* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download On the Dynamics of Profit – and Wage
Economic democracy wikipedia , lookup
Fiscal multiplier wikipedia , lookup
Non-monetary economy wikipedia , lookup
Refusal of work wikipedia , lookup
Ragnar Nurkse's balanced growth theory wikipedia , lookup
Business cycle wikipedia , lookup
Production for use wikipedia , lookup
THE DYNAMICS OF DIFFERENT REGIMES OF DEMAND-LED EXPANSION. by Amit Bhaduri Professor, Department of Economics, University of Pavia 27100 Pavia, Italy Any redistribution of income between profits and wages would have contradictory effects in terms of aggregate demand, so long as the propensities to consume are different for the two classes. For instance, the lowering of the real wage rate would tend to depress total consumption expenditure by redistributing income against the wage earners with a higher propensity to consume. At the same time, it might also encourage investment by increasing the margin of profit per unit of sale. Depending on which effect dominates quantitatively, two alternative regimes or paths both led by demand emerge: the consumption- or wage-led path which has also been called ‘stagnationist’ ,and the investment- or profit-led path called ‘exhilarationist’ (Bhaduri and Marglin, 1990; Marglin and Bhaduri, 1990). The essential formalism is simple. With full capacity (potential) output normalised at unity, the saving of the economy is written as, (1) S= s.h.z , where is the saving propensity out of profit, and all wage is assumed to be ( ) = share of profit in output; and z consumed for expositional simplicity; h = P Y * = Y * = degree of capacity utilization, with Y = 1 , i.e. the normalized level of full Y capacity output, 1≥ z , h≥ 0. We assume investment depends positively on both capacity utilization (z) and profit margin (m) or profit share (h) are by definition positively related as, h = m/(1+m). Assuming for expositional simplicity, static expectation, the investment function is written as (2) I = I( z, h ) , Iz. >0, Ih >0. From (1) and (2), the slope of the locus of saving – investment equality, the ISlocus, is derived through total differentiation as, (3) dz /dh = (Ih -sz) / (sh-Iz ) The positive slope of (3) indicates that a higher profit share (h) results in higher capacity utilization (z), placing the economy in the exhilarationist regime. In this case the stimulating effect of the higher profit share on investment expenditure outweighs its depressing effect on consumption expenditure. When the slope (3) is negative, the economy is said to be in the stagnationist regime the opposite reason. However, the two regimes have normally been distinguished by assuming as valid the stability condition of the one-variable income adjustment process through the Keynesian multiplier mechanism. This requires saving to be more responsive than investment to changes in income, making the denominator of the right hand side of expression (3) positive. (4) Thus, assuming (sh –Iz )> 0, 1 (5) (Ih-sh)> 0, implies that investment is more responsive than saving to profit share, setting the economy on an profit-led exhilarationist path; if, on the other hand, (6) (Ih –sh)< 0, the economy is on a wage led stagnationist path for the opposite reason. However, this analysis remains valid only so long as the distribution of income (h) is treated as an exogenous variable. In effect, this makes the underlying dynamical system correspond to the usual single variable income adjustment process of Keynesian theory with income distribution given, but capacity utilization (z) adjusting to excess demand or supply in the product market. With capacity utilization (z) as the only endogenous variable in the system, the dynamic adjustment equation, in view of (1) and (2) becomes, (7) dz /dt = α [ I( h,z) -shz ] , where α>0 is some arbitrary positive of adjustment. However, the above argument could be reversed by making income distribution (h) the endogenous variable adjusting to excess demand or supply in the product market, while the degree of capacity utilization is assumed exogenously fixed, say at the full employment or full capacity level. In this case an excess of demand in the product market, would raise the price level; and, if the money wage rate fails to keep pace in percentage terms, the real wage rate would fall, the margin and share of profit would