Survey
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Industrial Location and Physical Planning in Pakistan JOHN C. EDDISON* Introduction The subject of industrial location, as an aspect of the economic development of the country, is one to which frequent references have been made in recent years by government officials and by the writers of newspaper editorials. During the period of the First Five Year Plan, the burden of such references was generally to the effect that further industrialization should be fostered in backward areas and that it should be discouraged or actually banned in Karachi, Lahore and other cities believed to be overcrowded or vulnerable from a defence point of view. More recently, the desire for the dispersal of industry and for the provision of jobs in less developed areas has led to the espousal of industrial estates as a means of solving the industrial location problem1. The concern of officials and of editors with the overconcentration of manufacturing#in a few cities and with the lack of geographic balance in the location of industrial investments is well founded. The problem is a serious one in Pakistan, as well as in almost all countries in which a substantial amount of industrialization has taken place. However, it does not lend itself to simple solutions such as the banning of further investments in certain of the most advanced areas or the proliferation of industrial estates in backward, economically stagnant, or out-of-the-way towns. To say this is not to criticize the use of industrial estates as a method of channeling investment. These estates have a valuable function to perform if employed in conjunction with other tools of investment promotion and as a part of a systematic approach to the location of new industrial activity. It is the contention of this paper that the location and promotion of industries is too important a matter to be dealt with on an uncoordinated, piecemeal basis, and that high priority should be given to the formulation of a positive, integrated, industrial location strategy, to be spelled out in ♦The author is Economic Adviser to the Planning Commission, Government of Pakistan..At the time of writing, he was serving as Economic Adviser to the Government of West Pakistan. i. For example, see articles on industrial estates in the Civil and Military Gazette, Lahore, of 18th January, 1960, 9th October, 1960, 14th February, 1961, and 16th February, 1961. Income Velocity and Pakistan's Second Plan RICHARD C. PORTER* An attempt is made in this paper to appraise the extent to which the income velocity concept1 is a useful tool in the financial planning of the Second Five Year Plan. For many years now, economists have been skeptical of the efficacy of velocity analysis, but most of this skepticism derives from its disastrous failure in the depression of the 1930s. Theorists generally concede its applicability in full-capacity situations2, and it is in just such a situation that it is being applied in current analyses of the financial implications of Pakistan's Second Plan. Nevertheless, the basic reason why the quantity theory is being revived in Pakistan, and in many other developing countries, is not so much its theoretical relevance as its great practicability. "Modern" Keynesian gap analysis is just not feasible where data on consumption and investment (not to mention their functional determinants) are totally lacking. Since data do exist for velocity analysis3, it is used for want of a better. The conclusion of this paper, summarised in a sentence, is that resort to velocity analysis to avoid inflation is unnecessary, uncertain and misleading. The statistical estimates seem to "explain" movements in real money balances quite well and conform to a priori predilections very satisfactorily, but grave uncertainties are incurred when these historical fits are used to predict the future. Velocity analysis may be misleading if it suggests that the supply of money is a variable completely independent of its demand. In Pakistan *The author is Research Adviser in the Institute of Development Economics. For comments on a draft of this paper, I am grateful to Nurul Islam and Rehman Sobhan of Dacca University and to Parvez Hasan and Moinuddin Baqai of the State Bank of Pakistan (Research Department). Abdur Rahman of the Institute has helped greatly in the checking of calculations. They are in no way responsible for any errors that remain. i. The concepts, income velocity, quantity theory, liquidity preference and real money balance schedule are merely different ways of viewing a hypothesized relation between money and income. In this paper, the latter is preferred, but the terms are used interchangeably. 2. For a comprehensive discussion and extensive bibliography on the quantity theory of money see D. Patinkin, Money, Interest and Prices (1956), especially Chapters 8 and 10. Also see M. Friedman's introductory essay in Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money (1956). 