and health. Journal of Development Economics 147 (2020) 102548. Irfan, M., Cameron, M. P. and Hassan, G. 2018. Household energy elasticities and policy implications for Pakistan. Energy Policy 113: 633-642. 33 Jakubson, G. 1988. The Sensitivity of Labor-Supply Parameter Estimates to Unobserved Individual Effects: Fixed- and Random-Effects Estimates in a Nonlinear Model Using Panel Data. Journal of Labor Economics 6(3): Jul, 1988. Jewell, J., McCollum, D., Emmerling, J., Bertram, C., Gernaat, D., Krey, V., Paroussos, L. et al. 2018. Limited emission reductions from fuel subsidy removal except in energy-exporting regions. Nature 554 (7691): 229-233. Köhlin, G., Sills, E. O., Pattanayak, S. K. and Wilfong, C. 2011. Energy, Gender and Development: What are the Linkages? Where is the Evidence? The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper 5800. Kwesiga, C. 2019. Charcoal briquettes – affordable, clean energy for Uganda. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Regional Workshop on Promoting Cotton ByProducts in Eastern and Southern Africa. Accessible at < https://unctad.org/system/files/nonofficial-document/Cotton_SA_May2019_S4_Charles_Kwesiga.pdf> Lewbel, Arthur, and Krishna Pendakur. 2009. "Tricks with Hicks: The EASI Demand System." American Economic Review, 99 (3): 827-63. Masera, O., Bailis, R., Drigo, R., Ghilardi, A. and Ruiz-Mercado, I. 2015. Environmental Burden of Traditional Bioenergy Use. Annual Review of Environment and Resources 40(1): 121-150. Mattauch, L., Creutzig, F. and Edenhofer, O. 2015. Avoiding Carbon Lock-In: Policy Options for Advancing Structural Change. Economic Modelling 50: 49-63. MEMD, 2015. National Charcoal Survey for Uganda 2015. Final Report. Accessible at <http://unreeea.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/10/National-Charcoal-Survey_uganda.pdf> Meyerhoefer, C. D., Ranney, C. K. and Sahn, D. E. 2005. Consistent Estimation of Censored Demand Systems Using Panel Data. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 87(3): pp. 660-672. Ohlendorf, N., Jakob, M., Minx, J.C. et al. 2021. Distributional Impacts of Carbon Pricing: A Meta-Analysis. Environmental and Resource Economics 78: 1-42. Okonkwo, J. U. 2021. Welfare effects of carbon taxation on South African households. Energy Economics 96, April 2021, 104903. 34 Olabisi, M., Tschirley, D. L., Nyange, D. and Awokuse, T. 2019. Energy demand substitution from biomass to imported kerosene: Evidence from Tanzania. Energy Policy 130: 243-252. Pratiti, R., Vadala, D., Kalynych, Z. and Sud, P. 2020. Health effects of household air pollution related to biomass cook stoves in resource limited countries and its mitigation by improved cookstoves. Environmental Research 186: 109574. Reaños, M. and Wölfing, N. 2018. Household energy prices and inequality: Evidence from German microdata based on the EASI demand system. Energy Economics 70: 84-97. Renner, S., Lay, J. and Greve, H. 2018. Household Welfare and CO2 Emission Impacts of Energy and Carbon Taxes in Mexico. Energy Economics 72: 222-235. Renner, S. 2018. Poverty and distributional effects of a carbon tax in Mexico. Energy Policy 112: 98-110. Roth, Gregory A, Degu Abate, Kalkidan Hassen Abate, Solomon M Abay, Cristiana Abbafati, Nooshin Abbasi, Hedayat Abbastabar, et al. 2018. Global, regional, and national age-sexspecific mortality for 282 causes of death in 195 countries and territories, 1980-2017: a systematic analysis for the Global Burden of Disease Study 2017. The Lancet 392 (10159): 1736-1788. Schaffitzel, F., Jakob, M., Soria, R., Vogt-Schilb, A. and Ward, H. 2019. Can government transfers make energy subsidy reform socially acceptable? A case study on Ecuador. Energy Policy 137: 111120. Somanathan E., T. Sterner, T. Sugiyama, D. Chimanikire, N.K. Dubash, J. Essandoh-Yeddu, S. Fifita, L. Goulder, A. Jaffe, X. Labandeira, S. Managi, C. Mitchell, J.P. Montero, F. Teng, and T. Zylicz, 2014: National and Sub-national Policies and Institutions. In: Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of Climate Change. Contribution of Working Group III to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change [Edenhofer, O., R. Pichs-Madruga, Y. Sokona, E. Farahani, S. Kadner, K. Seyboth, A. Adler, I. Baum, S. Brunner, P. Eickemeier, B. Kriemann, J. Savolainen, S. Schlömer, C. von Stechow, T. Zwickel and J.C. Minx (eds.)]. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, United Kingdom and New York, NY, USA. Steckel, J. C., Hilaire, J., Jakob, M. and Edenhofer, O. 2020. Coal and carbonization in subSaharan Africa. Nature Climate Change 10(1): 83-88. 35 Sterner, T. 2012. Fuel taxes and the poor: the distributional effects of gasoline taxation and their implications for climate policy. Resources for the Future (RFF) Press. Stone, R. (1954) Linear Expenditure Systems and Demand Analysis: An Application to the Pattern of British Demand. The Economic Journal, 64, 511-527. Treiber, M. U., Grimsby, L. K. and Aune, J. B. 2015. Reducing energy poverty through increasing choice of fuels and stoves in Kenya: Complementing the multiple fuel model. Energy for Sustainable Development 27: 54-62. UBOS. 2018. Uganda National Household Survey 2016/2017. Uganda Bureau of Statistics, Kampala, Uganda. UNFCCC. 