* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download q** P - Viden.io
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Chapter 11 Profit Maximization Chapter Overview 1. The Profit Maximization Condition 2. Marginal Revenue and Elasticity 3. Short Run Equilibrium • Short Run Supply Curve for a Price Taking Firm • Profit Function • Producer Surplus 5. Profit Maximization and Input Demand • Marginal Revenue product • Substitution effect • Output effect 2 Profit Maximization • A profit-maximizing firm chooses both its inputs and its outputs with the sole goal of achieving maximum economic profits – seeks to maximize the difference between total revenue and total economic costs • If firms are strictly profit maximizers, they will make decisions in a “marginal” way – examine the marginal profit obtainable from producing one more unit of hiring one additional laborer Output Choice • Total revenue for a firm is given by R(q) = p(q)q • In the production of q, certain economic costs are incurred [C(q)] • Economic profits () are the difference between total revenue and total costs (q) = R(q) – C(q) = p(q)q –C(q) Output Choice • The necessary condition for choosing the level of q that maximizes profits can be found by setting the derivative of the function with respect to q equal to zero d dR dC ' (q ) 0 dq dq dq MR dR dC MC dq dq • To maximize economic profits, the firm should choose the output for which marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost Second-Order Conditions • MR = MC is only a necessary condition for profit maximization • For sufficiency, it is also required that d 2 d' (q ) 0 2 dq q q * dq q q * • “marginal” profit must be decreasing at the optimal level of q Marginal Revenue, Marginal Cost, and Profit Maximization A firm chooses output q*, so that profit, the difference AB between revenue R and cost C, is maximized. At that output, marginal revenue (the slope of the revenue curve) is equal to marginal cost (the slope of the cost curve). The second-order condition prevents us from mistaking q which is less than q0 as a maximum Δπ/Δq = ΔR/Δq − ΔC/Δq = 0 MR(q) = MC(q) Marginal Revenue • If a firm can sell all it wishes without having any effect on market price, marginal revenue will be equal to price • If a firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve, more output can only be sold if the firm reduces the good’s price dR d [ p(q ) q ] dp marginal revenue MR(q ) pq dq dq dq • If a firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve, marginal revenue will be a function of output • If price falls as a firm increases output, marginal revenue will be less than price Marginal Revenue from linear demand function • Suppose that the demand curve is q = 100 – 10p • Solving for price, we get p = -q/10 + 10 • This means that total revenue is R = pq = -q2/10 + 10q • Marginal revenue will be given by MR = dR/dq = -q/5 + 10 Profit Maximization • To determine the profit-maximizing output, we must know the firm’s costs • If output can be produced at a constant average and marginal cost of $4, then MR = MC -q/5 + 10 = 4 q = 30 Marginal Revenue and Elasticity • The concept of marginal revenue is directly related to the elasticity of the demand curve facing the firm • The price elasticity of demand is equal to the percentage change in quantity that results from a one percent change in price eq,p dq / q dq p dp / p dp q Marginal Revenue and Elasticity • This means that q dp q dp 1 p1 MR p p1 e dq p dq q ,p – if the demand curve slopes downward, eq,p < 0 and MR < p – if the demand is elastic, eq,p < -1 and marginal revenue will be positive – if the demand is infinitely elastic, eq,p = - and marginal revenue will equal price Marginal Revenue and Elasticity eq,p < -1 MR > 0 eq,p = -1 MR = 0 eq,p > -1 MR < 0 The Inverse Elasticity Rule • Because MR = MC when the firm maximizes profit, we can see that 1 MC p1 e q ,p e q ,p p MC 1 e q ,p • The “markup” will fall as the demand curve facing the firm becomes more elastic • If eq,p > -1, MC < 0 • This means that firms will choose to operate only at points on the demand curve where demand is elastic Markup Pricing • • • • • What does it mean? Where is it used? Why? Markup on price or cost? Should it be a constant? How does markup relate to profit maximization? Markup Pricing • What does it mean? – It is a pricing technique whereby a certain percentage of cost of goods sold or of price is added to the cost of goods sold in order to obtain the market price. • Markup on price or cost? – Suppose an item costs $50 to produce and is sold for $100. – Whether it is 50 percent markup or a markup of 100 percent. – In the 1st instance the margin is a markup on price (the proportion of the selling price that represents an amount added to the