Download Consumer and Producer Surplus

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Economic bubble wikipedia , lookup

2000s commodities boom wikipedia , lookup

Economic calculation problem wikipedia , lookup

Nominal rigidity wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Consumer and Producer Surplus
Consumer and producer surplus explained
Consumer surplus is the difference between the total amount that consumers are
willing and able to pay for a good or service (indicated by the demand curve) and the
total amount that they actually pay (the market price).
Producer surplus is the difference between what producers are willing and able to
supply a good for and the price they actually receive. The level of producer surplus is
shown by the area above the supply curve and below the market price.
Price
Supply
Equilibrium Point
Consumer
Surplus
P1
Producer Surplus
Demand
Q1
Quantity
Economic efficiency
Economic efficiency is achieved when an output of goods and services is produced making the
most efficient use of our scarce resources and when that output best meets the needs and
wants and consumers and is priced at a price that fairly reflects the value of resources used up
in production.
1. If in an economy, no one can be made better off without making someone else worse
off, the conditions for allocative efficiency have been met.
2. If in an economy, production of goods and services takes place at minimum of feasible
average cost, the conditions for productive efficiency have been met.
http://www.tutor2u.net/blog/index.php/economics/
Allocative efficiency in a competitive market
At the competitive market equilibrium price and output, we maximise consumer and producer
surplus. No one can be made better off without making someone else worse off – this is known as
the condition required for a Pareto optimal allocation of resources
Costs
Supply in a competitive market
Revenues
P2
Consumer
Surplus (CS)
Allocative efficient price
and output at the market
equilibrium
P1
Producer
Surplus (PS)
Requires other markets to
be competitive as well!
Market Demand
Net Loss of Economic
Welfare from price P2 raised
above the equilibrium price
Q2
Output (Q)
Q1
Radiohead - Paying the price you are willing to pay
Radiohead's new album In Rainbows was released to a wave of publicity largely surrounding
their innovative pricing strategy. Fans were invited to name their own price for the downloadable
mp3 files and in the event, nearly two-thirds of down loaders paid nothing. Indeed internet
monitoring company Comscore found that only 38% of down loaders willingly paid to do so and
the average price paid for the album was £2.90. One person in ten was willing to pay between
£3.80 and £5.71 for the album.
Source: Adapted from news reports
Price discrimination and consumer & producer surplus
Price discrimination occurs when a firm charges a different price to different groups of
consumers for an identical good or service, for reasons not associated with the costs of supply.
Is price discrimination something that economists should be supporting in terms of the
behaviour of businesses and final outcomes in different markets?
Pure (1st degree) discrimination
With 1st degree price discrimination the firm is able to perfectly segment the market so that
the consumer surplus is removed and turned into producer surplus. Thus there is a clear
transfer of welfare from consumers to producers. This is shown in the next diagram.
http://www.tutor2u.net/blog/index.php/economics/
Price (P)
P1
P2
Equilibrium output with perfect price
discrimination – the monopolist will sell an
extra unit providing that the next unit adds
as much to revenue as it does to cost
P3
P4
Average Cost = Marginal Cost
P5
Consumer surplus is turned into
extra revenue for the producer
= additional producer surplus
(higher profits)
AR (Market Demand)
MR
Q1 Q2
Q3
Q4
Q5
Quantity of Output (Q)
Third degree (or multi-market) price discrimination involves charging different prices for the
same product in different segments of the market. The key is that third degree discrimination is
linked directly to consumers’ willingness and ability to pay for a good or service. It means that
the prices charged may bear little or no relation to the cost of production. Clearly the elasticity of
demand is the key factor determining the pricing decision for producers for each segment of the
market.
Price
Market A
Market B
Price
Consumer surplus at Price Pa
Consumer surplus at Price Pa
Profit from selling to market A
– with a relatively elastic
demand – and charging a
lower price
Pa
Pb
Demand in segment B of the
market is relatively inelastic. A
higher unit price is charged
MC=AC
MC=AC
ARa
MRa
MRb
Qa
Quantity
Qb
ARb
Quantity
The market is usually separated in two ways: by time or by geography. For example, exporters
may charge a higher price in overseas markets if demand is found to be more inelastic than it is
http://www.tutor2u.net/blog/index.php/economics/
in home markets. There is more consumer surplus to be exploited when demand is insensitive
to price changes.
http://www.tutor2u.net/blog/index.php/economics/