3. Though, as will be seen, such data may not be sufficiently accurate, plentiful, or rich {i.e., varied) to yield meaningful income-velocity estimates. Financing the Second Five Year Plan AZIZUR RAHMAN KHAN* I The purpose of this paper is to indicate some of the problems involved in financing Pakistan's Second Five Year Plan. The Plan sets out the objective of increasing the gross national product by 20 per cent. The cost of this growth rate has been estimated at Rs. 19,000 million of investment expenditure over the Plan period, Rs. 9,750 million in the public sector, Rs. 3,250 million in the semi-public sector, and Rs. 6,000 million in the private sector.1 This is a large investment programme with per Table 1 Comparative Plan Costs: Pakistan and India Investment 1. Total Investment A. B. Public ... Private ... 2. Per-Capita Investment .. Pakistan's Pakistan's First First Plan Second Indian Plan Plan 10,800 m 35,000 m 61,000 m 102,000 m 7,500 m 13,000im 17,500 m 38,000 m 3,300 m 6,000 m 17,500 m 23,000 m 62,000 m 40,000 m Rs. 1312 19,000 m m=million rupees Second Third Indian Indian Plan Plan Rs. 2023 Rs. 99 Rs. 149 Rs. 233 SOURCE: Data about the First and Second Plan of Pakistan are obtained from the First Five Year Plan and the Second Five Year Plan, Planning Commission, Government of Pakistan. Data about the First and Second Indian Plans are obtained from An Appraisal of Pakistan's First Five Year Plan, S. A. Abbas, Netherlands Economic Institute, 1956. The Third Indian Plan figures are taken from Third Five Year Plan: A Draft Outline, Planning Commission, Government of India. !. Including semi-public sector. 2- According to the population estimates of the Planning Commission for the year 1955-56. Actual per capita investment was probably lower. 3. According to the provisional population estimates of the 1961 census. Morning News, 4 March, 1961. •The author is Staff Economist in the Institute of Development Economics. He is grateful to Dr. Irving Brecher, Dr. Richard C Porter, and Mr. S. U. Khan, (all of the Institute of Development Economics) for commenting on an earlier draft and suggesting improvements. !. This paper was prepared before the Plan was revised. It is therefore based entirely on the figures published in June 1960. Since the new estimates are incomplete, their use at this stage does not seem worthwhile. It is believed that in spite of the Plan revision, the main conclusions of the Paper are still valid. A First Glance at the Pakistan Age Distribution KAROL J. KROTKI* What follows is not only a summary of first impressions, but it is also limited to Pakistan as a whole, i.e., inter-regional differentials are not investigated. Furthermore, the following comments are limited to the youngest ages. In particular, no discussion is offered of the age distribution at the oldest ages. In any case the latter is partly a freak of the peculiar assumption on which it is drawn, namely, that nobody in Pakistan lives beyond the age of eighty. These are very severe limitations and in part what follows is more in the nature of advance notice of research to be undertaken than it is a report on substantive findings. Nevertheless, the initial impressions are of a startling enough nature to justify disclosure at this stage, but on the distinct understanding that they may on further inquiry prove illusory. The observations of this note are based on the simple fact that the population of any area at any time is a function of fertility, mortality and migration prevailing in the past. There are two ways in which these three influences show themselves: on the age distribution and the rate of growth. In a way, it may be more helpful to say that age distribution and growth are the other side of the same thing, namely, the combined product of fertility, mortality and migration. In fact, this is such a wide and all-embracing statement that it may seem almost meaningless. However, relatively recent developments in demographic theory furnish powerful tools for analysis of age distribution and growth. Evidence of growth, such as it is, is not considered in this note. As already indicated, the discussion is limited to age distribution. The theoretical approach in what follows is further illuminated in two ways. Firstly, it is suggested that the peculiarities of Pakistani age distribution are not real demographic facts, but are most likely, or even almost certainly, the function of enumeration vagaries. These enumeration freaks, when allowed for, indicate higher fertility than currently assumed. As a corollary, having accepted higher fertility even if only for the sake of argument, one or the other or both of two rates must give way. We can keep •The author is Research Adviser in the Institute of Development Economics. He is grateful for comments received from Professor Ansley J. Coale, Director of the OfBce of Population Research at Princeton University; Dr. John F. Kantner of The Population Council, Inc., in New York; Dr. Irving Brecher, Joint Director of the Institute of Development Economics in Karachi and Dr. Richard C. Porter, Research Adviser in the Institute of Development Economics. A Measure of Inflation in Pakistan* A Summary by