cost of the goods sold) – In 2nd case the markup is the markup on cost (the proportion of the cost of goods sold that is added on to that figure to arrive at the selling price) Profit Maximization & Markup • Profit is maximum when: P1 1 EP MR MC EP 1 MC MC P MC EP 1 EP 1 Profit maximizing markup is inversely related to price elasticity as follows: 1 markup EP 1 Profit Maximization & Markup • Note: As long as Ep (which is nearly always negative) Value of 100 x -1 / (Ep + 1) = Elasticity Optimal percent has an absolute value Coefficient markup on Cost larger than 1, m will be -2 100 positive. -3 50 • Profit maximizing markup is lower the higher the -4 33.3 absolute value of the own -5 25 price elasticity of demand -9 12.5 for the good or the service. The formula relating to markup on price to elasticity : Markup = -1/Ep Average Revenue Curve • If we assume that the firm must sell all its output at one price, we can think of the demand curve facing the firm as its average revenue curve – shows the revenue per unit yielded Marginal Revenue Curve • The marginal revenue curve shows the extra revenue provided by the last unit sold • In the case of a downward-sloping demand curve, the marginal revenue curve will lie below the demand curve Marginal Revenue Curve Price As output increases from 0 to q1, total revenue increases so MR > 0 As output increases beyond q1, total revenue decreases so MR < 0 p1 D (average revenue) Quantity per period q1 MR Marginal Revenue Curve • When the demand curve shifts, its associated marginal revenue curve shifts as well – a marginal revenue curve cannot be calculated without referring to a specific demand curve Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm Market price SMC SAC SAVC P* = MR Maximum profit occurs where P = SMC q* Quantity per period Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm Market price SMC SAC SAVC P* = MR Since P > SAC, profit > 0 q* Quantity per period Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm Market price SMC P** SAC SAVC P* = MR If the price rises to P**, the firm will produce q** and > 0 q* q** Quantity per period Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm Market price SMC If the price falls to P***, the firm will produce q*** SAC P* = MR SAVC Profit maximization requires that P = SMC and that SMC is upward-sloping P*** q*** q* Quantity per period <0 Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm • The positively-sloped portion of the short-run marginal cost curve is the short-run supply curve for a price-taking firm – it shows how much the firm will produce at every possible market price – firms will only operate in the short run as long as total revenue covers variable cost • the firm will produce no output if p < SAVC Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm • Thus, the price-taking firm’s short-run supply curve is the positively-sloped portion of the firm’s short-run marginal cost curve above the point of minimum average variable cost – for prices below this level, the firm’s profitmaximizing decision is to shut down and produce no output Short-Run Supply by a Price-Taking Firm Market price SMC SAC SAVC The firm’s short-run supply curve is the SMC curve that is above SAVC Quantity per period Short-Run Supply • Suppose that the firm’s short-run total cost curve is SC(v,w,q,k) = vk1 + wq1/k1-/ where k1 is the level of capital held constant in the short run • Short-run marginal cost is SMC(v ,w , q, k1 ) SC w (1 ) / / q k1 q Short-Run Supply • The price-taking firm will maximize profit where w ( 1 ) / / p = SMC SMC q k P 1 • Therefore, quantity supplied will be w q /( 1 ) /( 1 ) k1 P /( 1 ) • To find the firm’s shut - down price, we need to solve for SAVC SVC = wq1/k1-/ SAVC = SVC/q = wq(1-)/k1-/ Profit Functions • A firm’s economic profit can be expressed as a function of inputs = Pq - C(q) = Pf(k,l) - vk - wl • Only the variables k and l are under the firm’s control – the firm chooses levels of these inputs in order to maximize profits • treats P, v, and w as fixed parameters in its decisions Profit Functions • A firm’s profit function shows its maximal profits as a function of the prices that the firm faces ( P, v, w) Max[ Pf (k , l ) vk wl ] k ,l Envelope Results • We can apply the envelope theorem to see how profits respond to changes in output and input prices ( P ,v ,w ) ( P ,v ,w ) k( P ,v ,w ) q( P ,v ,w ) v P ( P ,v ,w ) (l P ,v ,w ) w Producer Surplus in the Short Run • The profit function is nondecreasing in output prices, we know that if P2 > P1 (P2,…) (P1,…) • The welfare gain to the firm of this price increase can be measured by welfare gain = (P2,…) – (P1,…) Mathematically, we can use the envelope theorem results P2 p2 P1 p1 welfare gain q( P )dP ( / P )dP ( P2 ,...) ( P1,...) Producer