* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Economics
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Economics Chapter 6 Supply, Demand and Government Policies When new policies are introduced they may have good intentions to solve particular problems or help groups of people but new policies generate new incentives and as a result the consequences may go far beyond those envisaged by the policy makers. Price controls are usually enancted when policy makers believe that the market price of a good or service is unfair to buyers or sellers. Yet as we will see these policies can generate inequities of their own. Policy makers use taxes both to influence market outcomes and to raise revenue for public purposes. Subsidy Payment to buyers and sellers to supplement income or lower costs and which thus encourages consumption or provides an advantage to the recipient A subsidy almost works exactly as the reverse of taxes. They are often used to encourage the supply of a product which is being underproduced and deemed to be in the public interest. In the case of subsidies, someone has to pay for the subsidy and firms and consumers may benefit in different ways Controls on prices Price ceiling A legal maximum on the price at which a good can be sold Price Floor A legal minimum on the price at which a good can be sold In a competitive market free of government regulation, the price of a good adjusts to balance supply and demand: at the equilibrium price, the quantity of ice cream that buyers want to buy exactly equals the quantity that sellers want to sell. The government imposes a legal maximum on the price at which ice cream can be sold. Because the price is not allowed to rise above this level the legislated maximum is called a price ceiling or a price cap. The government imposes a legal minimum on the price, the price cannot fall below this level the legislated minimum is called a price floor. How price ceilings affect market outcomes If the price of the good is below the price ceiling it is not binding. Market forces naturally move the economy to the equilibrium and the price ceiling has no effect on the price or the quantity sold. If the price of a good is above the price ceiling it is a binding constraint on the market The quantity of one good demanded exceeds the quantity supplied. There is a shortage of the good Sellers could ration their good according to their own personal bias Some sellers may not feel it worth while continuing in the market and leave thus depressing market supply When a government imposes a binding price ceiling on a competitive market a shortage of the good arises and sellers must ration the scarce goods among the large number of potential buyers By contrast the rationing mechanism in a free competitive market is both efficient and impersonal. Free markets ration goods with prices How price floors affect market outcomes Price floors like price ceilings are an attempt by the government to maintain prices at other than equilibrium levels. Whereas a price ceiling places a legal maximum on prices a price floor places a legal minimum If the equilibrium price is above the price floor the price floor is not binding. Market forces naturally move the economy to the equilibrium and the price floor has no effect I f the equilibrium price is below the price floor the price floor is a binding constraint on the market. The forces of supply and demand tend to move the price towards the equilibrium price but when the market hits the floor it can fall no further. The market price equals the price floor Just as price ceilings and shortages can lead to undesirable rationing mechanism so can price floors and surpluses. In the case of a price floor some sellers are unable to sell all they want at the market price. In a free market the price serves as the rationing mechanism and sellers can sell all they want at the equilibrium price Evaluating price controls This principle explains whay economists usually oppose price ceilings and price floors. To economists prices are not the outcome of some haphazard process. Prices are the result of the millions of business and consumer decisions that lie behind the supply and demand curves. When policy makers set prices by legal decree they obscure the signals that normally guide the allocation of society resources. Price controls are often aimed at helping the poor: price ceilings on rents Other ways of helping without controlling prices: Government can make housing more affordable by paying a fraction of the rent for poor families. Unlike rent control such rent subsidies do not reduce the quantity of housing supplied and therefore do not lead to housing shortages Taxes Tax incidence The manner in which the burden of a tax is shared among participants in a market All governments use taxes to raise revenue for public projects such as roads schools and national defence. But who actually bears the burden of the tax? Economists use the term tax incidence to refer to the distribution of a tax burden. As we will see some surprising lessons about tax incidence arise just by applying the tools of supply and demand How taxes on sellers affect market outcomes Step 1 Step 2 Step 3 Implications The immediate impact of a tax is on the sellers -the quantity demanded of the product at any given price is the same thus the demand curve does not change -tax makes production of the good less profitable at any given price so the supply curves shifts -because the tax on sellers raises the cost of producing and selling the good it reduces the quantity supplied at every price. -the supply curve shifts to the left (upward) -we can now