S. U. KHANt Although a number of series on wholesale and retail prices are being published by the Central Statistical Office and other organizations, there is no general price index to measure annual price changes in the country. The price indices (composed of more than one commodity) presently available in Pakistan are cost of living indices of limited coverage. This monograph presents an annual wholesale price index for the purpose of measuring the extent of inflationary pressure in Pakistan. The index is computed for the East and West wings separately and for the whole of Pakistan. It dates from 1951-52 through 1959-60 (July-June), with 1951-52 as the base year. Owing to lack of data, it was not possible to carry the index back to Partition, while the need for accuracy precluded the construction of the index on a quarterly or monthly basis. The choice of 1951-52 as the base year is inevitable if the special conditions of the Korean Boom, its aftermath and the Plan period are to be avoided. Moreover, 1951-52 was a year of fewer controls, and prices in that year did not differ much from the preceding two years. The West Pakistan index contains 35 commodities and the East Pakistan index 25. Thus the coverage is not "ideal" (that is, does not extend to all goods sold into final use within the country); it is restricted to the available data. The coverage of agricultural goods is estimated to be much greater (perhaps 85-95 per cent of "ideal") than that of non-agricultural goods. Insofar as the prices of agricultural goods are more volatile, the index may overstate the extent of general price changes. However, some tests suggest that the smaller coverage of non-agricultural commodities is not the primary cause of volatility of the price index. In order to avoid double counting, only end products were taken into account, although this was not possible in the case of some commodities which by their nature are sometimes final and sometimes intermediate goods. The weights for each wing were derived from the net quantity absorbed by final users in each year, which was computed as follows: *A recently published study of the Institute of Development Economics: A Measure of Inflation in Pakistan, 1951-60, Monograph No. 4 (March 1961). tStaif Economist in the Institute of Development Economics. Notes and Documents Trends in World Demand for Jute Manufactures* At the request of the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, the National Institute of Economic and Social Research, London, undertook a study of the trends in world demand for jute manufactures outside the principal raw jute producing countries. An attempt is made here to bring out the main findings of this study which analyses the relative importance of end-uses of jute manufactures, e.g., for floor coverings, packaging, etc., and also examines the prospects for demand in the major consuming countries over the period 1965-70. I. World Consumption Growth in world demand for jute has, since the end of the War, been relatively slow compared with the increases in both agricultural and industrial production. The index of agricultural production (part of which uses jute packaging material), showed a small increase at 117 during the years 1948-52 (base: 1934-38 average), as against the index of manufacturing production which rose to 153 ^1938 =100). Meanwhile, the index of jute consumption actually recorded a decline to 77 (1937 = 100). Further the divergence between (a) consumption of jute and (b) agricultural and industrial production, continued to exist in 1957-58, the latest year covered by this study. Thus, while the indices of agricultural and manufacturing production stood substantially higher at 137 and 233 respectively in 1957-58, the index of jute consumption had risen to only 106. The comparatively small increase in world demand for jute in post-war years was partly caused by a scarcity of raw jute and a substantial increase in prices, which tended to encourage substitutes for packaging. The devaluation; of the pound sterling in September 1949 and the boom created by the Korean War were important factors in the steep rise in raw jute prices. Bulk handling of agricultural output and certain structural changes and technological developments in the end-use of jute manufactures in the industrially advanced countries were other contributory factors in the slow growth rate of world demand for jute in recent years. It is noteworthy, however, that although jute consumption now remains at a lower level than pre-war in North America and Western Europe, there has actually been an appreciable expansion in the rest of the world, particularly in the centrally-planned countries. As shown in Table 1, the index of jute-goods consumption (1937 = 100) stood at only 70 in 1957-58 for the United States (the largest single importer in the world); in fact, even in the pre-war period, despite the phenomenal expansion in economic activity, jute *Mtonthly Bulletin of Agricultural Economics and Statistics, December 1960 and January 1961, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome.