Download ECON 500 –Microeconomic Analysis and Policy Producer Theory

Document related concepts

Comparative advantage wikipedia , lookup

Fei–Ranis model of economic growth wikipedia , lookup

Marginalism wikipedia , lookup

Externality wikipedia , lookup

Supply and demand wikipedia , lookup

Economic equilibrium wikipedia , lookup

Perfect competition wikipedia , lookup

Transcript
ECON 500
ECON 500 –Microeconomic Analysis and Policy
Producer Theory
ECON 500
Producer Theory
A theory of how firms coordinate the transformation of inputs into outputs
with a goal of maximizing profits in the meantime.
Part I
Part II
Part III
Production Functions
Cost Functions
Profit Maximization
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
The principal activity of any firm is to turn inputs into outputs.
In the theory of producer behavior the relationship between inputs and
outputs is formalized by a production function of the form
where q
rticular good during a period, k
represents the machine (that is, capital) usage during the period, l
represents hours of labor input, m represents
represents the possibility of other variables affecting the production
process.
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Most of our analysis will involve two inputs k and l, capital and labor
respectively
Where q is the maximum amount of a good that can be produced by using
alternative combinations of k and l.
Since it is possible to produce the same amount of a good using different
combinations of capital and labor, it is important to understand their
respective contributions to the production process at various levels of
utilization.
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Marginal Physical Product:
The marginal physical product of an input is the additional output that can
be produced by employing one more unit of that input while holding all
other inputs constant.
Where the use partial derivatives reflect the fact that all other input usage
is held constant while the input of interest is being varied.
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Diminishing Marginal Productivity:
We assume that the marginal physical product of an input depends on how
much of that input is used. We also postulate that inputs cannot be added
indefinitely to a production process without eventually exhibiting some
deterioration in its productivity. Mathematically:
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Diminishing Marginal Productivity
Changes in the marginal productivity of labor depend not only on how
labor input is growing, but also on changes in capital.
Therefore, we m
In most cases, this cross partial derivative is positive indicating that the
marginal productivity of an input increasing in the other input.
Diminishing marginal productivity of a single input can be offset by the
increases in other inputs. The gloomy prediction of Malthus that led
economics to be called a dismal science is misplaced.
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Average Physical Productivity
APl is easily measured and is of much empirical significance. The
relationship between average and marginal physical productivity is also of
significance.
When APl is at its maximum, it equals MPl
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Isoquants
An isoquant shows those combinations of k and l that can produce a given
level of output. Mathematically, an isoquant records the set of k and l that
satisfies:
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution
The marginal rate of technical substitution (RTS) shows the rate at which
labor can be substituted for capital while holding output constant along an
isoquant.
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
RTS and Marginal Productivities
The total differential of the production function is
Along and isoquant, we know that dq=0, therefore
Hence
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Diminishing RTS
Isoquants naturally have a negative slope but they are also as convex
curves. This means along any one of the isoquants, the RTS is diminishing
However, it is not possible to derive a diminishing RTS from the
assumption of diminishing marginal productivity alone since Marginal
Physical Product depends on the level of both inputs and cross
productivity effects are present.
To show that isoquants are convex, we would like to show that
dRTS/dl < 0. Since RTS = fl/fk, we have
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Diminishing RTS
Because fl and fk are functions of both k and l, we must be careful in
taking the derivative of this expression
Using the fact that dk/dl = - fl/fk along an isoquant and
kl = flk), we have
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Diminishing RTS
Because we have assumed fk > 0, the denominator of this function is
positive. Hence the whole fraction will be negative if the numerator is
negative. Because fll and fkk are both assumed to be negative, the
numerator definitely will be negative if fkl is positive.
When we assume a diminishing RTS we are assuming that marginal
