* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project
Download Malthus Revisited: Fertility Decision Making based on Quasi
Survey
Document related concepts
Transcript
Malthus Revisited: Fertility Decision Making based on Quasi-Linear Preferences∗ Jacob L. Weisdorf University of Copenhagen FIRST DRAFT September 7, 2006 Abstract The traditional interpretation of Malthus’ population theory makes it incompatible with the demographic transition and the massive expansion in income per capita which most industrialised countries have experienced. This study proposes a new interpretation of Malthus’ ‘preventive check’ hypothesis which makes his theory perfectly consistent with the development path of an industrialised economy. Putting together a simple analytical framework based on quasi-linear (‘zero income-effect’) preferences, this modified version of the Malthusian model predicts that a u-shaped relationship between income and fertility observed in historical England would have been caused by initial acceleration in agricultural productivity growth (i.e., an ‘agricultural revolution’), succeeded by acceleration in industrial productivity growth (i.e., an ‘industrial revolution’). 1 Introduction Malthus, in his Essay on the Principle of Population, identifies England as a ‘preventive check’ society, meaning a society in which fertility rates respond to changes in economic conditions (Malthus, 1798). That is, if income levels decrease and the price of provisions rises, then it becomes harder to rear a family; this, Malthus reasons, results in fewer people getting married and fewer early marriages taking place, leading ultimately to lower birth rates. In England, a u-shaped relationship between income and birth rates has been observed, whereby income growth leads initially to higher birth rates, and later to lower birth rates (see Figure 1). Ironically, the positive relationship between income and birth rates, i.e., the first half of the u-shaped relationship, for which Malthus is a spokesman, breaks down shortly after the Principle is ∗ I am greatful for the comments and suggestions made by the participants at the First Summer School of the Marie Curie Research Training Network ‘Unifying the European Experience: Historical Lessons of Pan-European Development,’ especially Tommy E. Murphy. 1 made public: the preventive check mechanism, seemingly, ceases to operate. Subsequently, increasing income levels are accompanied by a reduction in birth rates, an episode today recognised to as the demographic transition. [Figure 1 about here] Using a simple analytical framework, this study provides a theory of the u-shaped relationship between income and fertility, which, aside from a technicality, is perfectly consistent with Malthus’ preventive check hypothesis. More specifically, the current theory relies on a special type of preference function, namely, so-called quasi-linear (or zero income-effect) preferences. Such preferences imply, in line with Malthus’ theory, that peoples’ demand for children responds inversely to changes the price of provisions; however, unlike what Malthus imagines, the income-effect on the demand for children is absent. The use of a quasi-linear preference function brings out an interesting result. Namely, that the effect on fertility of income variation–which according to the current theory affects people’s birth rates through the price of provisions–turns out to be sector-dependent: agricultural sector income growth leads to higher birth rates, whereas industrial sector income growth leads to lower birth rates. According to the current work, therefore, the u-shaped relationship between income and birth rates outlined above is caused by initial acceleration in agricultural productivity growth (i.e., an ‘agricultural revolution’), succeeded by acceleration in industrial productivity growth (i.e., an ‘industrial revolution’). 1.1 Related Literature It is normally accepted that one of the most striking shortcomings of Malthus’ theory about the principle of population is its lack of power to forecast not only the massive expansion in income per capita but also an event such as the demographic transition, both of which nearly all industrialised country have experienced. Not surprisingly, therefore, nearly all studies that try to rationalise the ushaped relationship between income and birth rates attribute the effects of industrial development, especially that of technical progress, to the impetus behind the demographic transition. An incomplete list of papers that investigates the long-run relationship between income and fertility from a theoretical viewpoint includes Becker et al. (1990), Doepke (2004), Galor (2005), Galor and Weil (2000), Hansen and Prescott (2002), Jones (2001), Kalemli-Ozcan (2002), Lagerlöf (2003), Lucas (2002), O’Rourke et al. (2005), Strulik (2004), Tamura (2006) and Weisdorf (2004). The argument most commonly forwarded to motivate the demographic transition is that parents face a trade-off between child quantity and child quality. That is, given a fixed amount of resources, parents can choose between raising many children of a low quality (little education or human capital) and having only a few children of a high quality (much education or human capital). 