compare the initial and the new equilibrium. -the equilibrium price of the good rises, the equilibrium quantity falls -a tax on sellers places a wedge between the price that buyers pay and the price that sellers receive -the wedge between the buyers´ price and the sellers´ price is the same and would be the same regardless of whether the tax is levied on buyers or sellers ->Buyers and sellers share the burden of the tax Elasticity and tax incidence When a good is taxed buyers and sellers of the good share the burden of the tax. But how exactly is the tax burden divided? Only rarely will it be shared equally: Which curve shifts depends on whether the tax is levied on buyers or sellers. As we have seen this is irrelevant for the incidence of the tax A tax in a market with a very elastic supply and relatively inelastic demand Sellers are very responsive to changes in the price of the good (supply curve is relatively flat) whereas buyers are not very responsive (so the demand curve is relatively steep) When a tax is imposed on a market with these elasticities the price received by sellers does not fall much so sellers bear only a small burden. By contrast the price paid by buyers rises substantially indicating that buyers bear most of the burden of the tax A tax in a market with relatively inelastic supply and very elastic demand In this case sellers are not very responsive to changes in the price (so the supply curve is steeper) while buyers are very responsive (so demand curve is flatter). The price paid by buyers does not rise much while the price received by sellers falls substantially. Thus sellers bear most of the burden of the tax. In this case sellers know that if they try to pass on the tax to buyers that demand will fall by a relatively large amount A tax burden falls more heavily on the side of the market that is less elastic. Why is this true? In essence the elasticity measures the willingness of buyers or sellers to leave the market when conditions become unfavourable. A small elasticity of demand means that buyers do not have good alternatives to consuming this particular good. A small elasticity of supply means that sellers do not have good alternatives to producing this particular good. When the good is taxed the side of the market with fewer good alternatives cannot easily leave the market and must therefore bear more of the burden of the tax How subsidies affect market outcomes Subsidies are levied when governments want to encourage the consumption of a `good´ which they deem is currently underreproduced. Subsidies are generally given to sellers and have the effect of reducing the cost of production as opposed to a tax which increases the cost of production. Subsidies exist in a variety of different areas including education, transport etc Step 1 If the government gives a subsidy of 20Euros per journey to train operators it is the supply curve for journeys which is affected ->the demand curve is not affected because the number of train journeys demanded at each price stays the same Step 2 -subsidy to train operators reduces the cost to the train operators the supply curve shifts to the right by the amount of the subsidy ->Train operators are willing to supply more train journeys at every price Step 3 -comparing the initial and the new equilibrium we can see that the equilibrium price of each train journey is now lower and the equilibrium number of journeys travelled increases -Passangers and train operators both benefit from the subsidy as passengers can obtain train tickets at a lower price thant before the subsidy and have more journeys available and sellers receive more revenue than they did before the subsidy allowing them the potential to invest in the service they provide Implications There is a considerable debate surrounding the value of subsidies -altering the incentives for people to travel on the train rather than on the roads and so have the benefit of reducing congestion on the roads as well as reducing possible pollution that is associated with road use -subsidies are often financed by the tax payer but may encourage firms to overproduce which has a wider effect on the market Chapter 8 Application- the costs of Taxation The effects of taxes on welfare might at first seem obvious. The government imposes taxes in order to raise revenue, and that revenue must come out of someone´s pocket Buyers and sellers are worse off when a good is taxed The deadweight loss of taxation The effect of a tax on a buyer When a tax is levied on buyers the demand curve shifts downward by the size of the tax. The effect of a tax on a seller When a tax is levied on sellers, the supply curve shifts upward by that amount In either case when the tax is imposed the price paid by buyers rises, and the price received by sellers falls. Taxes place a wedge between the price buyers pay and the price sellers receive. Because of this tax wedge, the quantity sold falls below the level that would be sold without a tax. A tax on a good causes the size of the market for the good to shrink. How a tax affects market participants The benefit received by buyers in a market is measured by consumer surplus- the amount buyers are willing to pay for the good minus the amount they actually pay for it. The benefit received by sellers in a market is measured by producer surplus- the amount sellers receive for the good minus their costs Deadweight loss The fall in total surplus that results from a market distortion such as a tax People respond to incentives : When a tax rises the price to buyers and lowers the price to sellers, however it gives buyers an incentive to consume less and