productivities
possible
negative cross-productivity effects.
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Returns to Scale
If the production function is given by q = f (k,l) and if all inputs are
multiplied by the same positive constant t (where t > 1), then we classify
the returns to scale of the production function by
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Constant Returns to Scale
CRS production functions are homogenous of degree 1:
Derivatives of a CRS function are homogenous of degree 0:
And CRS functions are homothetic
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
Elasticity of Substitution
If the RTS does not change for changes in k/l, we say that substitution is
easy because the ratio of the marginal productivities of the two inputs does
not change as the input mix changes.
Alternatively, if the RTS changes rapidly for small changes in k/l, we
would say that substitution is difficult because minor variations in the
relative
productivities.
A scale-free measure of this responsiveness is
ECON 500
Part I. Production Functions
ECON 500
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
Accounting Costs vs. Economics Costs
Accountants emphasize out-of-pocket expenses, historical costs,
depreciation, and other bookkeeping entries.
Economists on the other hand define cost by the size of the payment
necessary to keep the resource in its present employment, or alternatively,
by the remuneration that input would earn in its next best use.
Labor costs = hourly wage = w
Capital costs = rental rate of capital = v
Cost of entrepreneurial services = forgone earnings
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
Cost Minimization
The firm seeks to minimize total costs given q = f (k, l) = q0.
First order conditions for this constrained minimum are
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
In order to minimize costs, the firm should choose inputs such that the rate
at which k can be traded for l in production to the rate at which they can
be traded in the marketplace.
Alternatively, the firm should chose inputs such that the marginal
productivity per dollar spent should be the same for all inputs.
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
Total Cost Function
Average Cost Function
Marginal Cost Function
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
CRS Production Function and its Costs
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
Cubic Cost Function
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
Properties of Cost Functions
Non-decreasing in v, w, and q
Homogenous of degree 1 in input prices
Concave in input prices
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
l
Suppose that the price of labor (w) were to increase slightly. Costs would
rise by approximately the amount of labor l that the firm was currently
hiring.
constant, so an
increase in the wage increases costs in direct proportion to the amount of
labor used.
Because the true cost function is tangent to the pseudo-function at the
current wage, its slope (that is, its partial derivative) also will show the
current amount of labor input demanded.
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
Lemma
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
Short run vs. Long run
In the short run, the firm is able to alter only its labor input while capital
input is fixed at some level k1.
With this formulation, payments to capital attain a fixed cost nature in the
short run and do not vary with the amount produced. Short run cost
function becomes:
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
Short run vs. Long run
In the short run, to change output, firms are forced to use input
combinations that are non-optimal.
Unavailability of input substitution prevents the firm from finding the
input mix where RTS equals the ratio of input prices.
Hence, in the short run, costs are not necessarily minimized.
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
Long-run total costs are always less than short-run total costs, except at
that output level for which the assumed fixed capital input is at the
appropriate level to ensure long-run cost minimization.
Therefore, long-run total cost curves constitute
their
respective short-run curves. A family of short run cost curves can be
obtained by varying the capital level in
Long run cost curve can be recovered by combining the above SC with
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
ECON 500
Part II. Cost Functions
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
A profit-maximizing firm chooses both its inputs and its outputs with the
sole goal of achieving maximum economic profits. That is, the firm seeks
to make the difference between its total revenues and its total economic
costs as large as possible.
This
-making
unit and sweeps away all the complicated behavioral issues about the
relationships (contractual or implicit) among input providers.
The profit maximizing assumption has a long history in economic
literature. It is plausible because firm owners may indeed seek to make
