Download In the last lecture, we talked about how a monopolist maximizes

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts

Economics wikipedia , lookup

Brander–Spencer model wikipedia , lookup

Marginalism wikipedia , lookup

Surplus value wikipedia , lookup

Supply and demand wikipedia , lookup

Externality wikipedia , lookup

Production for use wikipedia , lookup

Microeconomics wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
Other Market Models
Monopolies
Calculating a Monopolist’s Profit and Loss
Page 1 of 1
In the last lecture, we talked about how a monopolist maximizes profits by choosing the price and quantity where marginal
revenue equals marginal cost. In this lesson we’ll consider the question, is the monopolist making a profit or not? Because
even though you’re doing the best you can you may still not be covering all of your costs. Even though you’re maximizing
your profit, you may in effect be simply minimizing your losses. Are you making a positive economic profit or not?
In order to answer this question, we need to introduce the average cost curve. Now here’s a curve that we’ve seen before.
Remember the average cost curve includes not only the variable costs, but the fixed costs of production as well. The
average cost curve is U-shaped and it cuts through the marginal cost curve at the point of minimum average cost. When the
marginal cost is below the average cost, it pulls the marginal…well, let me be real clear about this, when the marginal cost
curve is below the average cost curve, it pulls the average down. And when the marginal cost is above the average cost
curve, it pulls it up. That’s why average cost cuts through marginal cost at the point of minimum average cost. Now this is
simply review of our earlier discussion of cost curves. Now we’re ready to ask the question, Is the monopolist making a
profit or not?
Well, remember what profit is. Profit is defined as equal to total revenue minus total cost. And if we want to divide both the
total revenue and the total cost by the quantity we can calculate the profit that the firm is making per unit of output. Now,
total revenue is equal to price times quantity. So if we divide price times quantity by the quantity produced, we’re simply
going to get the price of the product. And if we divide the total cost by the quantity, we’re going to get the average cost. So
the amount of profit that the firm is earning per unit will be the difference between the price and the average cost. We might
call this the profit margin or the per-unit profit. If we look at this profit margin and we multiply it by the total quantity of output
then we get total profit for the firm. So price minus average cost is the profit per unit and multiplying that by the number of
units produced gives us the total profit for the firm.
Now let’s find out how much profit our monopolist is making when he maximizes his profits. So remember you maximize
profit by producing where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. Drop that down to the horizontal axis, and you get the
monopolist’s profit maximizing quantity. Go up to the demand curve, and you get the price the monopolist charges for the
product. So here’s the monopolist’s profit-maximizing price, P star sub M. Now how much does it cost the monopolist to
produce each one of those units? Well go from the quantity up to the average cost curve and you find the average cost of
production. Now I can take this line over to the access and that gives me the average cost of the monopolist when the
monopolist is maximizing profit. This rectangle right here- price minus average cost multiplied by the quantity of output- this
rectangle is the monopoly profit. Here’s another way of seeing the monopoly profit: price times quantity gives us this big
rectangle. Price times quantity is the revenue that the monopolist is earning. Subtract from that revenue the costs of
production. So take the average cost, multiply it by the quantity produced, and that gives you the total cost of production.
Total revenue minus total cost leaves you with the monopolist’s economic profit, the top rectangle. In this case the average
cost is low enough that the monopolist is actually making an economic profit. The economic profit is positive. You can
imagine, however, another picture where the average cost curve is further up, that is if we increase the fixed costs of this
monopolist, or change the technology or the price of the inputs, or the economies of scale, the average cost curve might be
completely above the demand curve. In that case, when the monopolist is maximizing profit, average cost is greater than
price, in that case the monopolist would actually be making a loss. However, if average cost is less than price, as in the
picture I’ve drawn here, the monopolist is making a positive economic profit.
So, monopolies can be profitable, or unprofitable. It all depends on their costs. Let me do a quick review. A monopolist
always maximizes profit by pricing the product where marginal revenue equals marginal cost. That’s always the best you can
do. However, that doesn’t guarantee that you are making a profit. To find out whether you’re making a profit or not you have
to compare the price at that particular output with the average cost of production. If price is greater than average cost of
production, the monopolist is making an economic profit. However, if the costs are so high that the average cost is greater
than the price at this particular output then the monopolist would be making a loss. So, this is how monopolists try to make a
profit and sometimes they’re lucky and wind up with a substantial economic profit. However, is the monopoly good for
society or not? If we look at a monopoly from the point of view of normative economics, will we conclude that the monopoly
is a good thing or a bad thing. In the next lesson we will look at the social costs of monopoly.