rise. This would tend to close the gap between investment and saving at the exogenously given full employment or full capacity level of output. This theory of distribution, sketched originally by Keynes (1930; see also 1936,p.vii), was developed later as the Keynesian theory of distribution (Kaldor, 1956; Pasinetti, 1962; Robinson, 1962, Marglin, 1984). The theory presumes not only full employment, but also ‘forced saving’ by the workers even in a situation of full employment. On the other hand, if this latter assumption is abandoned, the possibility of 2 a ’profit squeeze, rather than ‘forced saving’ by the workers, has to accommodated in the analysis. In this case the money wage rate would rise faster than the price level, and the share of profit would fall rather than rise in response to excess demand in the product market. Thus, a more general version of the dynamic adjustment equation for the ‘Keynesian’ theory of distribution might be written as, (8) dh/dt= β [ I( h,z) -shz ] , where the speed of adjustment β >0 in case of ‘forced saving’ by the workers, but β <0 in case of ‘profit squeeze’. Note the central difference between adjustment equations (7) and (8).In the former, the profit margin as well as profit share are given which makes the real wage inflexible so that the entire burden of adjustment falls on capacity utilization (Kalecki, 1971). In the latter case, the margin is flexible but capacity utilization is fixed by assumption, making adjustment work exclusively through the real wage rate, i.e. income distribution. Consequently in a more general case in which neither the profit margin and share (h) nor the degree of capacity utilization(z) is treated as exogenous , and both are endogenous variables reacting simultaneously to an excess demand or supply in the product market , we have a coupled dynamical system consisting of (7) and (8). The product market clearing, equilibrium path of the system depicted by the IS-curve with its slope given in (3) still remains the same. However, the stability property of this two variable dynamical system need no longer correspond to the one- variable stability condition (4) of the usual Keynesian system. Moreover, since both z and h are assumed to be endogenous, a positive relation between z and h placing the economy on the profit- led exhilarationist path must hold, if both α and β are positive. This means that ‘forced saving’ by the workers necessarily implies that the economy is necessarily on an exhilarationist path, when both z and h are endogenous. Obversely, with α>0, but β<0 in the ‘profit squeeze’ case the economy is necessarily placed on a wage-led 3 stagnationist path. This can seen easily from dividing (7) by (8) to obtain the integral curve determining the sign of the slope of the IS locus as, (9) dz /dh= α / β, where α >0 but β can be positive or negative. . The stability of the dynamical system (7) and (8) may be examined by considering the function, (10) V (t ) = 1 [ I ( h, z ) − shz ]2 2 The function V is a Liapunov function with all the desirable properties for stability in the large, i.e. positive definiteness and unboundness as (I-S) tends to infinity, provided also dV/dt <0 (e.g. LaSalle and Lefschetz, 1961; Minorsky, 1962; Gondolfo,1995), . This last condition can be checked by differentiating (1) and (2) with respect to time, and substituting from (7) and (8) to obtain, (11) dV 2 = [ I − S ] β ( I h − sz ) − α ( sh − I z ) < 0 dt Therefore, global stability requires, (12) β (I h − s p z ) < α (s p h − I z ) . Using (3) and (12), a complete classification of the various cases of profit-led or exhilarationist as well as wage-led or stagnationist sub-regimes according to their stability property becomes possible. Note however that this classification is done in two successive steps to highlight the difference between a single endogenous variable stability analysis given by conditions (3) to (6), and the stability analysis in the case of 4 the dynamical system (7) to (9) when both the variables, h and z are endogenous.Classification (α > 0; β ⊕ 0) Sign of Cases dz / dh from (3) A.1 (s ph − I z ) > 0 Positive Nature of Regime Profit-led Stability Unambiguously larger is α Negative Wage-led β Unambiguously from (9),since z and h are endogenous Stability stable, but not ambiguous; possible and (I h − s p z ) < 0 B.1 for β < 0 more likely the possible (I h − s p z ) > 0 (s p h − I z ) > 0 for β > 0 ambiguous, and stable, but not and A.2 Stability Property from (11) from more likely to (9),since z and h be stable larger Negative Wage-led are endogenous. α Unambiguously Stability β (s p h − I z ) < 0 unstable, but not ambiguous. and possible (I h − s p z ) > 0 (9),since z and h likely, the larger B.2 Positive Profit-led from Stability less are endogenous. α Stability Unambiguously β (s p h − I z ) < 0 ambiguous, and unstable, but not and less likely the possible (I h − s p z ) < 0 larger is (α β ). . from (9),since z and hare endogenous. 5 In the case of the general dynamical system with both variables endogenous, it emerges as a general result that the stability of the neither the profit-led nor the wageled path of expansion is unambiguously stable. The stability depends critically on the relative magnitudes of the speeds of adjustment, i.e. the absolute value of the ratio (α / β). Thus, when β>o i.e. the case of ‘forced saving’ by the workers, only the profitled path is relevant, and the usual one variable Keynesian stability condition (4) may or may not matter in determining the stability of this profit- led regime depending on the ratio of the relative speeds of adjustment. The higher (lower) is the ratio, implying faster (slower) speed of adjustment of capacity utilization relative to that of income distribution, the more (less) likely is the stability of the profit –led regime, depending on whether the sensitivity of saving is more (less) than that of investment to changes in income (i.e.condition 4 satisfied or not). In a similar manner, in the case of ‘profit squeeze’ i.e.β < 0, leading to wage- led expansion, again the Keynesian stability condition may or not be relevant depending on the (absolute) value of the relative speeds of adjustment. It follows the Keynesian stability condition is neither necessary nor sufficient without considering simultaneously the relative speeds of adjustment of capacity utilization and, of income distribution. The critical role played by the relative speeds of adjustment points towards an interesting possibility of extending this analysis. It is often argued that Keynesian analysis neglects the ‘supply side’. One way of reckoning with the supply side would be to incorporate into the analysis the fact that the speed of adjustment of capacity utilization tends to decrease as the degree of utilization increases, and various bottlenecks begin to appear on the supply side. This means α can be treated as a decreasing function of z to incorporate partly considerations on the supply side. This 6 would lead non-linearities which we have avoided dealing with in this paper, and must remain a matter of future research. AMIT BHADURI Department of Economics University of Pavia, Italy e-mail [email protected] 7 References Bhaduri, A. and Marglin, S. 1990. ‘Unemployment and the real wage: the economic basis for eontesting political ideologies,’ Cambridge Journal of Economics, 14: 375-93. Kaldor, N. 1956. ‘Alternative theories of distribution,’ Review of Economic Studies, 23: 83-100. Kalecki, M. 1971. Selected Essays in the Dynamics of the Capitalist Economy, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Keynes, J. M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, London, Macmillan. Marglin, S. A. 1984 Growth, Distribution and Prices, Cambridge, Mass; Harvard University Press. Pasinetti, L. L. 1962. ‘The rate of profit and income distribution in relation to the rate of economic growth’, Review of Economic Studies, 29: 267-79. 8 The “Profit Squeeze” Case (Appendix) [ ] [ z& = α I (h, z ) − s p hz ; h& = − µ I (h, z ) − s p hz V (t ) = 1 (I − S )2 2 dV dt = (I − S ) I h h& + I z z& − s p zh& − s p hz& [ ] [ ] = (I − S ) (I h − s p z )h& + (I z − s p h )z& ] = (I − S ){(I h − s p z )[− µ (I − S )] + (I z − s p h )α (I − S )} [ ] = (I − S ) − µ (I h − s p z ) + α (I z − s p h ) < 0 2 For dV <0 ⇒ dt − µ (I h − s p z ) + α (I z − s p h ) < 0 − µ (I h − s p z ) < −α (I z − s p h ) or µ (s p z − I h ) < α (s p h − I z ) (11A) i.e. instead of (11) α (s p h − I z ) > µ (s p z − I h ) ; β = µ > 0 . Case A.1 αH.S.>0; R.H.S.<0 ∴unambiguously stable α A.2 αH.S.>0; R.H.S.>0 ∴stability ambiguous; larger more likely stability µ α B.1 αH.S.<0; R.H.S.<0 ∴stability ambiguous, larger stability less likely µ B.2 αH.S.<0; R.H.S.>0 ∴unambiguously unstable 9