Surplus in the Short Run Market price SMC P2 P1 If the market price is P1, the firm will produce q1 If the market price rises to P2, the firm will produce q2 q1 q2 Quantity per period Producer Surplus in the Short Run Market price SMC The firm’s profits rise by the shaded area P2 P1 q1 q2 Quantity per period Producer Surplus in the Short Run Market price SMC Suppose that the firm’s shutdown price is P0 P1 P0 q1 Quantity per period Producer Surplus in the Short Run Market price SMC Producer surplus at a market price of P1 is the shaded area P1 P0 q1 Quantity per period Producer Surplus in the Short Run • The extra profits available from facing a price of P1 are defined to be producer surplus P1 producer surplus ( P1,...) ( P0 ,...) q( P )dP P0 • Producer surplus is the extra return that producers make by making transactions at the market price over and above what they would earn if nothing were produced – the area below the market price and above the supply curve Producer Surplus in the Short Run • Because the firm produces no output at the shutdown price, (P0,…) = -vk1 – profits at the shutdown price are equal to fixed costs • This implies that producer surplus = (P1,…) – (P0,…) = (P1,…) – (-vk1) = (P1,…) + vk1 producer surplus is equal to current profits plus shortrun fixed costs Profit Maximization and Input Demand • A firm’s output is determined by the amount of inputs it chooses to employ – the relationship between inputs and outputs is summarized by the production function • A firm’s economic profit can also be expressed as a function of inputs (k,l) = Pq –C(q) = Pf(k,l) – (vk + wl) • The FOCs for a maximum are /k = P[f/k] – v = 0 /l = P[f/l] – w = 0 Profit Maximization and Input Demand • A profit-maximizing firm should hire any input up to the point at which its marginal contribution to revenues is equal to the marginal cost of hiring the input. • MRPL = PL and MRPK = PK • These FOCs for profit maximization also imply cost minimization – they imply that MRTS = w/v Profit Maximization and Input Demand • To ensure a true maximum, SOCs require that kk = fkk < 0 ll = fll < 0 kk ll - kl2 = fkkfll – fkl2 > 0 – capital and labor must exhibit sufficiently diminishing marginal productivities so that marginal costs rise as output expands Input Demand Functions • In principle, the first-order conditions can be solved to yield input demand functions Capital Demand = k(P,v,w) Labor Demand = l(P,v,w) • These demand functions are unconditional –they implicitly allow the firm to adjust its output to changing prices Single-Input Case • We expect l/w 0 – diminishing marginal productivity of labor • The first order condition for profit maximization was /l = P[f/l] – w = 0 Two-Input Case • For the case of two (or more inputs), the story is more complex – if there is a decrease in w, there will not only be a change in l but also a change in k as a new cost-minimizing combination of inputs is chosen • when k changes, the entire fl function changes • But, even in this case, l/w 0 Two-Input Case • When w falls, two effects occur – substitution effect • if output is held constant, there will be a tendency for the firm to want to substitute l for k in the production process – output effect • a change in w will shift the firm’s expansion path • the firm’s cost curves will shift and a different output level will be chosen Substitution Effect k per period If output is held constant at q0 and w falls, the firm will substitute L for K in the production process Because of diminishing MRTS along an isoquant, the substitution effect will always be negative q0 l per period Output Effect A decline in w will lower the firm’s MC Price MC MC’ Consequently, the firm will choose a new level of output that is higher P q0 q1 Quantity per period Output Effect Output will rise to q1 k per period Thus, the output effect also implies a negative relationship between l and w q0 q1 l per period Input Demand • For a fixed quantity, as price of labor decreases from $2 to $1, firm moves along its labor demand curve from B to A. Increase in output shifts the demand curve. Cross-Price Effects • No definite statement can be made about how capital usage responds to a wage change – a fall in the wage will lead the firm to substitute away from capital – the output effect will cause more capital to be demanded as the firm expands production Substitution and Output Effects • We have two concepts of demand for any input – the conditional demand for labor, lc(v,w,q) – the unconditional demand for labor, l(P,v,w) • At the profit-maximizing level of output lc(v,w,q) = l(P,v,w) Substitution and Output Effects • Differentiation with respect to w yields c c (l P ,v ,w ) l ( v ,w ,q ) l ( v ,w ,q ) q w w q w substitution effect output effect total effect