2016. Uganda’s Intended Nationally Determined Contribution (INDC). October 2015. Accessible at <https://www4.unfccc.int/sites/ndcstaging/PublishedDocuments/Uganda%20First/INDC%20 Uganda%20final%20%2014%20October%20%202015.pdf> van der Ploeg, R., Rezai, A. and Tovar, M. 2021. GATHERING SUPPORT FOR GREEN TAX REFORM: Evidence from German Household Surveys. European Economic Review, Available online 17 November 2021, 103966. WAVES. 2019. Uganda Woodfuels Overview: Technical Report. Ministry of Water & Environment (Republic of Uganda) and the World Bank. Accessible at < https://www.wavespartnership.org/sites/waves/files/kc/WAVESWoodfuel%20Overview%20-Technical%20Report%20Design%20Layout%20Final%20October.pdf> Wooldridge, J. M. 2010. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, Second Edition. MIT Press, Cambridge, USA. World Bank. 2021a. State and Trends of Carbon Pricing 2021. Washington, DC: World Bank. Accessible at <https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/35620> World Bank. 2021b. Quality, Efficient Biomass Stoves Reach Ugandan Households via Strengthened Supply Chains. Washington, DC: World Bank. Accessible at < https://documents1.worldbank.org/curated/en/825841615961218428/pdf/Quality-EfficientBiomass-Stoves-Reach-Ugandan-Households-via-Strengthened-Supply-Chains.pdf> 36 World Bank. 2017. Report of the High-Level Commission on Carbon Prices. Washington, DC: World Bank. Yaméogo, N. D. 2015. Household Energy Demand and the Impact of Energy Prices: Evidence from Senegal. African Development Bank Group, Working Paper 218. Zhen, C., Finkelstein, E. A., Nonnemaker, J. M., Karns, S. A. and Todd, J. E. 2013. Predicting the Effects of Sugar-Sweetened Beverage Taxes on Food and Beverage Demand in a Large Demand System. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 96(1): 1-25. 37 Appendix A. Data preparation and Descriptive Statistics This section presents additional details of the commodity price data, and additional descriptive statistics. Market prices for food and energy items reported by households in the Uganda National Panel Survey (UNPS, World Bank LSMS), 2015-16, are expressed in various units, including nonstandard units with no available metric conversion factors. We first convert the majority of unit codes for which metric conversions are available, into kilograms for food items and charcoal, bundles for firewood, and litre for kerosene. Next, we plot the mean price for each item and unit code, to detect potential outlier unit codes, We omit unit codes with prices in the order of 5-10 times the mean price for a specific item. The remaining unit codes are not converted. Hence, prices are reported in kilogram and litre for the majority of the sample, while the remaining observations contain prices reported in non-standard units such as bundles and heaps of firewood. Therefore, the price variation observed in Table 2, partly reflects differences in unit codes of reporting. However, graphical inspection of the range of prices per item, for different unit codes, suggests that only a handful of unit codes reflect outlier values for prices. Further, we subsequently compute and analyse elasticities, which negate differences arising due to measurement units. 38 Table A1: Item-wise expenditure shares (%) by expenditure tercile and rural-urban areas Item Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other Food & Drink N Tercile 1 – Rural Mean Std. Dev. 0.28 1.790 0.29 0.413 0.21 0.840 3.09 2.817 18.28 17.311 2.51 4.619 48.26 23.644 8.25 10.265 1.59 3.784 2.10 2.449 3.31 6.634 11.84 21.411 3,638 Tercile 1 – Urban Mean Std. Dev. 1.36 3.559 0.29 0.436 1.03 1.683 2.06 2.791 18.40 16.330 2.02 3.895 39.59 24.702 6.92 8.913 1.80 3.971 2.52 2.533 3.03 6.676 20.98 28.461 883 Tercile 2 – Rural Mean Std. Dev. 0.86 3.105 0.21 0.310 0.29 0.890 2.29 2.195 17.20 14.612 3.22 4.875 47.91 20.352 11.57 11.865 2.58 4.548 2.01 1.945 2.73 5.890 9.13 15.162 3,135 Tercile 2 – Urban Mean Std. Dev. 2.85 4.715 0.16 0.311 1.46 1.654 0.92 1.756 18.27 14.102 2.41 3.939 34.48 21.186 10.17 10.770 2.77 4.474 2.37 2.102 2.99 6.075 21.16 26.480 1,386 Tercile 3 – Rural Mean Std. Dev. 2.61 5.390 0.12 0.230 0.34 0.850 1.77 1.884 17.17 12.533 3.78 4.870 43.00 18.364 13.63 11.718 3.65 4.870 1.86 1.734 2.79 5.459 9.29 13.600 2,405 Tercile 3 – Urban Mean Std. Dev. 5.33 6.210 0.07 0.197 1.43 1.368 0.51 1.202 17.35 11.517 3.18 4.211 30.59 17.372 13.28 10.944 4.31 4.943 2.09 1.695 2.95 5.673 18.90 21.624 2,115 39 Figure A1. Item-specific Engel Curves Note: The X-axis represents the household’s log of Expenditure on Food and Energy items, modelled in the demand system. While the Engel curves are nonlinear for several items, the EASI model specification we employ is parsimonious and linearly approximates Engel curves for model tractability, and is a limitation of the analysis. 