their asset as valuable as possible and because competitive markets may
punish firms that do not maximize profits. The assumption also yields
interesting theoretical
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Marginalism and Profit Maximization
Firms perform the conceptual experiment of adjusting those variables that
can be controlled until it is impossible to increase profits further. This
involves, say, looking at the
from producing one more unit of output. As long as this incremental profit
is positive, the extra output will be produced. When the incremental profit
of an activity becomes zero, the firm has pushed output far enough, and it
would not be profitable to go further.
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Firms choose the level of output that maximizes
The first order condition for a maximum is
In order to maximize economic profits, the firm should choose that output
for which marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
MR=MC condition is only a necessary condition for maximum profits.
The second order condition that
decreasing at the optimal level of output must also hold for sufficiency.
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Marginal Revenue
If the firm can sell all it wishes without having any effect on market price,
the market price will indeed be the extra revenue obtained from selling
one more unit. Total revenue will be linear in output, marginal and
average revenue will be equal to price.
However, a firm may not always be able to sell all it wants at the
prevailing market price. If it faces a downward-sloping demand curve for
its product, the revenue obtained from selling one more unit will be less
than the price of that unit because, in order to get consumers to take the
extra unit, the price of all other units must be lowered. Marginal revenue
be below price for any quantity q>1.
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Marginal Revenue
If price does not change as quantity increases dp/dq = 0, marginal revenue
will be equal to price. In this case we say that the firm is a price taker
because its output decisions do not influence the price it receives.
On the other hand, if price falls as quantity increases dp/dq < 0, marginal
revenue will be less than price.
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Marginal Revenue and Elasticity
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Price Marginal Cost Markup
Using the MR elasticity relationship and equating MR to MC
The more elastic demand becomes, the lower the markup over MC
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Supply Decision of a Price Taking Firm
If a firm is sufficiently small such that its output choice has no market on
the market price, the marginal revenue becomes equal to the market price.
The profit maximizing level of output q* can be found by
P = MR = MC
As long as at this level of output average variable cost is below the market
price, the firm would continue to operate in the short run.
The short run supply curve for a price taking firm is the positively sloped
-run marginal cost above the point of minimum
average variable cost.
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Cobb Douglas Example
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
I - The supply curve is positively sloped - increases in P cause the firm to
produce more because it is willing to incur a higher marginal cost
II - The supply curve is shifted to the left by increases in the wage rate,
III - The supply curve is shifted outward by increases in capital input
IV - The rental rate of capital, v, is irrelevant to short-run supply decisions
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Profit Functions
We can represent
depending only on the
prices that the firm faces by a profit function of the form
With the properties:
I
Homogenous of degree 0
II Non-increasing in input prices
III Non-decreasing in output price
IV Convex in output prices
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Cobb Douglas Example
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Input Demand
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Comparative Statics for Input Demand
Single Input
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
Comparative Statics for Input Demand
Two Inputs
ECON 500
Part III. Profit Maximization
ECON 500
Demand and Marginal Revenue for a Competitive Firm
DEMAND CURVE FACED BY A COMPETITIVE FIRM
A competitive firm supplies only a small portion of the total output of all the firms in an
industry. Therefore, the firm takes the market price of the product as given, choosing
its output on the assumption that the price will be unaffected by the output choice.
In (a) the demand curve facing the firm is perfectly elastic,
even though the market demand curve in (b) is downward sloping.
Because each firm in a competitive industry sells only a small fraction
of the entire industry output, how much output the firm decides to sell
will have no effect on the market price of the product.
