Reconciling the invisible hand and innovation
... promote the public interest. This concept –that the rough-and -tumble of market competition– is a potent force for raising output and living standards– is one of the most profound and powerful ideas in history. (Samuelson and Nordhaus 1998, 265) Clearly, the way Samuelson and Nordhaus paraphrase Sm ...
... promote the public interest. This concept –that the rough-and -tumble of market competition– is a potent force for raising output and living standards– is one of the most profound and powerful ideas in history. (Samuelson and Nordhaus 1998, 265) Clearly, the way Samuelson and Nordhaus paraphrase Sm ...
consumer surplus and prices in perfect competition and
... PPC = {(2)*(PM) – a}; (where ‘a’ is the y-intercept of the demand curve) The above results can be shown (and generalized) with the help of an illustration. Let us consider a linear demand curve, of the form, Q = (i.e., P = a – bQ), (where ‘a’ and ‘b’ are the intercept and slope parameters respective ...
... PPC = {(2)*(PM) – a}; (where ‘a’ is the y-intercept of the demand curve) The above results can be shown (and generalized) with the help of an illustration. Let us consider a linear demand curve, of the form, Q = (i.e., P = a – bQ), (where ‘a’ and ‘b’ are the intercept and slope parameters respective ...
Evolutionary and competence- based theories
... number of causal mechanisms are simultaneously at work. As long as they do not involve internal inconsistencies, plural rather than singular explanations may, in principle, be possible and plausible. An example of a plural position is the work of Richard Langlois (Langlois, 1992; Langlois and Robert ...
... number of causal mechanisms are simultaneously at work. As long as they do not involve internal inconsistencies, plural rather than singular explanations may, in principle, be possible and plausible. An example of a plural position is the work of Richard Langlois (Langlois, 1992; Langlois and Robert ...
Monetary Plurality in Economic Theory
... equilibrium, grants nonetheless that though in the long term money is neutral, in the short term it does play an active part. The second line of thinking revolves round the relationship between economic theories and the problem of the unicity or plurality of money as a norm to be established. This r ...
... equilibrium, grants nonetheless that though in the long term money is neutral, in the short term it does play an active part. The second line of thinking revolves round the relationship between economic theories and the problem of the unicity or plurality of money as a norm to be established. This r ...
History of macroeconomic thought
Macroeconomic theory has its origins in the study of business cycles and monetary theory. In general, early theorists believed monetary factors could not have an impact on real factors such as real output. John Maynard Keynes attacked some of these ""classical"" theories and produced a general theory that described the whole economy in terms of aggregates rather than individual, microeconomic parts. Attempting to explain unemployment and recessions, he noticed the tendency for people and businesses to hoard cash and avoid investment during a recession. He argued that this invalidated the assumptions of classical economists who thought that markets always clear, leaving no surplus of goods and no willing labor left idle. The word macroeconomics was first used by Ragnar FrischThe generation of economists that followed Keynes synthesized his theory with neoclassical microeconomics to form the neoclassical synthesis. Although Keynesian theory originally omitted an explanation of price levels and inflation, later Keynesians adopted the Phillips curve to model price-level changes. Some Keynesians opposed the synthesis method of combining Keynes's theory with an equilibrium system and advocated disequilibrium models instead. Monetarists, led by Milton Friedman, adopted some Keynesian ideas, such as the importance of the demand for money, but argued that Keynesians ignored the role of money supply in inflation. Robert Lucas and other new classical macroeconomists criticized Keynesian models that did not work under rational expectations. Lucas also argued that Keynesian empirical models would not be as stable as models based on microeconomic foundations.The new classical school culminated in real business cycle theory (RBC). Like early classical economic models, RBC models assumed that markets clear and that business cycles are driven by changes in technology and supply, not demand. New Keynesians tried to address many of the criticisms leveled by Lucas and other new classical economists against Neo-Keynesians. New Keynesians adopted rational expectations and built models with microfoundations of sticky prices that suggested recessions could still be explained by demand factors because rigidities stop prices from falling to a market-clearing level, leaving a surplus of goods and labor. The new neoclassical synthesis combined elements of both new classical and new Keynesian macroeconomics into a consensus. Other economists avoided the new classical and new Keynesian debate on short-term dynamics and developed the new growth theories of long-run economic growth. The Great Recession led to a retrospective on the state of the field and some popular attention turned toward heterodox economics.