40 D. Derivation (Section 2.3): Proportionate change in quantity demanded Consider a Marshallian demand function 𝑓𝑖 for commodity i, as a function of the J-vector of prices q, and total household expenditure x: 𝑓𝑖 = 𝑓𝑖 (𝑞1 , 𝑞2 , … 𝑞𝑖 , … , 𝑞𝐽 ; 𝑥) The differential of 𝑓𝑖 is expressed as: 𝜕𝑓 𝜕𝑓 𝑑𝑓𝑖 = 𝜕𝑞 𝑖 𝑑𝑞1 + ⋯ + 𝜕𝑞 𝑖 𝑑𝑞𝐽 + 1 𝜕𝑓𝑖 𝜕𝑥 𝐽 𝑑𝑥 Now we consider changes in all commodities’ prices, holding total expenditure x constant (hence dx = 0), and compute the proportionate change in quantity demanded for good i: 𝑑𝑓𝑖 𝑓𝑖 𝜕𝑓 𝑞1 𝑑𝑞1 = 𝜕𝑞 𝑖 1 𝑓𝑖 𝑞1 𝜕𝑓 𝑞 𝑑𝑞𝐽 + ⋯ + 𝜕𝑞 𝑖 𝑓𝐽 𝐽 𝑖 𝑞𝐽 For small price changes around the initial demand vector, this can be approximated in elasticity form, as follows: ∆𝑓𝑖 𝑓𝑖 ≈ 𝑒 𝑢𝑓𝑖 ,𝑞1 ∆𝑞1 𝑞1 + ⋯ + 𝑒 𝑢𝑓𝑖 ,𝑞𝐽 ≈ ∑𝐽𝑗=1 𝑒 𝑢𝑓𝑖 ,𝑞𝑗 ∆𝑞𝐽 𝑞𝐽 ∆𝑞𝑗 𝑞𝑗 41 Table A2: EASI Model Regression Coefficients (Full Sample, N = 13,582) Parameter Coefficient Std. Error Z-Statistic P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval] b0_1 -0.421 0.017 -25.18 0.000 -0.454 -0.388 b0_2 b0_3 0.028 -0.016 0.001 0.003 27.06 -4.93 0.000 0.000 0.026 -0.023 0.030 -0.010 b0_4 b0_5 0.225 0.297 0.017 0.026 13.59 11.66 0.000 0.000 0.193 0.247 0.258 0.347 b0_6 -0.187 0.016 -11.86 0.000 -0.218 -0.156 b0_7 b0_8 1.089 -0.579 0.034 0.020 32.11 -28.95 0.000 0.000 1.022 -0.618 1.155 -0.540 b0_9 b0_10 -0.245 0.058 0.011 0.004 -22.03 14.08 0.000 0.000 -0.267 0.050 -0.223 0.066 b0_11 b0_12 -0.049 0.800 0.017 0.041 -2.94 19.31 0.003 0.000 -0.082 0.718 -0.016 0.881 b1_1 0.028 0.002 18.05 0.000 0.025 0.031 b2_1 b3_1 -0.003 -0.001 0.000 0.000 -28.18 -1.63 0.000 0.104 -0.003 -0.001 -0.003 0.000 b4_1 b5_1 -0.019 -0.010 0.001 0.003 -36.02 -3.93 0.000 0.000 -0.020 -0.015 -0.018 -0.005 b6_1 0.017 0.001 16.03 0.000 0.015 0.019 b7_1 b8_1 -0.061 0.075 0.003 0.002 -17.93 37.42 0.000 0.000 -0.067 0.071 -0.054 0.079 b9_1 b10_1 0.025 -0.003 0.001 0.000 23.09 -6.61 0.000 0.000 0.023 -0.003 0.027 -0.002 b11_1 b12_1 0.009 -0.060 0.002 0.004 5.63 -16.19 0.000 0.000 0.006 -0.067 0.013 -0.052 a1_1 -0.082 0.007 -12.00 0.000 -0.095 -0.069 a2_2 a3_3 -0.001 -0.014 0.000 0.001 -4.76 -11.22 0.000 0.000 -0.002 -0.017 -0.001 -0.012 a4_4 a5_5 -0.006 -0.081 0.001 0.006 -4.90 -13.82 0.000 0.000 -0.009 -0.092 -0.004 -0.069 a6_6 a7_7 -0.024 -0.077 0.001 0.006 -17.04 -12.94 0.000 0.000 -0.027 -0.089 -0.022 -0.065 a8_8 -0.021 0.003 -6.63 0.000 -0.027 -0.015 a9_9 a10_10 -0.049 -0.004 0.003 0.000 -17.79 -10.39 0.000 0.000 -0.054 -0.004 -0.043 -0.003 a11_11 a12_12 -0.041 -0.125 0.003 0.014 -14.75 -8.98 0.000 0.000 -0.047 -0.152 -0.036 -0.098 a1_2 0.000 0.000 0.48 0.634 -0.001 0.001 a1_3 a1_4 -0.011 0.019 0.001 0.002 -7.37 8.28 0.000 0.000 -0.014 0.014 -0.008 0.023 a1_5 a1_6 -0.015 0.006 0.004 0.002 -4.12 3.49 0.000 0.000 -0.022 0.003 -0.008 0.009 a1_7 a1_8 0.030 0.045 0.003 0.005 9.37 9.36 0.000 0.000 0.024 0.036 0.036 0.054 42 a1_9 0.003 0.003 1.07 0.284 -0.002 0.008 a1_10 a1_11 0.007 0.008 0.001 0.003 5.99 2.42 0.000 0.016 0.004 0.001 0.009 0.014 a2_3 0.001 0.000 4.11 0.000 0.000 0.001 a2_4 a2_5 -0.001 0.000 0.000 0.000 -2.96 2.18 0.003 0.029 -0.001 0.000 0.000 0.001 a2_6 a2_7 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 2.03 -0.74 0.042 0.462 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 a2_8 0.001 0.000 2.94 0.003 0.000 0.001 a2_9 a2_10 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.98 -4.57 0.327 0.000 -0.001 -0.001 0.000 0.000 a2_11 a3_4 0.002 0.002 0.000 0.001 10.93 3.69 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.003 a3_5 a3_6 -0.003 0.003 0.001 0.000 -3.38 6.78 0.001 0.000 -0.005 0.002 -0.001 0.004 a3_7 0.018 0.001 21.37 0.000 0.017 0.020 a3_8 a3_9 -0.001 0.005 0.001 0.001 -1.07 6.13 0.286 0.000 -0.002 0.003 0.001 0.006 a3_10 a3_11 0.002 0.007 0.000 0.001 4.97 10.20 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.005 0.002 0.008 a4_5 -0.007 0.001 -6.46 0.000 -0.010 -0.005 a4_6 a4_7 -0.001 -0.004 0.001 0.001 -2.55 -3.70 0.011 0.000 -0.002 -0.006 0.000 -0.002 a4_8 a4_9 -0.001 -0.005 0.001 0.001 -1.07 -6.32 0.287 0.000 -0.002 -0.007 0.001 -0.004 a4_10 a4_11 0.002 -0.001 0.000 0.002 4.25 -0.57 0.000 0.568 0.001 -0.006 0.003 0.003 a5_6 0.009 0.002 4.27 0.000 0.005 0.013 a5_7 a5_8 0.069 0.009 0.004 0.003 15.47 2.67 0.000 0.008 0.060 0.002 0.077 0.016 a5_9 a5_10 0.001 -0.013 0.002 0.001 0.65 -14.31 0.516 0.000 -0.003 -0.015 0.006 -0.011 a5_11 -0.039 0.003 -13.06 0.000 -0.045 -0.034 a6_7 a6_8 -0.015 0.006 0.002 0.001 -8.16 4.43 0.000 0.000 -0.018 0.004 -0.011 0.009 a6_9 a6_10 0.006 0.002 0.001 0.000 4.69 3.83 0.000 0.000 0.004 0.001 0.009 0.003 a6_11 a7_8 0.002 -0.040 0.002 0.003 1.43 -12.27 0.153 0.000 -0.001 -0.046 0.006 -0.033 a7_9 0.012 0.002 5.99 0.000 0.008 0.016 a7_10 a7_11 -0.004 0.001 0.001 0.003 -5.28 0.27 0.000 0.785 -0.005 -0.005 -0.002 0.006 a8_9 a8_10 0.011 -0.003 0.002 0.001 5.38 -5.03 0.000 0.000 0.007 -0.005 0.014 -0.002 a8_11 0.008 0.002 3.41 0.001 0.003 0.013 a9_10 0.003 0.001 4.39 0.000 0.002 0.004 43 a9_11 0.000 0.002 -0.09 0.927 -0.004 0.003 a10_11 a1_12 0.004 -0.009 0.001 0.007 5.63 -1.30 0.000 0.194 0.002 -0.022 0.005 0.005 a2_12 -0.002 0.000 -4.39 0.000 -0.002 -0.001 a3_12 a4_12 -0.009 0.005 0.001 0.005 -5.93 1.00 0.000 0.316 -0.011 -0.004 -0.006 0.014 a5_12 a6_12 0.069 0.005 0.005 0.003 13.44 1.52 0.000 0.128 0.059 -0.001 0.080 0.011 a7_12 0.009 0.005 1.85 0.065 -0.001 0.019 a8_12 a9_12 -0.014 0.013 0.005 0.004 -2.94 3.68 0.003 0.000 -0.024 0.006 -0.005 0.020 a10_12 a11_12 0.006 0.051 0.001 0.005 4.29 10.65 0.000 0.000 0.003 0.042 0.008 0.061 Table A3. Expenditure elasticities of demand (Full Sample) Item Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other Food & Drink Expenditure Elasticity 15.16*** (0.784) -12.94*** (0.494) 0.21 (0.488) -8.19*** (0.255) 0.45*** (0.140) 6.63*** (0.351) -0.40*** (0.078) 7.73*** (0.180) 9.94*** (0.387) -0.25 (0.190) 4.08*** (0.548) -3.33*** (0.268) Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. N = 13,582. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. 