Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
CHAPTER 9 – MONOPOLY (6e) Features of Monopoly: One seller Product has no close substitutes Barriers to entry exist The firm is a price searcher I. Barriers to Entry A monopoly exists because there are barriers to entry: There are three kinds of barriers: A. Legal Restrictions B. Economies of Scale C. Control of Essential Resources 1 II. Revenue for the Monopolist The monopoly firm = the industry. Thus, the demand curve facing the monopolist = the market demand curve, which is downward sloping. A. Demand and Marginal Revenue The monopolist is subject to the law of demand: the price must fall in order for consumers to increase their quantity demanded of the product. Ex. 2 Note that for QD to increase, the price must fall. B. Revenue Schedules Ex. 3 As P falls, QD rises. TR = P x Q TR rises over the range of 0 to 15 units, levels out at 15 to 16 units, and then begins to fall after 16 units. MR = ∆TR ÷ ∆Q of output MR declines over the entire range of output. Note that for a monopolist, MR is NOT = P. Instead, MR < P and MR declines twice as fast as P. When graphed, the MR curve will fall below the D curve and will be twice as steep. C. Revenue Curves Ex. 4, panel (a): The monopolist’s D and MR curves are shown. When D is elastic, MR is positive because a decrease in P will increase TR. When D is unit elastic, MR = zero because a decrease in P will not change TR. When D is inelastic, MR is negative because a decrease in P will decrease TR. 2 [The relationship between price and total revenue for different elasticities of demand was first presented in Chapter 5. Go back and review this information on p. 92 and review Ex. 2 on p. 94. Also review the homework assignment from Ch. 5 to see how elasticity along a linear demand curve relates to total revenue.] Ex. 4, panel (b): The monopolist’s TR curve is shown. When D is elastic, a decrease in P will increase TR; MR is positive though declining. When D is unit elastic, a decrease in P will not change TR; MR is zero. When D is inelastic, a decrease in P will decrease TR; MR is negative. III. The Firm’s Costs and Profit Maximization Like other firms, the monopolist seeks to maximize profit. Since the monopolist has some control over what price to charge, it is a price maker and will select the price-and-quantity combination that will maximize its profit. A. Profit Maximization (1) The “Total Approach:” Total Revenue minus Total Cost Total profit = TR – TC Total profit is maximized when TR > TC by the greatest amount. Ex. 5, columns 1,2,3,5, and 8: Column 8 shows the monopolist’s losses and profits. Total profit is maximized at 10 units, which is thus the profit-maximizing level of output for this firm. The price at 10 units is $5,250, meaning that if it wishes to sell 10 units, the firm will set a price of $5,250. [The monopolist “makes” the price rather than “takes” the price.] 3 Ex. 6, panel (b): Graphical depiction of the “total approach” TC curve has the shape we saw in Ch. 7 TR begins at zero; it rises as long as the price is falling and demand is elastic; it reaches a peak when demand is unit elastic; and then it falls as long as price is falling and demand is inelastic. (Notice that total profit is maximized where TR>TC by the greatest amount, and not where TR is at its highest level. The goal of the firm is to maximize total profit, not maximize total revenue.) (2) The “Marginal Approach:” Marginal Revenue Equals Marginal Cost Remember RULE #1: To maximize profit (or minimize loss), a firm should produce the output at which MR=MC. Looking at Ex. 5, columns 4,6, and 8, we see that: As long as MR>MC, the firm can move toward the maximum profit by increasing its output. When MR=MC, profit is maximized. (This occurs at 10 units.) The firm should produce this level of output. When MR<MC, the firm can move toward the maximum profit by decreasing its output. Ex. 6, panel (a): Graphical depiction of the “marginal approach” How to read this graph: 1. Find the point where MR=MC, then go down to the horizontal axis to find the profitmaximizing quantity of output. 2. From the profit-maximizing quantity, GO UP TO THE DEMAND CURVE AND THEN OVER TO THE VERTICAL AXIS TO FIND THE PROFIT-MAXIMIZING PRICE! 4 3. Find the difference between the price and the ATC at the profit-maximizing quantity to determine the profit per unit. Then multiply profit per unit x quantity to get total profit. Note that since MC is always > zero, it must always intersect MR in the positive portion of the MR curve. This in turn corresponds to the elastic portion of the D curve. B. Short-Run Losses and the Shutdown Decision If TR<TC (i.e., if P<ATC), the monopolist will suffer a loss. Should the firm keep producing, or should it shut down? (1) Producing to Minimize Losses Remember RULE #2: If P<ATC, produce the output at which MR=MC only if P is > or = AVC. Ex. 7 At the profit-maximizing level of output (where MR=MC), P<ATC (the demand curve lies below the ATC curve), but since P>AVC the firm will produce and minimize its losses. The loss per unit is shown by the vertical distance between points a and b; the total loss is shown by the shaded rectangle. (2) Shutting Down to Minimize Losses If P<AVC, the firm will minimize losses by shutting down temporarily. The firm’s loss will = its fixed costs. Graphically, if the demand curve lies below the AVC curve at the level of output at which MR=MC, the firm should shut down temporarily, i.e., produce zero output. 5 C. Long Run Profit Maximization (Remember that in perfect competition, SR profits attract new firms while SR losses cause firms to leave the industry. In the LR, perfectly competitive firms earn zero economic profits.) For the monopolist, there can be LR profits because new firms are hindered from entering the market because of barriers to entry. The monopolist will seek to adjust the scale of the firm in the LR to achieve the greatest profit. Are LR profits guaranteed for a monopolist? NO, especially if the market is contestable, meaning that it is possible for new firms to enter the industry because barriers to entry are relatively low. IV. Monopoly and the Allocation of Resources and V. Problems Estimating the Welfare Cost of Monopoly You will not need to know Ex. 8. From these sections, you will only need to understand the following: How does the efficiency of resource allocation under monopoly compare to that under perfect competition? Resources are not allocated as efficiently under monopoly as under perfect competition. A perfectly competitive industry will typically produce a larger output at a lower price, while a monopolist will produce a lower output and charge a higher price. Because the monopolist’s price is higher and output lower than under a perfectly competitive market, and because the monopolist may be able to earn a profit in the LR whereas perfectly competitive firms can only break even in the LR, it is often believed that, for consumers, a monopoly is “bad” and perfect competition is “good”. So is a monopoly “as bad as it looks”? NO, a monopoly is not so bad: If economies of scale make the monopolist able to produce at a lower average cost than perfectly competitive firms could. If the monopolist keeps prices and profits lower than the profit-maximizing levels to discourage potential rivals from entering the industry or to avoid government scrutiny and regulation. If the monopolist keeps profits down to avoid public criticism. 6 YES, the monopolist is “bad:” If the monopolist uses up scarce resources just to secure and maintain a monopoly position. (This is called “rent seeking.”) If the monopolist becomes inefficient or wasteful or slow to innovate (if it grows “fat and lazy”) because it is protected from competition. VI. Price Discrimination Up to now we have assumed that the monopolist charges the same price to all consumers. Sometimes monopolists practice price discrimination: Why would a monopolist practice price discrimination? To increase total profit! Conditions necessary for price discrimination to work: (1) The firm must have some control over price. (2) There must be at least two classes of consumers, each with a different price elasticity of demand. (3) The seller must be able to distinguish among the different classes of consumers in order to charge them different prices. (4) The seller must be able to prevent resale of the product among consumers. Examples of price discrimination: You will not need to know Ex. 9 or Ex. 10. END 7