2 Probably the most prominent example is Galor and Weil (2000). According to their theory, people divided up their time between income-generating activities, on the one hand, and child rearing, on the other. Each person requires a minimum consumption level in order to subsist. At relatively low income levels, therefore, people have to devote a relatively large fraction of their time to income-generating activities, to meet their subsistence requirements. As a result, productivity (i.e., technology) growth enables people to reduce time spent on income-generating activities and increase time allocated to the upbringing of children. At relatively low income levels, therefore, productivity growth increases a person’s income potential, and therefore its birth rate, which is how the authors explain the first half of the u-shaped relationship described above. Higher birth rates leads to a larger population. Population size constitutes a positive scale-effect on the growth rate of new technology. This creates a virtues circle whereby technology growth leads to higher birth rates, which leads to population increase, which accelerates technology growth. Eventually, however, technology growth becomes so significant that keeping up with technological progress demands schooling. This, according to the authors, is why parents ultimately trade off child quantity for child quality, and is what triggers the demographic transition, i.e., accounts for the second half of the u-shaped relationship outlined above. The current study differs from the existing literature from two perspectives. First, a new interpretation of Malthus’ preventive check hypothesis is proposed, which is perfectly consistent with the u-shaped relationship between income and fertility described above. That is, we modify the Malthusian model by removing the income-effect on the demand for children while holding on to the price-effect. Second, a trade-off between child quantity and child quality is not the engine behind the demographic transition in this paper. Instead, the fertility decline in this model appears as a result of changes in the price of provision. More specifically, the drop in birth rates results from the fact that industrial (i.e., nonfood) productivity growth drives up the price of foods relative to manufactured goods. The increase in the price of foods, which makes it more expensive to rear a family, shifts demand away from children, causing ultimately fertility decline. In the following, a simple analytic framework is provided, which explains in detail the paper’s theory. 2 The Model Consider a two-sector, closed economy. An agricultural sector produces foods; an industrial sector produces manufactured goods. As will become apparent below, the economy’s labour force is divided endogenously between the two sectors, so that some people are employed as farmers, others as manufacturers. 3 2.1 The Agricultural Sector Suppose that food production is subject to constant returns to land and labour.1 We assume that the mass of land, measured by X, is in fixed supply, and that the amount is set to unity. The total food output can thus be written as 1−α YA = ΩA Lα ≡ ΩA Lα AX A , α ∈ (0, 1) , X ≡ 1. (1) The variable ΩA measures the agricultural sector’s total factor productivity (subscript A for agriculture). The variable LA is agricultural labour input, i.e., the number of farmers in the economy. Unless explicitly stated, all variables in the model are considered in time-period t. For simplicity, there are no property rights over land, which means that the land rent is zero.2 A farmers, therefore, gets the average agricultural output, meaning that a farmer’s income is wA = YA ΩA = 1−α . LA LA (WA) To be used in the following, we define the net rate of growth of agricultural productivity between any two periods as γA ≡ 2.2 ΩA,t+1 − ΩA,t . ΩA,t (2) The Industrial Sector Suppose that manufactured goods production is subject to constant returns to labour. Total industrial output can thus be written as YM = ΩM LM , where the variable ΩM measures industrial labour productivity (subscript M for manufacturing). The variable LM is industrial labour input, i.e., the number of manufacturers in the economy. It follows that a manufacturer’s income is wM = YM = ΩM . LM (WM) To be used below, we define the net rate of growth of industrial productivity between any two periods as γM ≡ ΩM,t+1 − ΩM,t . ΩM,t (3) 1 Throughout, we suppress the use of capital in production, an assumption commonly used in the related literature (see, e.g., Galor and Weil, 2000). 2 In the related literature, this is also not an unusual assumption (e.g., Galor and Weil, 2000). 4 2.3 The Labour Market Equilibrium Condition The economy’s total labour force, measured by the variable L, consists of farmers and manufacturers. That is, L = LA + LM . In equilibrium, the relative price of the two types of goods, foods and manufactured goods, adjusts, so that workers receive the same income regardless of their choice of occupation. Let p denote the relative price of the two goods, or, more specifically, the number of units of manufactured goods that it takes to obtain a unit of food. In other words, p measures agricultural terms of trade. The labour market equilibrium condition (LEC) then requires that agricultural terms of trade adjust, so that p= 2.4 wM . wA (LEC) Population and Labour Force Dynamics Consider an overlapping-generations economy in which people live for a maximum of two periods: childhood and possibly adulthood. During childhood, there are no productive or income-generating activities. Such activities take place only during adulthood. The income that adults generate through productive activities, as will become apparent below, is divided endogenously between children and consumption goods. The development in the