44 Table A4: Compensated price elasticities of demand (Rural Sample) Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other Food & Drink E K C Fw Ce Fr V Me Mi Ch Al O -11.845*** (1.027) -0.287 (0.274) -0.164 (0.653) 0.612*** (0.126) -0.118*** (0.024) 0.159* (0.085) -0.024*** (0.008) 0.510*** (0.064) 0.002 (0.151) 0.898*** (0.083) 0.354* (0.181) 0.464*** (0.098) -0.057 (0.054) -1.834*** (0.183) 0.233 (0.155) -0.036*** (0.012) 0.004*** (0.001) 0.011** (0.005) 0.001* (0) 0.01*** (0.002) 0.027*** (0.009) -0.018*** (0.005) 0.069*** (0.006) -0.021*** (0.004) -0.041 (0.163) 0.296 (0.196) -9.645*** (0.66) 0.108*** (0.026) 0.001 (0.005) 0.071*** (0.016) 0.013*** (0.002) -0.028*** (0.006) 0.160*** (0.044) -0.090*** (0.015) 0.180*** (0.032) 0.077*** (0.012) 1.391*** (0.286) -0.413*** (0.141) 0.982*** (0.237) -1.466*** (0.057) -0.060*** (0.007) 0.000 (0.022) 0.016*** (0.003) 0.015* (0.008) -0.109*** (0.038) 0.204*** (0.022) 0.323*** (0.11) -0.146** (0.063) -1.921*** (0.384) 0.312*** (0.112) 0.061 (0.334) -0.427*** (0.05) -1.514*** (0.037) 0.283*** (0.088) 0.136*** (0.011) 0.111*** (0.035) 0.180* (0.108) -0.666*** (0.052) -1.481*** (0.117) 0.879*** (0.06) 0.451* (0.242) 0.161** (0.07) 0.801*** (0.186) 0.000 (0.028) 0.049*** (0.015) -2.431*** (0.061) -0.006 (0.005) 0.118*** (0.017) 0.275*** (0.064) 0.051* (0.028) -0.084 (0.078) 0.125*** (0.043) -1.048*** (0.344) 0.181* (0.096) 2.172*** (0.305) 0.300*** (0.052) 0.360*** (0.03) -0.092 (0.076) -1.110*** (0.015) -0.267*** (0.034) 0.930*** (0.112) -0.139*** (0.047) 0.985*** (0.128) -0.317*** (0.062) 5.063*** (0.634) 0.486*** (0.123) -1.108*** (0.255) 0.066* (0.034) 0.068*** (0.022) 0.412*** (0.058) -0.062*** (0.008) -1.362*** (0.032) 0.309*** (0.078) -0.213*** (0.033) 0.475*** (0.097) -0.284*** (0.066) 0.004 (0.344) 0.306*** (0.105) 1.449*** (0.404) -0.110*** (0.038) 0.025* (0.015) 0.221*** (0.052) 0.049*** (0.006) 0.071*** (0.018) -4.570*** (0.138) -0.103*** (0.04) -0.003 (0.064) 0.455*** (0.041) 1.660*** (0.153) -0.170*** (0.048) -0.660*** (0.114) 0.166*** (0.018) -0.076*** (0.006) 0.033* (0.018) -0.006*** (0.002) -0.040*** (0.006) -0.084*** (0.032) -1.345*** (0.02) 0.077*** (0.024) 0.060*** (0.018) 0.970* (0.497) 0.951*** (0.086) 1.970*** (0.352) 0.390*** (0.132) -0.250*** (0.02) -0.081 (0.075) 0.063*** (0.008) 0.131*** (0.027) -0.003 (0.077) 0.114*** (0.036) -2.776*** (0.097) 0.256*** (0.064) 4.373*** (0.92) -0.989*** (0.21) 2.907*** (0.453) -0.604** (0.26) 0.511*** (0.035) 0.414*** (0.142) -0.069*** (0.014) -0.269*** (0.063) 1.885*** (0.171) 0.307*** (0.09) 0.881*** (0.219) -2.549*** (0.179) Note: The items are - Electricity (E), Kerosene (K), Charcoal (C), Firewood (Fw), Cereals (Ce), Fruits (Fr), Vegetables (V), Meat & Fish (Me), Milk & Eggs (Mi), Cheese, Oils & Fats (Ch), Alcohol & Tobacco (Al) and Other food and drink (O). Robust standard errors in parentheses. N = 9,185. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. 45 Table A5: Compensated price elasticities of demand (Urban Sample) Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other Food & Drink E K C Fw Ce Fr V Me Mi Ch Al O -3.108*** (0.319) 3.54*** (0.763) -0.065 (0.191) 2.422*** (0.435) 0.119** (0.047) -0.116 (0.097) 0.160*** (0.015) 0.067 (0.061) 0.142 (0.133) 0.470*** (0.089) -0.580** (0.224) -0.127** (0.057) 0.133*** (0.029) -2.037*** (0.264) 0.089*** (0.034) -0.0300 (0.062) -0.015*** (0.004) 0.026*** (0.008) -0.002 (0.001) -0.013** (0.005) -0.01 (0.011) 0.016* (0.009) 0.040** (0.017) -0.009** (0.004) -0.023 (0.069) 0.852*** (0.324) -1.400*** (0.094) 0.462*** (0.101) -0.019 (0.013) 0.078*** (0.029) 0.054*** (0.005) 0.009 (0.016) 0.125*** (0.033) 0.175*** (0.032) -0.232*** (0.048) -0.091*** (0.013) 0.614*** (0.11) -0.203 (0.42) 0.324*** (0.071) -0.986*** (0.319) -0.061*** (0.02) -0.118*** (0.034) 0.007 (0.007) -0.070*** (0.025) -0.233*** (0.049) -0.046 (0.04) -0.089 (0.173) 0.017 (0.048) 0.563** (0.221) -1.863*** (0.45) -0.253 (0.17) -1.136*** (0.376) -1.534*** (0.095) 0.728*** (0.15) 0.232*** (0.026) -0.189** (0.091) -0.244 (0.159) -0.246*** (0.092) -1.687*** (0.286) 0.389*** (0.072) -0.084 (0.07) 0.492*** (0.161) 0.156*** (0.057) -0.335*** (0.095) 0.110*** (0.023) -0.431*** (0.111) -0.088*** (0.01) 0.028 (0.032) -0.078 (0.064) 0.029 (0.035) 0.545*** (0.103) -0.097*** (0.03) 1.434*** (0.138) -0.364 (0.280) 1.327*** (0.114) 0.249 (0.240) 0.437*** (0.048) -1.088*** (0.121) -0.919*** (0.036) -0.438*** (0.063) -0.514*** (0.123) -0.308*** (0.061) -3.042*** (0.215) 0.066 (0.056) 0.198 (0.178) -1.016** (0.392) 0.076 (0.132) -0.812*** (0.288) -0.117** (0.056) 0.112 (0.129) -0.144*** (0.021) 0.186* (0.102) -0.035 (0.134) -0.256*** (0.08) -1.307*** (0.234) -0.09 (0.062) 0.125 (0.117) -0.232 (0.268) 0.304*** (0.08) -0.809*** (0.171) -0.045 (0.03) -0.096 (0.079) -0.051*** (0.012) -0.011 (0.04) 0.153 (0.133) 0.308*** (0.05) 0.08 (0.147) -0.097*** (0.036) 0.283*** (0.053) 0.258* (0.14) 0.292*** (0.053) -0.11 (0.095) -0.031*** (0.012) 0.024 (0.029) -0.021*** (0.004) -0.053*** (0.016) 0.211*** (0.034) -0.854*** (0.032) 0.015 (0.055) -0.035** (0.014) -0.459** (0.177) 0.832** (0.357) -0.508*** (0.105) -0.278 (0.54) -0.281*** (0.048) 0.6*** (0.113) -0.269*** (0.019) -0.353*** (0.063) 0.072 (0.132) 0.02 (0.072) 6.376*** (0.36) -0.167*** (0.059) -0.676** (0.303) -1.259** (0.628) -1.34*** (0.198) 0.362 (1.01) 0.436*** (0.08) -0.719*** (0.225) 0.039 (0.033) -0.164 (0.113) -0.588*** (0.216) -0.309** (0.12) -1.121*** (0.399) -0.759*** (0.144) Note: The items are - Electricity (E), Kerosene (K), Charcoal (C), Firewood (Fw), Cereals (Ce), Fruits (Fr), Vegetables (V), Meat & Fish (Me), Milk & Eggs (Mi), Cheese, Oils & Fats (Ch), Alcohol & Tobacco (Al) and Other food and drink (O). Robust standard errors in parentheses. N = 4,397. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. 46 Table A6.1: Uncompensated price elasticities of demand: Expenditure Tercile - I E Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other Food & Drink K Rural (N = 3,638) -30.871 -0.195 0.096 -1.376 -5.167 0.432 0.615 -0.012 -0.082 0.001 0.219 -0.012 0.062 0.000 0.519 -0.019 0.127 -0.056 0.311 -0.018 0.226 0.042 -0.066 -0.003 C Fw Ce Fr V Me Mi Ch Al O -4.117 0.330 -7.757 0.073 -0.017 0.119 0.038 -0.030 0.261 0.079 0.190 -0.065 3.781 -0.027 0.974 -1.068 -0.055 -0.279 -0.003 -0.299 -0.802 0.087 -0.152 0.151 -22.704 1.581 -1.180 0.592 -1.532 -0.961 0.171 -1.600 -2.754 -0.592 -1.851 1.249 -0.220 0.274 1.627 0.070 0.038 -2.153 -0.026 -0.158 -0.002 0.090 -0.017 0.131 -35.030 3.703 9.338 2.069 0.136 -4.092 -1.083 -4.995 -6.740 -0.101 -1.720 1.826 8.378 0.852 -0.301 0.347 0.008 -0.348 -0.069 -2.021 -0.618 -0.141 -0.052 0.179 -0.532 0.062 2.235 -0.093 0.000 0.130 0.028 -0.020 -4.305 0.144 -0.062 0.168 0.355 0.026 0.814 0.151 -0.082 -0.081 -0.005 -0.236 -0.140 -1.165 0.037 0.125 -0.330 0.868 3.153 0.107 -0.232 -0.144 0.007 -0.211 -0.526 0.184 -2.370 0.553 -14.475 0.373 -3.946 0.687 0.321 -0.669 0.037 -1.280 -1.016 0.297 1.118 -1.625 Urban (N = 883) Electricity -7.314 -0.043 -1.007 0.954 -4.800 0.034 -5.779 1.911 -0.165 -0.028 -0.037 -4.889 Kerosene 0.176 -1.367 0.385 -0.105 1.552 0.231 2.956 0.732 0.077 0.056 0.828 1.054 Charcoal -1.061 0.086 -2.383 0.179 -0.387 0.314 1.566 -0.120 0.442 0.147 0.618 -0.949 Firewood 1.002 -0.016 0.171 -1.161 0.987 0.082 2.706 0.465 -0.116 0.267 0.156 1.756 Cereals -0.087 0.001 -0.021 -0.050 -1.531 0.040 0.176 0.014 -0.001 -0.084 -0.230 0.273 Fruits 0.177 -0.014 0.076 -0.248 -1.159 -2.383 -4.201 -0.295 0.146 -0.132 -0.146 -1.605 Vegetables 0.081 0.001 0.051 -0.001 0.249 -0.029 -1.032 -0.072 0.038 0.001 0.014 0.109 Meat & Fish 0.500 -0.023 -0.125 -0.238 -1.884 -0.130 -4.909 -2.055 -0.045 -0.323 -0.214 -2.502 Milk & Eggs -0.038 -0.050 0.116 -0.567 -2.459 0.062 -4.785 -0.370 -3.938 -0.183 -0.428 -2.170 Cheese, Oils & Fats 0.259 -0.016 0.066 0.068 -0.524 0.071 -0.163 -0.131 0.118 -1.142 0.148 0.227 Alcohol & Tobacco 0.205 0.046 0.176 -0.124 -2.010 0.003 -1.500 0.002 -0.075 0.026 -2.483 0.881 Other Food & Drink -0.021 -0.003 -0.024 0.055 0.627 0.055 0.680 0.044 0.092 0.068 0.293 -1.257 Note: The items are - Electricity (E), Kerosene (K), Charcoal (C), Firewood (Fw), Cereals (Ce), Fruits (Fr), Vegetables (V), Meat & Fish (Me), Milk & Eggs (Mi), Cheese, Oils & Fats (Ch), Alcohol & Tobacco (Al) and Other food and drink (O). Elasticities are computed based on coefficients estimated for the full sample (Table A2), combined with tercile-rural/urban specific mean budget shares and mean real expenditure on food & fuel. 47 Table A6.2: Uncompensated price elasticities of demand: Expenditure Tercile - II E Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other Food & Drink K Rural (N = 3,135) -10.833 -0.044 0.206 -1.526 -3.730 0.311 0.874 -0.019 -0.090 0.002 0.133 -0.006 0.065 0.000 0.325 -0.010 0.014 -0.029 0.326 -0.019 0.248 0.055 -0.052 -0.006 C Fw Ce Fr V Me Mi Ch Al O -1.360 0.469 -5.883 0.106 -0.018 0.086 0.039 -0.029 0.149 0.083 0.226 -0.078 1.404 -0.097 0.693 -1.122 -0.052 -0.184 -0.002 -0.175 -0.438 0.093 -0.149 0.174 -7.451 2.276 -0.892 0.880 -1.543 -0.781 0.185 -1.186 -1.755 -0.598 -2.195 1.689 -0.375 0.494 1.176 0.165 0.040 -1.956 -0.023 -0.182 -0.101 0.099 -0.052 0.226 -12.467 5.652 6.663 3.179 0.194 -3.426 -1.044 -3.862 -4.570 -0.047 -2.067 2.683 1.375 1.673 -0.208 0.771 0.002 -0.522 -0.055 -2.028 -0.810 -0.126 -0.208 0.468 -0.546 0.224 1.619 -0.043 -0.003 0.031 0.032 -0.098 -3.149 0.155 -0.119 0.283 0.088 0.050 0.584 0.216 -0.085 -0.069 -0.003 -0.176 -0.097 -1.170 0.049 0.172 -0.002 1.172 2.269 0.132 -0.241 -0.094 0.008 -0.130 -0.294 0.194 -2.635 0.708 -4.081 0.332 -2.892 0.840 0.365 -0.417 0.041 -0.794 -0.454 0.317 1.473 -1.874 Urban (N = 1,386) Electricity -4.184 -0.009 -0.536 0.554 -2.468 -0.047 -2.627 0.492 -0.200 -0.024 -0.045 -2.571 Kerosene 0.595 -1.707 0.811 -0.343 3.229 0.534 5.452 2.022 0.332 0.127 1.604 2.389 Charcoal -0.764 0.061 -1.983 0.129 -0.323 0.214 1.032 -0.125 0.301 0.098 0.429 -0.729 Firewood 2.541 -0.054 0.483 -1.523 2.599 0.302 5.993 1.798 -0.037 0.626 0.410 4.429 Cereals -0.094 0.002 -0.023 -0.044 -1.527 0.039 0.215 0.002 -0.005 -0.083 -0.230 0.281 Fruits 0.023 -0.003 0.024 -0.129 -1.058 -2.198 -3.324 -0.540 0.037 -0.112 -0.135 -1.469 Vegetables 0.107 0.001 0.064 -0.004 0.330 -0.025 -0.977 -0.043 0.055 0.006 0.024 0.177 Meat & Fish 0.209 -0.007 -0.127 -0.084 -1.403 -0.135 -3.205 -2.032 -0.122 -0.225 -0.164 -1.867 Milk & Eggs -0.183 -0.022 0.025 -0.275 -1.744 -0.015 -2.947 -0.619 -3.026 -0.126 -0.300 -1.607 Cheese, Oils & Fats 0.278 -0.017 0.071 0.074 -0.535 0.078 -0.129 -0.127 0.128 -1.148 0.161 0.267 Alcohol & Tobacco 0.145 0.052 0.159 -0.083 -2.061 -0.017 -1.375 -0.141 -0.118 0.029 -2.507 0.854 Other Food & Drink 0.007 -0.005 -0.015 0.038 0.646 0.065 0.642 0.109 0.110 0.069 0.294 -1.222 Note: The items are - Electricity (E), Kerosene (K), Charcoal (C), Firewood (Fw), Cereals (Ce), Fruits (Fr), Vegetables (V), Meat & Fish (Me), Milk & Eggs (Mi), Cheese, Oils & Fats (Ch), Alcohol & Tobacco (Al) and Other food and drink (O). Elasticities are computed based on coefficients estimated for the full sample (Table A2), combined with tercile-rural/urban specific mean budget shares and mean real expenditure on food & fuel. 48 Table A6.3: Uncompensated price elasticities of demand: Expenditure Tercile - III E Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other Food & Drink K Rural (N = 2,405) -4.467 -0.006 0.784 -1.950 -3.185 0.266 1.311 -0.032 -0.097 0.002 0.011 -0.001 0.081 0.000 0.156 -0.003 -0.137 -0.014 0.362 -0.021 0.163 0.058 0.050 -0.010 C Fw Ce Fr V Me Mi Ch Al O -0.458 0.849 -5.180 0.145 -0.019 0.069 0.044 -0.029 0.100 0.091 0.219 -0.074 0.499 -0.248 0.589 -1.190 -0.050 -0.136 -0.001 -0.124 -0.283 0.101 -0.127 0.149 -2.662 4.360 -0.776 1.276 -1.539 -0.726 0.238 -1.077 -1.350 -0.621 -2.181 1.710 -0.232 1.069 1.008 0.296 0.039 -1.857 -0.017 -0.206 -0.138 0.114 -0.082 0.264 -4.093 9.815 5.645 4.023 0.228 -2.815 -0.984 -3.155 -3.144 -0.001 -1.895 2.507 0.063 3.665 -0.175 1.295 -0.002 -0.603 -0.031 -2.058 -0.814 -0.109 -0.318 0.610 -0.341 0.692 1.390 0.071 -0.006 -0.043 0.045 -0.165 -2.625 0.177 -0.169 0.346 0.023 0.092 0.498 0.281 -0.084 -0.058 -0.001 -0.148 -0.069 -1.182 0.051 0.167 -0.041 2.143 1.941 0.199 -0.241 -0.093 0.014 -0.126 -0.230 0.214 -2.610 0.708 -1.475 0.801 -2.481 1.177 0.367 -0.398 0.063 -0.723 -0.392 0.357 1.420 -1.824 Urban (N = 2,115) Electricity -2.884 0.000 -0.296 0.316 -1.401 -0.094 -1.420 -0.018 -0.228 -0.013 -0.044 -1.392 Kerosene 2.426 -2.620 1.867 -0.902 7.555 1.593 11.959 6.148 1.458 0.259 3.699 5.239 Charcoal -0.793 0.062 -2.001 0.134 -0.316 0.214 1.090 -0.143 0.298 0.102 0.438 -0.720 Firewood 5.562 -0.124 0.903 -2.065 4.879 0.893 10.386 4.664 0.575 1.095 0.810 7.773 Cereals -0.107 0.002 -0.023 -0.044 -1.536 0.040 0.272 -0.002 -0.009 -0.084 -0.239 0.324 Fruits -0.161 0.003 0.012 -0.076 -0.844 -1.973 -2.459 -0.670 -0.088 -0.080 -0.116 -1.085 Vegetables 0.154 0.000 0.075 -0.007 0.407 -0.014 -0.931 0.009 0.085 0.009 0.033 0.228 Meat & Fish -0.025 0.000 -0.104 -0.041 -1.115 -0.169 -2.385 -2.060 -0.214 -0.167 -0.140 -1.396 Milk & Eggs -0.312 -0.009 0.008 -0.154 -1.183 -0.080 -1.861 -0.686 -2.428 -0.078 -0.211 -1.022 Cheese, Oils & Fats 0.329 -0.019 0.084 0.084 -0.571 0.096 -0.087 -0.113 0.156 -1.163 0.189 0.340 Alcohol & Tobacco 0.036 0.056 0.160 -0.068 -2.083 -0.054 -1.287 -0.294 -0.190 0.037 -2.532 0.926 Other Food & Drink 0.073 -0.007 -0.013 0.036 0.758 0.097 0.736 0.223 0.166 0.078 0.337 -1.235 Note: The items are - Electricity (E), Kerosene (K), Charcoal (C), Firewood (Fw), Cereals (Ce), Fruits (Fr), Vegetables (V), Meat & Fish (Me), Milk & Eggs (Mi), Cheese, Oils & Fats (Ch), Alcohol & Tobacco (Al) and Other food and drink (O). Elasticities are computed based on coefficients estimated for the full sample (Table A2), combined with tercile-rural/urban specific mean budget shares and mean real expenditure on food & fuel. 49 Table A7: Matching of UNHS Consumption Items with GTAP Sectors UNHS Item Code 101 102 103 107 109 114 116 117 119 120 125 126 128 129 130 132 133 134 135 136 138 139 140 141 142 143 144 145 147 150 151 152 153 154 155 156 157 158 159 UNHS Item Matooke (Bunch) Matooke (Cluster) Matooke (Heap) Cassava (Fresh) Irish Potatoes Bread (wheat) Sorghum Beef Goat Meat Other Meat (eg duck, rabbit etc) Fresh Milk Infant Formula Foods Ghee Margarine Passion Fruits Mangoes Oranges/Tangerines Other Fruits Onions Tomatoes Dodo/Nakati/gyobyo/Malakwang Other vegetables Bean( fresh) Beans (dry) Ground nuts (in shell) Ground nuts (shelled) Ground nuts (pounded) Peas(fresh) Sugar Salt Soda Beer Other Alcoholic drinks Other drinks Cigarrates Other Tobacco Food in Restaurants Soda in Restaurants Beer Restaurants GTAP Sector v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f ofd ofd cmt cmt omt mil ofd mil vol v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f ofd v_f v_f v_f v_f sgr ocr b_t b_t b_t b_t b_t b_t ofd b_t b_t GTAP Code 4 4 4 4 4 25 25 19 19 20 22 25 22 21 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 25 4 4 4 4 24 8 26 26 26 26 26 26 25 26 26 50 160 161 162 163 164 165 166 167 168 169 170 171 172 173 174 175 306 308 309 310 1051 1052 1061 1062 1063 1081 1082 1083 1101 1102 1111 1112 1121 1122 1131 1132 1151 1171 1172 1191 1192 1193 Other juice Packed in Restaurant Other foods in Restaurants Peas(dry) Ground nuts (paste) Green Pepper Pumpkins Avocado Carrots Egg plants Watermelon Pineapple Pawpaw Wheat (flour) Chapati Apples Water Electricity Paraffin or kerosene Charcoal Firewood Sweet Potatoes white/yellow(Fres Sweet Potatoes-orange fleshed (f Sweet Potatoes white/yellow (Dry Sweet Potatoes-orange (Dry) Sweet Potatoes white/yellow (flo Cassava (Dry) Cassava (flour) Pancakes(Kabalagala) Rice (white) Rice (brown) Maize yellow (grains) Maize white (grains) Maize white (cobs) Maize yellow (cobs) Maize white (flour) Maize yellow (flour) Millet flour Beef Liver Beef Offals Goat Liver Goat offals Roasted goat meat b_t ofd ofd ofd v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f wht ofd v_f b_t ely p_c NA NA v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f pdr pdr gro gro gro gro ofd ofd ofd cmt cmt cmt cmt cmt 26 25 25 25 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 2 25 4 26 46 32 0 0 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 1 1 3 3 3 3 25 25 25 19 19 19 19 19 51 1201 1211 1212 1213 1214 1215 1221 1222 1231 1232 1234 1235 1236 1237 1241 1242 1243 1251 1252 1253 1254 1271 1272 1281 1291 1311 1312 1313 1351 1352 1353 1371 1372 1391 1461 1462 1471 1472 1481 1482 1491 1492 Roasted other meat Chicken off-layer Chicken Broiler Chicken Kroiler Chicken Local