Because it is a price taker, the demand curve d facing an individual competitive
firm is given by a horizontal line.
The demand curve d facing an individual firm in a competitive market is
both its average revenue curve and its marginal revenue curve. Along this
demand curve, marginal revenue, average revenue, and price are all equal.
Profit Maximization by a Competitive Firm
A perfectly competitive firm should choose its output so that marginal cost
equals price:
MC(q) = MR = P
Choosing Output in the Short Run
Short-Run Profit Maximization by a Competitive Firm
A COMPETITIVE FIRM
MAKING A POSITIVE
PROFIT
In the short run, the
competitive firm maximizes
its profit by choosing an
output q* at which its
marginal cost MC is equal
to the price P (or marginal
revenue MR) of its product.
The profit of the firm is
measured by the rectangle
ABCD.
Any change in output,
whether lower at q1 or
higher at q2, will lead to
lower profit.
Output Rule: If a firm is producing any
output, it should produce at the level at which
marginal revenue equals marginal cost.
When Should the Firm Shut Down?
A COMPETITIVE FIRM
INCURRING LOSSES
A competitive firm should
shut down if price is below
AVC.
The firm may produce in
the short run if price is
greater than average
variable cost.
-run
Supply Curve
the portion of the marginal cost curve for which
marginal cost is greater than average variable cost.
THE SHORT-RUN SUPPLY
CURVE FOR A COMPETITIVE
FIRM
In the short run, the firm
chooses its output so that
marginal cost MC is equal to
price as long as the firm
covers its average variable
cost.
The short-run supply curve is
given by the crosshatched
portion of the marginal cost
curve.
THE RESPONSE OF A FIRM
TO A CHANGE IN INPUT
PRICE
When the marginal cost of
production for a firm
increases (from MC1 to MC2),
the level of output that
maximizes profit falls (from q1
to q2).
The Short-Run Market Supply Curve
INDUSTRY SUPPLY IN THE
SHORT RUN
The short-run industry
supply curve is the
summation of the supply
curves of the individual
firms.
Because the third firm has
a lower average variable
cost curve than the first two
firms, the market supply
curve S begins at price P1
and follows the marginal
cost curve of the third firm
MC3 until price equals P2,
when there is a kink.
For P2 and all prices above
it, the industry quantity
supplied is the sum of the
quantities supplied by each
of the three firms.
Elasticity of Market Supply
Es = ( Q/Q)/( P/P)
Producer Surplus in the Short Run
producer surplus Sum over all units produced by a firm of
differences between the market price of a good and the marginal cost of
production.
PRODUCER SURPLUS FOR
A FIRM
The producer surplus for a
firm is measured by the
yellow area below the market
price and above the marginal
cost curve, between outputs 0
and q*, the profit-maximizing
output.
Alternatively, it is equal to
rectangle ABCD because the
sum of all marginal costs up
to q* is equal to the variable
costs of producing q*.
PRODUCER SURPLUS VERSUS PROFIT
Producer surplus = PS =
Profit =
PRODUCER SURPLUS FOR
A MARKET
The producer surplus for a
market is the area below the
market price and above the
market supply curve, between
0 and output Q*.
=R
VC
Choosing Output in the Long Run
Long-Run Profit Maximization
OUTPUT CHOICE IN THE
LONG RUN
The firm maximizes its profit
by choosing the output at
which price equals long-run
marginal cost LMC.
In the diagram, the firm
increases its profit from
ABCD to EFGD by
increasing its output in the
long run.
The long-run output of a profit-maximizing competitive firm is the point at which
long-run marginal cost equals the price.
Long-Run Competitive Equilibrium
ACCOUNTING PROFIT AND ECONOMIC PROFIT
Economic profit takes into account opportunity costs. One such opportunity cost
is
elsewhere. Accounting
profit equals revenues R minus labor cost wL, which is positive. Economic profit
, however, equals revenues R minus labor cost wL minus the capital cost, Rk.
ZERO ECONOMIC PROFIT
zero economic profit A firm is earning a normal return on its investment
i.e., it is doing as well as it could by investing its money elsewhere.
ENTRY AND EXIT
In a market with entry and exit, a firm enters when it can earn a positive longrun profit and exits when it faces the prospect of a long-run loss.
long-run competitive equilibrium All firms in an industry are
maximizing profit, no firm has an incentive to enter or exit, and price is
such that quantity supplied equals quantity demanded.
When a firm earns zero economic profit, it has no incentive to exit the industry.
Likewise, other firms have no special incentive to enter.
A long-run competitive equilibrium occurs when three conditions hold:
1. All firms in the industry are maximizing profit.
2. No firm has an incentive either to enter or exit the industry because all
firms are earning zero economic profit.
3. The price of the product is such that the quantity supplied by the
industry is equal to the quantity demanded by consumers.
LONG-RUN COMPETITIVE
EQUILIBRIUM
Initially the long-run equilibrium
price of a product is $40 per unit,