sellers an incentive to produce less than they otherwise would. As buyers and sellers respond to these incentives, the size of the market shrinks below its optimum. Thus because taxes distort incentives they cause markets to allocate resources inefficiently Deadwight losses and the gains from trade Taxes cause dead-weight losses because they prevent buyers and sellers from realizing some of the gains from trade Thus these trades do not get made once the tax is imposed. The deadweight loss is the surplus lost because the tax discourages these mutually advantageous trades. The determinants of the deadweight loss What determines whether the deadweight loss from a tax is large or small? The answer is the price elasticities of supply and demand which measures how much the quantity supplied and quantity demanded respond to changes in the price. A tax has a deadweight loss because it induces buyers and sellers to change their behaviour. The tax raises the price paid by buyers so they consume less. At the same time the tax lowers the price received by sellers so they produce less. Because of these changes in behaviour the size of the market shrinks below the optimum. The elasticities of supply and demand measure how much sellers and buyers respond to the changes in price and therefore deterime how much the tax distorts the market outcome. Hence the greater the elasticities of supply and demand the greater the deadweight loss of a tax Deadweight loss and tax revenue as taxes vary The effect of a small, medium, large tax holding constant the market´s supply and demand curves varys The deadweight loss – the reduction in total surplus that results when the tax reduces the size of a market below the optimum- equals the area of the triangle between the supply and the demand curves. As the size of a tax rises the deadweight loss grows larger and larger Rises more rapidly than the size of the tax The government´s tax revenue is the size of the tax times the amount of the good sold. For a very large tax no revenue would be raised because people would stop buying and selling the good altogether Chapter 10 Externalities The market failures examined in this chapter fall under a general category called externalities. An externality arises when a person engages in an activity that influences the well-being of a bystander (a third party) who neither pays nor receives any compensation for that effect. Negative externality Positive externality Individuals and groups make decisions which are designed to maximize their individual or group welfare. In making these decisions there will be private costs and private benefits. Social costs are not taken into consideration by people In the presence of externalities society´s interest in a market outcome extends beyond the well-being of buyers and sellers who participate in the market, it also includes the well-being of bystanders who are affected indirectly. Because buyers and seller neglect the external effects of their actions when deciding how much to demand or supply, the market equilibrium is not efficient when there are externalities. That is the equilibrium fails to maximize the total benefit to society as a whole. Negative externalities How does this externality affect the efficiency of the market outcome? Because of the externality the cost of society of producing a good is larger than the cost to the producers of the good. For each unit of the produced good, the social (external) costs includes the private costs of the producer of the good plus the costs to those bystanders that are affected by the products pollution etc The social cost curve is above the supply curve because it takes into account the external costs imposed on society by the producer The social cost curve is the sum of the private costs and the social or external cost These two curves reflect the social or external cost of the e.g pollution emitted The equilibrium quantity of a product Qmarket is larger than the socially optimal quantity Qoptimum. The reason for this inefficiencys is that the market equilibrium reflects only the private costs of production A tax would shift the supply curve for one good upward by the size of the tax. If the tax accurately reflected the social cost of the pollution released inot the atmosphere the new supply curve would coincide with the social cost curve The use of such a tax is calle internalizing an externality because it gives buyers and sellers in the market an incentive to take account of the external effects of their actions Internalizing an externality Altering incentives so that people take account of the external effects of their actions Positive Externalities Some of the productivity benefits of e.g education spill over and benefit other people as is the case if economic growth is stimulated then this effect would count as a positive externality as well Because the social value (or external benefit) is greater than the private value, the social value curve lies above the demand curve. The social value curve is the private value plus the external benefit to society at each price. The optimal quantity is found where the social value curve and the supply curve (which represents costs) intersect. Hence the socially optimal quantity is greater than the quantity determined by the private market To move the market equilibrium closer to the social optimum a positive externality requires a subsidy. In fact that is exactly the policy governments follow by heavily subsidizing education Negative externalities lead markets to produce a larger quantity than is socially desirable. Positve externalities lead markets to produce a smaller quantity than is socially desirable. To remedy the problem government can internalize the externality by taxing goods that have negative externalities and subsidizing goods that have positive externalities Private Solutions to Externalities People can develope priavate solutions for externalities Charities Colleges and universities get donations from allumni, corporations or foundations since education has positive externalities for society Joint ventures and partnerings The Coase Theorem Coase Theorem The proposition that if private parties can bargain without cost over the allocation of resources, they can solve the problem of externalities on their own According to the Coase Theorm the initial distribution of rights does not matter for market´s ability to reach the efficient outcome. Coase Theorm says that private economic actors can solve the problem of externalities among themselves. Whatever the initial distribution of rights, the interested parties can always reach a bargain in which everyone is better off and the outcome is efficient Why private solutions do not always work Transaction costs The costs that parties incur in the process of agreeing and following through on a bargain Sometimes the interested parties fail to solve an externality problem because of transaction costs Bargaining simply breaks down. The recurrence of wars and labour strikes shows that reaching agreement can be difficult and that failing to reach agreement can be costly Bargaining is especially difficult when the number of interested parties is large because coordinationg everyone is costly Asymmetric information and the assumption of rational behaviour The situation is further complicated byy the existence of free riders. When private bargaining does not work the government can sometimes play a role. The government is an institution designed for collective action. Public Policies towards externalities 1. Command-and-control policies ->regulate behaviour directly 2. Marked-based policies ->provide incentives so that private decision makers will choose to solve the problem on their own Regulation The government can remedy an externality by making certain behaviours either required or forbidden. For example it is a crime in European countries to dump poisonous chemicals into water supply Pigovian Taxes and Subsidies Pigovian Tax A tax enacted to correct the effects of a negative externality The government can use marked-based policies to align private incentives with social efficiency. Economist usually prefer Pigovian taxes over regulations as a way to deal with e.g pollution because such taxes can reduce pollution at a lower cost to society. Pigovian taxes are better for the environment. Under the command-and-control policy pf regulation the factories have no reason to reduce emission further once they have reached the target of 300 tonnes per year. The tax gives the companies an incentive to develope cleaner technologies etc Public/Private Policies towards externalities Property Rights In some cases private solutions to externalities can occur but need some form of legal back-up to be able to work Extending property rights therefore might be one area where externalities can be internalized. For example if property rights over the air that we breathe can be extended than any firm polluting the air could face prosecution The cost of establishing property rights and getting international agreement on what they entail is considerable and my counteract the social benefits they might provide ->Complexe negotiations etc ->property owners may also have insufficient knowledge about their rights and exactly what they mean it is also not a costless exercise to prove that property rights have been violated Objections to Economic Analysis of Pollution Some environmentalists argue that it is in some sense morally wrong to allow anyone to pollute the environment in return for paying a fee Trying to eliminate all pollution would reverse many of the technological advances that allow us to enjoy a high standard of living Chapter 11 Public Goods and common resources When a good does not have a price attached to it private markets cannot ensure that the good is produced and consumed in the proper amounts. In such cases government policy can potentially remedy the market failure and raise economic well-being Three different kinds of goods Excludability Rivalry The property of a good whereby a person can be prevented from using it when they do not pay for it The property of a good whereby one person´s use diminishes other people´s use Private goods Public goods Common resources Goods that are both excludable and rival Goods that are neither excludable nor rival Goods that are rival but not excludable In thinking aobut the various goods in the economy it is useful to group them according to two characteristics 1. Is the good excludable? Can people who do not pay for the use of the good be prevented from using the good? 2. Is the good rival? Does one person´s use of the good diminish another person´s ability to use it? Category 1 Private goods -both exludable and rival Most goods in the economy are private goods like food for example Category 2 Public goods -neither excludable nor rival -people cannot be prevented from using them, one person´s use of a public good does not reduce another person´s ability to use it e.g national defence Category 3 Common resources -are rival but not excludable -e.g fish in the ocean Category 4 Natural monopoly -when a good is excludable but not rival -e.g protection of a small town Because of these external effects, private decisions about consumption and production can