Roasted Chicken Fresh tilapia Fish Fresh Nile perch Dry/ Smoked tilapia fish Dry/Smoked Nile perch Dried Nkejje Other fresh fish Other dry/smoked fish Silver Fish (Mukene) Eggs (yellow yolk) Eggs (white yolk) Other eggs (duck, turkey etc) Milk Powdered Fermented milk (Bongo) Ice-cream Yoghurt Cooking oil refined Cooking oil unrefined Cheese Butter Sweet Bananas-Ndiizi Sweet Bananas-Bogoya Plantain (gonja/kivuvu) Garlic Ginger fresh Ginger powder Cabbages – Red leaf Cabbage – green leaf Other spices Simsim Simsim paste Honey Jam/ Mamalede Coffee Coffee Other Tea leaves Tea bags omt oap oap oap oap oap ofd ofd ofd ofd ofd ofd ofd ofd oap oap oap mil mil mil mil vol vol mil mil v_f v_f v_f v_f v_f ocr v_f v_f ocr osd osd oap ofd b_t ocr ocr b_t 20 10 10 10 10 10 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 10 10 10 22 22 22 22 21 21 22 22 4 4 4 4 4 8 4 4 8 5 5 10 25 26 8 8 26 52 1493 1601 1602 1603 1651 1652 1653 1654 1721 1731 1732 1733 1734 1735 1741 1761 1762 Green tea Other juice fresh Other juice packed Other juice Fresh in Restaurants Pumpkin Leaves Mushrooms Cucumber Okra Macaroni/Spaghetti Biscuits Cakes Doughnuts Cornflakes Samosas Jackfruit (ffene) Soya beans (fresh) Soya beans (dry) b_t b_t b_t b_t v_f v_f v_f v_f ofd ofd ofd ofd ofd ofd v_f v_f ofd 26 26 26 26 4 4 4 4 25 25 25 25 25 25 4 4 25 Figure A2. Scatterplot of item-wise price increases and expenditure shares Note: The markers in the scatterplot correspond to the 12 items modelled in the demand system. 53 Robustness Checks for demand system estimation We conduct two robustness checks of the demand system. First, we expand the original model specification by controlling for sub-regional heterogeneity, and use instrumental variables for commodity prices and sub-region dummy variables. Given the importance of transportation in the supply chain for food items and energy sources (MEMD, 2015), we construct instrumental variables for prices to mitigate the influence of transportation costs in final commodity prices, which may result in simultaneous increases of several commodity prices, leading to a bad control problem (Angrist and Pischke 2008). We first conduct regressions of the pass-through of transport to commodity prices (all energy22 and food items), constructing a district-level panel dataset of commodity prices from the UNPS for 2009-2020. We draw on monthly international diesel prices to proxy for local transportation costs. All coefficients of the log of commodity prices on the log of diesel prices are positive and statistically significant, reflecting a sizeable effect of transport costs on commodity prices. We then construct instruments for food and energy prices as follows: ln 𝑝𝑖𝑣 = ln 𝑝𝑖 − 𝛽𝑖 ln 𝑑 where 𝛽𝑖 is the regression coefficient of the price pass-through for commodity 𝑖, and ln 𝑑 is the international price of diesel (converted to Ugandan shillings) for the respective month. The 12 constructed commodity prices ln 𝑝𝑖𝑣 and the price of diesel are then used as instruments for the original prices. We additionally introduce sub-region dummy variables as instruments to capture geographical heterogeneity in demand responses. The estimated compensated price elasticities of demand are presented in Table A8. While the broad patterns of substitution are similar to those obtained from the Uganda National Household Survey 2016-17, the model 22 Electricity tariff schedules set by the Electricity Regulatory Authority in Uganda are also influenced by international fuel prices and the nominal exchange rate. 54 does not meet the criterion for over-identification as Hansen’s J-statistic is large, and we reject the null hypothesis of all instruments being valid. Table A8: Robustness Check I – Compensated price elasticities of demand Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other Food & Drink E K C Fw Ce Fr V Me Mi Ch Al O -4.537*** (0.398) -1.410*** (0.338) -1.970*** (0.26) 0.762*** (0.124) -0.129*** (0.021) 0.298*** (0.062) 0.063*** (0.007) 0.586*** (0.044) 0.171* (0.092) 0.512*** (0.055) 0.555*** (0.127) -0.293*** (0.058) -0.138*** (0.033) -1.911*** (0.145) 0.090** (0.043) 0.180*** (0.02) 0.013*** (0.002) -0.006 (0.005) -0.001 (0.001) 0.006** (0.003) -0.039*** (0.01) -0.021*** (0.006) 0.132*** (0.011) -0.034*** (0.004) -0.630*** (0.083) 0.294** (0.141) -3.399*** (0.201) 0.337*** (0.031) -0.022*** (0.006) 0.077*** (0.018) 0.062*** (0.002) -0.062*** (0.006) 0.098*** (0.029) 0.146*** (0.018) 0.128*** (0.019) -0.056*** (0.012) 0.772*** (0.126) 1.859*** (0.203) 1.067*** (0.098) -1.356*** (0.067) -0.088*** (0.007) -0.065*** (0.019) 0.016*** (0.003) 0.002 (0.008) -0.293*** (0.029) 0.047** (0.02) 0.044 (0.087) -0.013 (0.038) -1.172*** (0.193) 1.202*** (0.185) -0.629*** (0.163) -0.790*** (0.06) -1.480*** (0.033) 0.589*** (0.074) 0.159*** (0.01) 0.050* (0.03) -0.019 (0.08) -0.500*** (0.044) -2.095*** (0.103) 0.805*** (0.04) 0.452*** (0.095) -0.097 (0.08) 0.365*** (0.086) -0.098*** (0.028) 0.099*** (0.012) -1.936*** (0.048) -0.047*** (0.004) 0.029** (0.013) 0.284*** (0.047) 0.165*** (0.023) 0.176*** (0.061) 0.012 (0.025) 1.367*** (0.162) -0.164 (0.125) 4.214*** (0.166) 0.336*** (0.058) 0.382*** (0.024) -0.674*** (0.059) -1.163*** (0.013) -0.375*** (0.029) 0.211*** (0.071) -0.509*** (0.035) 0.845*** (0.104) -0.130*** (0.038) 3.263*** (0.244) 0.364** (0.183) -1.073*** (0.099) 0.009 (0.041) 0.031* (0.019) 0.106** (0.046) -0.096*** (0.007) -1.163*** (0.028) 