Download Summary - Harvard Kennedy School

Survey
yes no Was this document useful for you?
   Thank you for your participation!

* Your assessment is very important for improving the workof artificial intelligence, which forms the content of this project

Document related concepts
no text concepts found
Transcript
“The Natural Resource Curse: A Survey”
May 24, 2010
Summary
Jeffrey Frankel
Harpel Professor of Capital Formation and Growth, Harvard University
The paper is a revised version of NBER Working Paper No 15836 and Harvard Kennedy School RWP 10-003. It was
written for Export Perils, edited by Brenda Shaffer (forthcoming, University of Pennsylvania Press).
It is striking how often countries with oil or other natural resource wealth have
failed to grow more rapidly than those without. This is the phenomenon known as the
Natural Resource Curse. The principle is not confined to individual anecdotes or case
studies, but has been borne out in some econometric tests of the determinants of
economic performance across a comprehensive sample of countries. Already-classic
contributors to the rapidly growing literature include Auty (1993, 2001) and Sachs and
Warner (1995, 2001).
This paper considers seven aspects of commodity wealth, each of interest in its
own right, but each also a channel that some have suggested could lead to sub-standard
economic performance. They are:
1. Allegedly adverse long-term trends in world commodity prices (the Prebisch-Singer
hypothesis, as opposed to Malthus, Hotelling, and the “peak oil hypothesis”).
2. Volatility in world commodity prices, resulting from low short-run elasticities
3. Permanent crowding out of manufacturing, where developmental spillover effects are
allegedly concentrated (as in the Matsuyama model, 1992)
4. Poor institutions
5. Unsustainably rapid depletion, with the market failure originating in unenforceable
property rights over non-renewable resources (“open access”), particularly in anarchic
frontier conditions, and sometimes exacerbated by international trade.
6. Civil war,
7. And cyclical Dutch Disease.
The literature on channel 4, poor institutions, begins with Engerman and Sokoloff,
(1997, 2000). Lands endowed with extractive industries (“point source” sectors: oil,
minerals, and plantation crops) historically developed institutions of slavery, inequality,
dictatorship, and state control. Meanwhile, other countries (in those climates originally
suited to fishing and small farms) developed institutions based on individualism,
democracy, egalitarianism, and capitalism. When the industrial revolution came along,
the latter areas were well-suited to make the most of it. Those that had specialized in
extractive industries were not, because society had come to depend on class structure and
authoritarianism, rather than on individual incentive and decentralized decision-making.
The theory is thought to fit Middle Eastern oil exporters especially well.
The literature on channel 7 takes us into the macroeconomics of the business cycle.
The Dutch Disease phenomenon arises when a strong, but perhaps temporary, upward
swing in the world price of the export commodity causes some or all of the following side
effects:
 a large real appreciation in the currency (taking the form of nominal currency
appreciation if the country has a floating exchange rate or the form of money inflows
and inflation if the country has a fixed exchange rate);
 an increase in spending (especially by the government, which increases spending in
response to the increased availability of tax receipts or royalties);
 an increase in the price of nontraded goods (goods and services such as housing that
are not internationally traded), relative to traded goods (manufactures and other
internationally traded goods other than the export commodity),
 a resultant shift of labor and land out of non-export-commodity traded goods (pulled
by the more attractive returns in the export commodity and in non-traded goods and
services), and
 a current account deficit (thereby incurring international debt that may be difficult to
service when the commodity boom ends1).
What makes the Dutch Disease a “disease?” One interpretation, particularly relevant
if the complete cycle is not adequately foreseen, is that the process is all painfully
reversed when the world price of the export commodity goes back down. A second
interpretation is that, even if the perceived longevity of the increase in world price turns
out to be accurate, the crowding out of non-commodity exports is undesirable, perhaps
because the manufacturing sector has greater externalities for long-run growth (“deindustrialization”). But the latter view is just another name for the Natural Resource
Curse; it has nothing to do with cyclical fluctuations per se. In a real trade model, the
reallocation of resources across tradable sectors, e.g., from manufactures to oil, may be
inevitable, regardless of macroeconomics. But the movement into non-traded goods is
macroeconomic in origin.
Recently, skeptics have questioned the Natural Resource Curse. They point to
examples of commodity-exporting countries that have done well, persuasively arguing
that natural resource endowments do not necessarily doom a country to slow growth. But
they further question the negative relationship even as a statistical generalization. They
argue that “resource dependence” and commodity booms are not exogenous. The
1
Manzano and Rigobon (2008) show that the negative Sachs-Warner effect of resource
dependence on growth rates during 1970-1990 was mediated through international debt
incurred when commodity prices were high. Arezki and Brückner (2010a) find that
commodity price booms lead to increased government spending, external debt and default
risk in autocracies, and but do not have those effects in democracies. Arezki and
Brückner (2010b) find that the dichotomy extends also to the effects on sovereign bond
spreads paid by autocratic versus democratic commodity producers.
2
reverse causality between industrialization and commodity exports can have either a
negative sign (those countries that fail at manufacturing have a comparative advantage at
commodity exports, by default) or a positive sign (good institutions and technological
progress are just as useful for developing natural resources as they are for the other
sectors of the economy).
It is best to view commodity abundance as a double-edged sword, with both benefits
and dangers. Clearly the relevant policy question for a country with natural resources is
how to make the best of them. The paper concludes with a consideration of ideas for
institutions that could help a country that is endowed with, for example, oil overcome the
pitfalls of the Curse and achieve good economic performance.
The most promising ideas include:
 indexation of oil or mineral contracts to world prices of the commodity
 hedging of export proceeds on forward markets
 denomination of debt in terms of the world price of the export commodity
 Chile-style fiscal rules, which prescribe a structural budget surplus and use
independent panels of experts to determine what long-run price of the export
commodity should be assumed in forecasting the structural budget.
 An inflation target for the central bank that emphasizes product prices, rather than the
CPI on which the fashionable monetary regime of Inflation Targeting is usually based
 transparent commodity funds,
 and lump-sum per capita distribution of oil revenues.
3