lead to an inefficient allocation of resources and government intervention can potentially raise economic well-being Public Goods – The free rider problem Free rider A person who receives the benefit of a good but avoids paying for it One way to view this market failure is that it arises because of an externality Because public goods are not excludable the free rider problem prevents the private market form supplying them. The government however can potentially remedy the problem. If the government decides that the total benefit exceeds the costs it can provide the public good and pay for it with tax revenue making everyone better off Some important public goods National Defence Basic Research Fighting Poverty The defence of the country from foreign aggressors is a classic example of a public good Once the country is defended it is impossible to prevent any single person from enjoying the benefit of this defence The creation of knowledge is a public good Profit-seeking firms tend to free ride on the knowledge created by others and as a result devote too few resources to creating new technologies Anti-poverty programmes are aimed at helping the poor Financed by taxes on families that are financially more successful -can make everyone better off The difficult job of cost-benefit analysis Cost-benefit analysis A study that compares the costs and benefits to society of providing a public good So far we have seen the government provides public goods because the pivate market on its own will not produce an efficient quantity, The government must then determine what kinds of public goods to provide and in what quantities To conduct a study called a cost-benefit-analysis the goal of which is to estimate the total costs and benefits of the project to society as a whole The efficient provision of public goods is therefore intrinsically more difficult tahn the efficient provision of private goods Private goods are provided in the market. Buyers of a private good reveal the value they place on it by the prices they are willing to pay. Sellers reveal their costs by the prices they are willing to accept Common resources Common resources like public goods are not excludable: they are available free of charge to anyone who wants to use them. Common resources are however rival: One person´s use of the common resources reduces other people´s ability to use it Once the good is provided policy makers need to be concerned about how much it is used. This problem is best understood from the classig parable called the Tragedy of the Commons Some important common resources Private decision makers use the common resources too much. Government often regulates behaviour or impose fees to mitigate the problem of overuse Clean Air and Water One can view this market failure as an example of a common-resource problem Congested Roads Fish, Whales and other Wildlife Clean air, water are common resources like open grazing land and excessive pollution is like excessive grazing Roads can be either public good or common resources If a road is not congested then one person´s use does not affect anyone else In this case use is not rival and the road is a public good Yet if a road is congested then use of that road yields a negative externality Commercial value (fish) Chapter 15 Monopoly Microsoft is said to have a monopoly in the market for Windows By contrast a monopoly such as Microsoft has no close competitiors and therefore can influence the market price of its product. While a competitive firm is a price taker a monopoly firm is a price maker Monopolies cannot achieve any level of profit they want because high prices reduce the amount that their customers buy. Altough monopolies can control the price of their goods their profits are not unlimited Monopoly firms are unchecked by competition the outcome in a market with a monopoly is often not in the best interest of society Why monopolies arise Monopoly A firm that is the sole seller of a product without close substitutes In reality firms are said to have a monopoly power if they are a dominant seller in the market and are able to exert some control over the market as a result. In the analysis that follows however the assumption is that there is only one seller The fundamental cause of monopoly is barriers to entry: a monopoly remains the only seller in its market because other firms cannot enter the market and compete with it. Barriers to entry, in turn, have four main sources: 1. A key resource is owned by a single firm 2. The government gives a single firm the exclusive right to produce some good or service 3. The costs of production make a single producer more efficient than a large number of producers 4. A firm is able to gain control of other firms in the market and thus grow in size. Monopoly resources The simplest way for a firm to achieve a monopoly Government-created monopolies Natural monopoly External growth Monopolies arise because the government has given one person or firm the exclusive right to sell some good or service Sometimes the monopoly arises from the sheer political clout of the would-be monopolist ->patent and copyright laws By allowing these monopoly producers to charge higher prices and earn higher profits the laws also encourage some desirable behaviour The benefit of the patent and copyright laws are the increased incentive for creative activity These benefits are offset to some extent by the costs of monopoly priceing which we examine fully later in this chapter A monopoly that arises because a single firm can supply a good or service to an entire market at a smaller cost than could two or more firms ->In some cases the