0.493*** (0.074) -0.300*** (0.03) 0.163** (0.081) -0.150*** (0.037) 0.241* (0.13) -0.564*** (0.143) 0.431*** (0.127) -0.406*** (0.04) -0.003 (0.012) 0.263*** (0.044) 0.014*** (0.005) 0.125*** (0.019) -2.782*** (0.095) 0.232*** (0.033) 0.002 (0.06) 0.143*** (0.026) 0.549*** (0.059) -0.225*** (0.064) 0.489*** (0.059) 0.050** (0.021) -0.059*** (0.005) 0.117*** (0.017) -0.025*** (0.002) -0.058*** (0.006) 0.177*** (0.025) -1.103*** (0.017) 0.052** (0.021) 0.040*** (0.01) 0.846*** (0.193) 2.059*** (0.167) 0.613*** (0.092) 0.066 (0.131) -0.352*** (0.017) 0.176*** (0.062) 0.059*** (0.007) 0.045** (0.022) 0.002 (0.066) 0.074** (0.03) -2.345*** (0.093) 0.298*** (0.038) -2.013*** (0.398) -2.406*** (0.303) -1.197*** (0.252) -0.09 (0.259) 0.610*** (0.03) 0.056 (0.115) -0.041*** (0.012) -0.185*** (0.045) 0.697*** (0.129) 0.255*** (0.067) 1.343*** (0.169) -1.622*** (0.109) Note: The items are - Electricity (E), Kerosene (K), Charcoal (C), Firewood (Fw), Cereals (Ce), Fruits (Fr), Vegetables (V), Meat & Fish (Me), Milk & Eggs (Mi), Cheese, Oils & Fats (Ch), Alcohol & Tobacco (Al) and Other food and drink (O). Robust standard errors in parentheses. The Hansen J chi-sq. statistic for over-identification is 5693.11 (p = 0.0000). N = 13,582. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. 55 Second, we estimate elasticities using an alternative pooled cross-sectional dataset – the Uganda National Panel Survey, over the 2009-10 to 2019-20 period, for both expenditure and price data. After excluding outliers and observations with missing price and expenditure data, we obtain a total pooled cross-sectional sample of 15,950 households. We additionally control for time effects, using year dummy variables as instruments. The estimated compensated price elasticities of demand are presented in Table A9. Results are broadly similar to those obtained using the Uganda National Household Survey 2016-17. In particular, the patterns of substitution between electricity and firewood, as well as between kerosene, charcoal and firewood, corroborate those obtained from the cross-sectional UNHS dataset. 56 Table A9: Robustness Check II – Compensated price elasticities of demand Electricity Kerosene Charcoal Firewood Cereals Fruits Vegetables Meat & Fish Milk & Eggs Cheese, Oils & Fats Alcohol & Tobacco Other Food & Drink E K C Fw Ce Fr V Me Mi Ch Al O -4.344*** (0.242) -0.762*** (0.044) -0.437*** (0.032) 0.422*** (0.034) 0.338*** (0.03) 0.182*** (0.024) -0.177*** (0.031) -0.276*** (0.033) -0.018 (0.036) 0.109*** (0.012) 0.246*** (0.035) 0.401*** (0.077) -0.280*** (0.016) -0.939*** (0.022) 0.009*** (0.002) -0.010* (0.006) 0.022*** (0.004) 0.008*** (0.003) 0.003 (0.004) -0.049*** (0.006) 0.009* (0.005) 0.006*** (0.001) 0.008** (0.004) 0.052*** (0.005) -0.585*** (0.043) 0.032*** (0.007) -0.931*** (0.008) -0.086*** (0.007) 0.018*** (0.006) -0.030*** (0.005) 0.012* (0.007) 0.032*** (0.007) 0.007 (0.008) 0.004 (0.002) 0.009 (0.007) 0.273*** (0.018) 0.628*** (0.051) -0.042* (0.025) -0.096*** (0.007) -0.910*** (0.023) -0.143*** (0.012) -0.022*** (0.008) 0.028** (0.013) 0.064*** (0.016) -0.082*** (0.015) 0.007* (0.003) -0.024* (0.013) -0.031** (0.015) 1.109*** (0.099) 0.200*** (0.033) 0.045*** (0.014) -0.316*** (0.026) -1.195*** (0.029) 0.129*** (0.017) 0.139*** (0.026) -0.230*** (0.027) 0.157*** (0.027) -0.014* (0.008) -0.060** (0.026) -0.293*** (0.035) 0.656*** (0.087) 0.074*** (0.028) -0.081*** (0.013) -0.054*** (0.02) 0.141*** (0.019) -1.178*** (0.021) 0.080*** (0.023) -0.176*** (0.021) -0.243*** (0.023) 0.021*** (0.007) -0.117*** (0.021) -0.006 (0.034) -0.251*** (0.045) 0.011 (0.015) 0.013* (0.008) 0.027** (0.012) 0.060*** (0.011) 0.032*** (0.009) -1.022** (0.019) 0.204*** (0.013) 0.030** (0.014) -0.045*** (0.004) 0.030** (0.014) 0.045** (0.019) -0.156*** (0.019) -0.076*** (0.009) 0.013*** (0.003) 0.024*** (0.006) -0.040*** (0.005) -0.028*** (0.003) 0.081*** (0.005) -0.965*** (0.008) -0.025*** (0.006) 0.011*** (0.001) -0.001 (0.005) 0.078*** (0.007) -0.021 (0.041) 0.027* (0.015) 0.006 (0.007) -0.062*** (0.011) 0.054*** (0.009) -0.076*** (0.007) 0.024** (0.011) -0.051*** (0.011) -0.981*** (0.017) -0.017*** (0.003) -0.004 (0.01) 0.157*** (0.015) 0.946*** (0.104) 0.138*** (0.026) 0.024 (0.016) 0.040* (0.02) -0.036* (0.02) 0.050*** (0.016) -0.273*** (0.024) 0.164*** (0.022) -0.133*** (0.024) -1.033*** (0.011) 0.208*** (0.025) -0.394*** (0.043) 0.467*** (0.066) 0.041** (0.021) 0.013 (0.01) -0.030* (0.017) -0.035** (0.015) -0.062*** (0.011) 0.040** (0.019) -0.003 (0.016) -0.007 (0.017) 0.046*** (0.005) -1.035*** (0.022) -0.238*** (0.028) 0.831*** (0.16) 0.294*** (0.027) 0.422*** (0.028) -0.043** (0.021) -0.185** (0.022) -0.003 (0.02) 0.066** (0.028) 0.287*** (0.024) 0.287*** (0.028) -0.094*** (0.01) -0.260*** (0.031) -1.043*** (0.086) Note: The items are - Electricity (E), Kerosene (K), Charcoal (C), Firewood (Fw), Cereals (Ce), Fruits (Fr), Vegetables (V), Meat & Fish (Me), Milk & Eggs (Mi), Cheese, Oils & Fats (Ch), Alcohol & Tobacco (Al) and Other food and drink (O). Robust standard errors in parentheses. As the model includes year dummy variables as instruments, we compute Hansen’s J chi-sq statistic to test for overidentifying restrictions. The Hansen J chi-sq. statistic for over-identification is 3020.99 (p = 0.0000). The model does not meet the criterion for over-identification as Hansen’s J-statistic is large. N = 15,949. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. 57