size of the adult population, which, by construction, equals the size of the labour force, is affected by birth rates and death rates. That is, at the end of each period, the total adult generation leaves the economy (i.e., die out). It is then replaced by a new generation of adults, consisting of the children who survive childhood. The number of children surviving childhood, in turn, is equal to the former period’s birth rate, denoted b, multiplied by the probability of outliving childhood. If we let d ∈ (0, 1) denote the risk of dying before adulthood, then 1 − d reflects the chances making it until adulthood. It is assumed that the death risk d cannot be affected by any actions taken by individuals. Throughout, therefore, the death risk is considered as exogenous. Individuals are, however, capable of affecting their birth rate, the size of which will be determined endogenously further below. With all individuals being identical, the number of children of a representative individual surviving until adulthood can thus be written as n = (1 − d) b. The evolution in the size of the labour force from one period to the next is therefore Lt+1 = nt Lt = (1 − d) bt Lt (4) 5 It follows that the net rate of growth of the labour force between any two periods can be written as Lt+1 − Lt γL ≡ = (1 − d) bt − 1. (5) Lt 2.5 The Food Market Equilibrium Condition Suppose that an individual, over the course of a lifetime, consumes a fixed quantity of foods–i.e., a certain amount of calories–measured by η. To simplify matters, a person’s lifetime food consumption is demanded during childhood and some of it then stored for adulthood.3 Without loss of generality, the food demanded by an individual can be set to unity, i.e., η ≡ 1. Therefore, the total amount of foodstuff demanded in the economy in any given period equals the birth rate multiplied by the size of the labour force. That is, the total food demand is bL. By setting total food demand equal to total food supply–the latter given by equation (1)–it follows that the food market equilibrium condition (FEC) is fulfilled when bL = ΩA Lα (FEC) A. 2.6 Preferences In line with the Beckerian approach (see Becker, 1991), we assume that children provide utility alongside other goods. Furthermore, as was explained in the introduction section above, we want to capture the idea proposed by Malthus (1798) that people’s demand for children respond to changes in the price of provisions. Suppose, in accordance with these views, that the utility function of a representative individual is of a quasi-linear type,4 whereby u (n, m) = ln n + m. It follows that people derive utility from the number of their children making it to adulthood, measured by n, and from the amount of manufactured goods consumed, measured by m. 2.7 Utility Maximisation Suppose that the costs of bringing up children consist of the costs of provisions, i.e., the costs of the foods that the children consume.5 Since the total amount of 3 If the individual does not survive until adulthood, then it is assumed that foods left over are either wasted or consumed by the child’s siblings. It would not affect the qualitative nature of the results, if, instead, the individual’s food demand where to be divided over two periods. However, such a construction would severely complicate matters. 4 The quasi-linear preference type is also known as zero income-effect preferences. 5 A construction by which children, in addition to foods, require a certain amount of parents’ time or a certain number of manufactured goods will not change the quantitative nature of the results. Such a construction, however, severely complicate the analysis. 6 foods demanded by an individual is set to unity (i.e., η ≡ 1), and since p is the price of a unit of food, it follows that the total costs of bringing up b children, measured in terms of manufactured goods, equals pb. Normalising the price of manufactured goods to one, it follows that the budget constraint of a representative individual can be written as w = pb + m, where, according to the labour market equilibrium condition equation (LEC), w ≡ pwA = wM . A representative individual’s utility maximisation problem is thus max u (n, m) = ln n + m b,m st. w = pb + m, The solution to the maximisation problem (SMP) implies that, in optimum (signified with an asterisk), the number of children demanded by an individual, i.e., its birth rate, is 1 b∗ = (SMP) p Note that the income-elasticity on the demand for children is zero while the price-elasticity is negative; that is, children are an ordinary good. It also follows from the solution to the maximisation problem that the number of manufactured goods demanded in optimum is m∗ = w − 1. 2.8 The Static General Equilibrium Condition The aim in the following is to sort out the factors that determine the general equilibrium birth rate as well as the number of manufactured goods consumed by each individual. Combining the solution to the optimisation problem (SMP), the labour market equilibrium condition (LEC) and the food market equilibrium condition (FEC) with the income of farmers (WA) and the income of manufacturers (WM), it follows that, in a static general equilibrium (SGE), the birth rate is bGE = ΩA α ΩM L1−α (b-SGE) while manufactured goods consumption level is mGE = ΩM − 1. (m-SGE) The static general equilibrium birth rate, i.e., equation (b-SGE), reveals the response of fertility to changes in economic conditions. It tells us that birth rates increase with agricultural productivity growth, but decrease with industrial productivity growth and with growth in the size of the labour force. 