size of the market is one determinant of whether an industry is a natural monopoly A firm might be able to develop monopoly power over its rivals and erect barriers to entry to make it harder for new firms to enter It is for this reason that governments monitor such acquisitors to see if there are implications for competition How monopolies make production and pricing decisions – Monopoly versus competition The key difference between a competitive firm and a monopoly is the monopoly´s ability to influence the price of its output. A competitive firm is small relatively to the market in which it operates and therefore takes the price of its output as given by market conditions Because a monopoly is the sole producer it can alter the price One way to view this difference between a competitive firm and a monopoly is to consider the demand curve that each firm faces Because a competitve firm can sell as much or as little as it wants at this price the competitive firm faces a horizontal demand curve In effect because the competitive firm sells a product with many perfect substitutes the demand curve that any one firm faces is perfectly elastic Because a monopoly is the sole producer in its market its demand curve is the market demand curve. Thus the monopolist´s demand curve slopes downward for all the usual reasons The quantity of output it sells the price of its output increases By adjusting the quantity produced the monopolist can choose any point on the demand curve but it cannot choose a point off the demand curve A monopoly´s revenue The monopolist´s total revenue equals the quantity sold times the price Average revenue: the amount of revenue the firm receives per unit sold. We compute average revenue by taking the number for total revenue and divide it by the quantity of output in the first column A monopolist´s marginal revenue is always less than the price of its good For a monopoly marginal revenue is lower than price because a monopoly faces a downward sloping demand curve. To incease the amount sold a monopoly firm must lower the price of its good. The output effect: More output is sold so Q is higher which tends to increase total revenue The price effect: The price falls so P is lower which tends to decrease total revenue By contrast when a monopoly inceases production by 1 unit it must reduce the price it charges for every unit it sells, and this cut in price reduces revenue on the unit it was already selling. A monopoly´s marginal revenue is less than its price Profit Maximization Thus the monopolist´s profit-maximizing quantity of output is determined by the intersection of the marginal revenue curve and the marginal cost curve. In following this rule for profit-maximization competitive firms and monopolies are alike. The difference between these types of firms: the marginal revenue of a competitive firm equals its price whereas the marginal revenue of a monopoly is less than its price Competitive firm : P=MR=MC Monopoly: P>MR=MC We can now see a key difference between markets with competitive firms and markets with a monopoly firm In competitive markets price equals marginal cost In monopolized markets, price exceeds marginal cost. As we will see in a moment this finding is crucial to understanding the social cost of monopoly The welfare cost of monopoly From the standpoint of a cónsumer this high price makes monopoly undersirable. At the same time however the monopoly is earning profit form charging this high price. From the standpoint of the owners of the firm, the high price makes monopoly very dersirable As in that chapter we use total surplus as our measure of economic well-being. Recall total surplus is the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus Consumer surplus is consumer´s willingness to pay for a good minus the amount they actually pay for it Producer surplus is the amount producers receive for a good minus their costs of producing it. In this case there is a single producer the monopolist The deadweight loss Keep in mind that total surplus equals the value of the good to consumers minus the costs of making the good incurred by the monopoly producer We can evaluate welfare effects of monopoly by comparing the level of output that the monopolist chooses to the level of output that a social planner would choose The deadweight loss caused by monopoly is similar to the deadweight loss caused by a tax. Indeed a monopolist is like a private tax collecter. A tax on a good places a wedge between consumer´s willingness to pay and producer´s costs Because a monopoly exerts its market power by charging a price above the marginal cost it places a similar wedge. In both cases the wedge causes the quantity sold to fall short of the social optimum. The difference between the two cases is that the government gets the revenue from a tax whereas a private firm gets the monopoly profit The monopoly´s profit: A social cost In other words the monopoly´s profit itself does not represent a shrinkage in the size of the economic pie, it merely represents a bigger slice for producers and a smaller slice for consummers The problem in a monopolized market arises because the firm produces and sells a quantity of output below the level that maximizes total surplus. The deadweight loss measures how much the economic pie shrinks as a result This inefficiency is connected to the monopoly´s high price Consumers buy fewer units when the firm raises the price above the marginal cost If the high monopoly price did not discourage some consumers from buying the good it would raise producer surplus by exactly the amount it reduced consumer surplus leaving total