shown in (b) as the intersection of
demand curve D and supply curve
S1.
In (a) we see that firms earn
positive profits because long-run
average cost reaches a minimum
of $30 (at q2).
Positive profit encourages entry of
new firms and causes a shift to
the right in the supply curve to S2,
as shown in (b).
The long-run equilibrium occurs at
a price of $30, as shown in (a),
where each firm earns zero profit
and there is no incentive to enter
or exit the industry.
FIRMS HAVING IDENTICAL COSTS
To see why all the conditions for long-run equilibrium must hold,
assume that all firms have identical costs.
Now consider what happens if too many firms enter the industry in
response to an opportunity for profit. The industry supply curve will shift
further to the right, and price will fall.
Only when there is no incentive to exit or enter can a market be in longrun equilibrium.
FIRMS HAVING DIFFERENT COSTS
Now suppose that all firms in the industry do not have identical cost curves.
Perhaps one firm has a patent that lets it produce at a lower average cost than
all the others. In that case, it is consistent with long-run equilibrium for that firm
to earn a greater accounting profit and to enjoy a higher producer surplus than
other firms.
If the patent is profitable, other firms in the industry will pay to use it. The
increased value of the patent thus represents an opportunity cost to the firm
that holds it. It could sell the rights to the patent rather than use it. If all firms
are equally efficient otherwise, the economic profit of the firm falls to zero.
THE OPPORTUNITY COST OF LAND
There are other instances in which firms earning positive accounting profit may
be earning zero economic profit.
Suppose, for example, that a clothing store happens to be located near a large
shopping center. The additional flow of customers can substantially increase
historical cost. When the opportunity cost of land is included, the profitability of
the clothing store is no higher than that of its competitors.
Economic Rent
economic rent Amount that firms are willing to pay for an input less the
minimum amount necessary to obtain it. A payment for the services of an
economic resource which is not necessary as an incentive for its production
In competitive markets, in both the short and the long run, economic rent is
often positive even though profit is zero.
Producer Surplus in the Long Run
In the long run, in a competitive market, the producer surplus that a firm earns
on the output that it sells consists of the economic rent that it enjoys from all its
scarce inputs.
FIRMS EARN ZERO PROFIT IN LONG-RUN EQUILIBRIUM
In long-run equilibrium, all firms earn zero economic profit.
In (a), a baseball team in a moderate-sized city sells enough tickets so that price ($7) is
equal to marginal and average cost.
In (b), the demand is greater, so a $10 price can be charged. The team increases sales
to the point at which the average cost of production plus the average economic rent is
equal to the ticket price.
When the opportunity cost associated with owning the franchise is taken into account,
the team earns zero economic profit.
Long-Run Supply Curve
Constant-Cost Industry
constant-cost industry
Industry whose long-run supply curve is horizontal.
LONG-RUN SUPPLY IN A
CONSTANT COST INDUSTRY
In (b), the long-run supply
curve in a constant-cost
industry is a horizontal line SL.
When demand increases,
initially causing a price rise,
the firm initially increases its
output from q1 to q2, as shown
in (a).
But the entry of new firms
causes a shift to the right in
industry supply.
Because input prices are
unaffected by the increased
output of the industry, entry
occurs until the original price is
obtained (at point B in (b)).
The long-run supply curve for a constant-cost industry is,
therefore, a horizontal line at a price that is equal to the
long-run minimum average cost of production.
Long-Run Supply Curve
Increasing-Cost Industry
increasing-cost industry Industry whose long-run supply curve is upward sloping.
LONG-RUN SUPPLY IN AN
INCREASING COST INDUSTRY
In (b), the long-run supply
curve in an increasing-cost
industry is an upward-sloping
curve SL.
When demand increases,
initially causing a price rise,
the firms increase their output
from q1 to q2 in (a).
In that case, the entry of new
firms causes a shift to the right
in supply from S1 to S2.
Because input prices increase
as a result, the new long-run
equilibrium occurs at a higher
price than the initial
equilibrium.
In an increasing-cost industry, the long-run
industry supply curve is upward sloping.
The Effects of a Tax
EFFECT OF AN OUTPUT TAX
OUTPUT
marginal cost curve by the
amount of the tax.
The firm will reduce its output
to the point at which the
marginal cost plus the tax is
equal to the price of the
product.
EFFECT OF AN OUTPUT TAX
ON INDUSTRY OUTPUT
An output tax placed on all
firms in a competitive market
shifts the supply curve for the
industry upward by the
amount of the tax.
This shift raises the market
price of the product and
lowers the total output of the
industry.