7 On the one hand, therefore, the result in equation (b-SGE) is well in line with the traditional interpretation of Malthus’ theory. That is, starting from a constant population, an upward shift in agricultural productivity raises agricultural sector income. Through its negative effect on the price of provisions, this leads to fertility increase, and thus to population growth. Due to diminishing returns to labour in agriculture, however, population growth causes agricultural income reduction. This brings down fertility, until population growth eventually peters out. On the other hand, the results of equation (b-SGE) provide an insight that contrasts with the traditional interpretation of Malthus’ theory. That is, starting from a constant population, an upward shift in industrial productivity raises industrial sector income. Though its positive effect on the price of provisions, this creates a decline in birth rates, thus causing a negative rate of growth of population. Via diminishing returns in agriculture, a smaller population fosters a higher agricultural income, which increases birth rates, until the population growth rate is back to zero. The key to understanding this result is that the effect on fertility of productivity change enters through the price of provisions. When, for example, industrial sector productivity grows, manufacturers receive a higher income. By the labour market equilibrium condition, an adjustment in the price of provisions, i.e., in agricultural terms of trade, takes place, so that people obtain the same income regardless of their choice of occupation. In the case of growing industrial productivity, for example, food goods need to become more expensive relative to manufactured goods in order for farmers to obtain the same income as manufacturer. As a result of higher food prices, and because of a negative price-elasticity on the demand for children, birth rates ultimately drop.6 Turning instead to the general equilibrium manufactured goods consumption level, i.e., equation (m-SGE), this shows that the number of manufactured goods produced and consumed depends solely on the level of industrial productivity ΩM . That is, because industrial output is not adversely affected by the population level, the economy’s standard of living is subject to limitless increase, restricted only by industrial productivity growth. 2.9 Dynamics and Stability Equation (b-SGE) gives us the static equilibrium birth rate in the economy in period t. To see how the static equilibrium birth rate evolves over time, we now characterize the equilibrium along a steady-state balanced growth path. Then, we explore the dynamics and the stability properties of this path. 6 If instead we had allowed for a postive income-effect on the demand, for example, if preferences had been of a Cobb-Douglas type instead which normally employed the related literature, i.e., if u (n, m) = β ln n + (1 − β) ln m, then the static general equilibrium birth rate would have been bGE = β α ΩA /L1−α . Using a Cobb-Douglas type preference function, therefore, the effect of changes in industrial sector productivity drops out. As a result, the Malthusian model becomes incapable of capturing the effect of development in the industrial sector. 8 A balanced growth path is a path along which all variables grow at constant geometric rates (possibly zero). We will look for a balanced growth path in which the birth rate b is constant. Along a balanced growth path the left-hand-side of equation (b-SGE) is constant by definition, so the right-hand-side must also be constant. Using the growth rates defined in equations (2) and (3), the equilibrium birth rate remains fixed over time when γ A = αγ M + (1 − α) γ L , where γ A and γ M are the rates of growth of productivity in the agricultural and industrial sector, respectively, and where γ L is the rate of growth of population. Inserting the growth rate of population as was defined in equation (5), it follows that, along a balanced growth path, the steady state birth rate is ¶ µ 1 1 st.st. = b 1+ (γ − αγ M ) . 1−d 1−α A As expected, a reduction in death rates in steady state leads to lower fertility. More importantly, abstracting from changes in the death risk, which we have taken to be exogenous, variation in the demand for children, along a balanced growth path, is caused by a shift in the ratio of agricultural productivity growth to industrial productivity growth. If we define this ratio as γ (6) γ≡ A, γM then it follows that an increase in γ will increase fertility whereas a reduction in γ has the opposite effect. Accordingly, the u-shaped relationship between income and birth rates described above would be caused by initial acceleration in agricultural productivity growth, i.e., an increase in γ, succeeded by acceleration in industrial productivity growth, i.e., a reduction in γ. In other words, the current theory predicts that an ‘agricultural revolution’ where to be succeeded by an ‘industrial revolution,’ in order to create the u-shaped relationship illustrated in Figure 1. Note that the steady state birth rate is not necessarily equal to one. That is, the steady state population level is not necessarily constant. Rather, the size of the population will increase or decrease along a balanced growth path, depending on the relative rate of growth of productivity in the agricultural and the industrial sector. Of course, in the absence of any productivity growth, as Malthus predicted, the steady state population level would be constant. Turning next to the steady state manufactured goods consumption level, the right-hand-side of equation (m-SGE) is constant only when the level of industrial productivity remains fixed. This implies that the growth rate of manufactured goods consumption, in steady state, is γm = γM where γ M is the rate of growth of productivity in the industrial sector, and where γ m is defined as the net rate of growth of manufactured goods consumption–or, in this model, economic growth–between any two periods. 