surplus the same as could be achieved by a benevolent social planner Price discrimination Price discrimination The business practice of selling the same good at different prices to different customers Price discrimination is not possible when a good is sold in a competitive market Deadweight loss is the usual inefficiency that arises whenever a monopolist charges a price above the marginal cost Price discrimination is a rational strategy for a profit-maximizing monopolist By charging different prices to different customers a monopolist can increase its profit In essence a price-discriminating monopolist charges each customer a price closer to his or her willingness to pay than is possible with a single price Price discrimination requires the ability to separate customers according to their willingness to pay In particular one such force is arbitrage the process of buying a good in one market at a low price and selling it in another market at a higher price in order to profit from the price difference Price discrimination can raise economic welfare. The analytic of price discrimination Without price discrimination the firm charges a single price above the marginal cost. Because some potential customers who value the good at more than marginal cost do not buy it at this high price, the monopoly causes a deadweight loss. Yet when a firm can perfectly price discrimination each customer who values the good at more than marginal cost buys the good and is charged his willingness to pay. There is no deadweight loss The entire surplus derived from the market goes to the monopoly producer in the form of profit Firms price discriminate by dividing customers into groups The analysis of these pricing schemes is quite complicated ant it turns out that there is no general answer to this question. Compared to the monopoly outcome with a single price, imperfect price discrimination can raise lower or leave unchange total surplus in a market Price discrimination raises the monopoly´s profit Public policy towards monopolies Monopolies produce less than the socially desirable quantity of output and as a result charge prices above marginal cost. Policy makers in the government can respond to the problem of monopoly in one of four ways 1. Trying to make monopolized industries more competitive 2. Regulating the behaviour of the monopolies 3. Turning some private monopolies into public enterprises 4. Doing nothing at all Competition legislation covers three main areas 1. Acting against cartels and cases where businesses engage in restrictive business practices which prevent free trade 2. Banning pricing strategies 3. Monitoring and supervising acquisitions and joint ventures Regulation This solution is common in the case of natural monopolies such as utility companies like water, gas, etc Companies are not allowed to charge any price they want. Instead government agencies regulate their prices Public ownership Government can run monopoly itself. Private owners have an incentive to minimize costs as long as they reap part of the benefit in form of higher profit. If the firm´s managers are doing a bod job of keeping costs down, the firm´s owners will fire them By contrast if the government bureaucrats who run a monopoly do a bad job the losers are the customers and taxpayers whose only recourse is the political system Chapter 22 Frontiers of Microeconomics How do economists try to expand their understanding of human behaviour and society? Three approaches: 1. Asymmetric information: many times in life people are better informed than others, and this difference in information can affect the choices people they make and how they deal with one another. 2. Political economy: the government policy aims to improve the market -> market failure 3. Behavioural economics: insights from psychology, offers a view of human behaviour that is more subtle and complex than that found in conventional economic theory Asymmetric Information Information asymmetry: difference in access to relevant knowledge Hidden action: A worker knows more than his employer about how much effort he puts into his job Hidden characteristic: a seller of a used car knows more about its condition than its buyer Hidden Actions: Principles, Agents and Moral Hazard Moral hazard The tendency of a person who is imperfectly monitored to engage in dishonest or otherwise undesirable behaviour Agent A person who is performing an act for another person, called principle Principle A person for whom another person, called the agent is performing some act The phrase moral hazard refers to the risk, or hazard of inappropriate or otherwise immoral behaviour by the agent Moral hazard can lead to adverse selection -> market process may end up with bad outcomes because of asymmetric information Employers can respond to this problems in various ways: 1. Better monitoring Parents hiring nannies or au pairs have been known to plant hidden video cameras in their homes to record the individual´s behaviour 2. High wages According to efficiency wage theories some employers choose to pay their workers wage above the level that equilibriates supply and demand in the labour market. A worker who earns above-equilibrium wages is less likely to shirk 3. Delayed payment Firms can delay part of a worker´s compensation so if the worker is caught shirking and is fired he suffers a larger penalty Hidden Characteristics: Adverse selection and the lemons problem Adverse selection The tendency for the mix of unobserved attributes to become undesirable from the standpoint of an uninformed party Example: market for used cars When markets suffer from adverse selection, the invisible hand does not necessarily work its magic. In the used car market, owners of good cars may choose to keep them rather than sell them at the low price that sceptical buyers are willing to pay. In the labour market wages may be stuck above the level that balances supply and demand resulting in unemployment. In insurance markets buyers with low risk may choose to remain uninsured because the policies they are offered fail to reflect their true characteristics. Signalling to convey private information It also motivates some individual behaviour that otherwise might be hard to explain. Markets respond to the problems of asymmetric information in many ways. One of them is signalling which refers to actions taken by an informed party for the sole purpose of credibly revealing his private information What does it take for an action to be an effective signal? It must be costly, if a signal were free everyone would use it and it would convey no information The signal must be less costly, or more beneficial to the person with the higher quality product. Otherwise everyone would have the same incentive to use the signal and the signal would reveal nothing. Screening to induce information revelation Screening An action taken by an uninformed party to induce an informed party to reveal information Example: A person buying a used car may ask that it be checked by a car mechanic before sale. A seller who refuses this request reveals his private information that the car is a lemon Asymmetric information and public policy The study of asymmetric information gives us new reason to be wary of markets. When some people know more than others, the market may fail to put resources to their best use. People with high-quality used cars may have trouble selling them because buyers will be afraid of getting a lemon. Although asymmetric information may call for government action in some cases, three facts complicate the issue. 1. The private market can sometimes deal with information asymmetries on its own using a combination of signalling and screening 2. The government rarely has more information than the private parties 3. The government itself is an imperfect institution Political economy The field of political economy applies the methods of economics to study how governments work. The Condorcet Voting Paradox Condorcet paradox The failure of majority rule to produce transitive preferences for society Most advanced societies rely on democratic principles to set government policy. But democratic outcomes do not always obey this property. Pairwise voting might produce transitive preferences for society depending on the pattern of individual preferences but it cannot be counted on to do so. There are more than two options, setting the agenda can have a powerful impact on the outcome or a democratic election. The broad lesson is that majority voting by itself does not tell us what outcome a society really wants. Arrow´s impossibility theorem Arrow´s impossibility theorem A mathematical result showing that under certain assumed conditions there is no scheme for aggregating individual preferences into a valid set of social preferences Arrow´s impossibility theorem is a deep and disturbing result. It doesn´t say that we should abandon democracy as a form of government. But it does say that no matter what voting scheme society adopts for aggregating the preferences of its members, in some way it will be flawed as a mechanism for social choice. The median voter is king Median voter theorem A mathematical result showing that if voters are choosing a point along a line and each voter wants the point closest to his most preferred point then majority rule will pick the most preferred point of the median voter Voting is how most societies choose their leaders and public policies often by majority rule. The next step in studying government is to examine how governments run by majority rule work. That is, in a democratic society, who determines what policy is chosen? Majority rule will produce the outcome most preferred by the median voter. The median voter is the voter exactly in the middle of the distribution. One implication of the median voter theorem is that minority views are not given much weight. Behavioural economics The fields of economics and psychology usually proceed independently in part because they address a different range of questions. But recently a field called behavioural economics has emerged in which economists are making use of basic psychological insights. People aren´t always rational Studies of human decision making have tried to detect systematic mistakes that people make. 1. People are overconfident 2. People give too much weight to a small number of vivid observations 3. People are reluctant to change their minds 4. People have a natural tendency to look for examples which confirm their existing view or hypothesis. 5. People use rules of thumb-heuristics Anchoring: the tendency for people to start with something they are familiar with or know and make decisions or adjustments based on this anchor Availability: decisions are made based on an assessment of the risk of the likelihood of something happening Representativeness: people tend to make judgements by comparing how representative something is to an image or stereotype that they hold. 6. People care about fairness 7. People are inconsistent over time Some economists believe that the consumption-saving decision is an important instance where people exhibit this inconsistency over time. Spending provides a type of instant gratification. Saving requires a sacrifice in the present for a reward in a distant future