9 In the traditional interpretation of the Malthusian population hypothesis, productivity growth, via higher income, will lead to population increase. And population increase ultimately “eats up” all the extra income that agricultural productivity growth brings about. Clearly, this feature is well captured by the current model, at least as long as the increase in productivity stems from the agricultural sector. Industrial productivity growth, however, have a different effect. Not only does it cause lower birth rates, and, therefore, slower population growth. It also leads to a higher industrial income, which is not “eaten up” by a larger population because it does not boost up popolation growth. Finally, since industrial productivity growth brings about a drop in fertility, this will limit the demand for agricultural labour. All other things being equal, this means that workers, as a result of industrial productivity growth alone, can be transferred from agricultural to industry, another important feature of the process of industrialisation. 3 Conclusion In England, a u-shaped relationship between income and birth rates has been observed, whereby income growth leads first to higher birth rates, and then later to lower birth rates. The latter part of the u-shape, often referred to as the demographic transition, is normally taken to go against Malthus’ theory about the principle of population. Using a simple analytical framework, this study provides a new interpretation of the Malthus’ population hypothesis, which is perfectly consistent with the demographic transition and with a steady growth in income per capita. It is demonstrated that if people have so-called quasi-linear preferences, i.e., if the demand for children varies negatively with the price of foods but is unaffected by changes the individual’s income, then the effect of productivity growth on fertility ends up being sector-dependent: agricultural productivity growth increases fertility whereas industrial productivity growth reduces fertility. The theory predicts that the u-shaped relationship between income and birth rates observed in England would result from an ‘agricultural revolution,’ which is succeeded an ‘industrial revolution.’ In principle, this modified version of Malthus population model easily put to the test. It can be done in at least two ways. Either by testing if birth rates respond inversely to changes in agricultural terms of trade. Or by testing if the γ ratio from equation (6) moves in the direction dictated by the model. An impediment to testing the model’s results, however, arises from the fact that this is a model of a closed economy. The fact that, during the process of industrialisation most countries become open to foreign trade and exchange, breaks down the labour market equilibrium condition. 10 References [1] Becker, Gary S. (1991), A Treatise on the Family, expanded ed., Cambridge MA, Harvard University Press. [2] Becker, Gary S., Murphy, Kevin M., and Tamura, Robert, (1990) “Human Capital, Fertility, and Economic Growth,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98: 12 - 37. [3] Doepke, Matthias (2004), “Accounting for Fertility Decline during the Transition to Growth,” Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 9 (Semptember): 347-383. [4] Galor, Oded (2005), “From Stagnation to Growth: Unified Growth Theory”, in Handbook of Economic Growth, 2005: 171-293. [5] Galor, Oded and David Weil (2000), “Population, Technology and Growth: From Malthusian Stagnation to the Demographic Transition and Beyond,” American Economic Review, Vol. 90: 806-828. [6] Hansen, Gary D. and Edward C. Prescott (2002), “Malthus to Solow,” American Economic Review, Vol. 92: 1205-17. [7] Jones, Charles I. (2001), “Was the Industrial Revolution Inevitable? Economic Growth over the Very Long Run,” Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1: No. 2. [8] Kalemli-Ozcan, Sebnem (2002), “Does Mortality Decline Promote Economic Growth?” Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 7: 411-439. [9] Lagerlöf, Nils-Petter (2003) “From Malthus to Modern Growth: Can Epidemics Explain the Three Regimes,” International Economic Review, Vol. 44: 755-777. [10] Lucus, Robert E. (2002), The Industrial Revolution: Past and Future, Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [11] Malthus, Thomas (1798), An Essay on the Principle of Population, London, printed for J. Johnson. [12] O’Rourke, Kevin H., Ahmed S. Rahman and Alan M. Taylor (2005), "Trade, Knowledge and the Industrial Revolution,” mimeo, September 2005. [13] Strulik, Holger (2004), “Economic Growth and Stagnation with Endogenous Health and Fertility,” Journal of Population Economics, Vol. 17: 433453. [14] Tamura, Robert (2006), “Human capital and economic development”, Journal of Development Economics, Vol. (79): 26-72. 11 [15] Weisdorf, Jacob (2004), “From Stagnation to Growth: Revisiting Three Historical Regimes,” Journal of Population Economics, Vol. 17: 445-474. Figure 1 12